throbber
Volume 13 * Number | + Z010
`VALUE IN HEALTH
`
`Good Research Practices for Measuring Drug Costsin
`Cost Effectiveness Analyses: Issues and Recommendations:
`The ISPOR Drug Cost Task Force Report—Part|
`
`Joel W. Hay, PhD,! Jim Smeeding, RPh, MBA,? Norman V. Carroll, RPh, PhD,? Michael Drummond,PhD,*
`Louis P. Garrison, PhD,? Edward C. Mansley, PhD,® C. Daniel Mullins, PhD,’ Jack M. Mycka, BS,®
`Brian Seal, PhD, RPh, MBA,” Lizheng Shi, PhD, MS?°
`‘Departmentof Clinical Pharmacy, Pharmaceutical Economies & Policy, University of Southern California, Los Angeles, CA, USA; “JestaRx
`Group, Dallas, TX, USA; 3School of Pharmacy, Virginia Commonwealth University, Richmond, VA, USA; ‘Centre for Health Economics,
`University of York,York, UK; *Pharmaceutical Outcomes Research & Policy Program, Department of Pharmacy, University of Washington,
`Seattle, WA, USA;‘Merck & Co., Inc., North Wales, PA, USA; ’Pharmaceutical Health Services Research, University of Maryland School of
`Pharmacy, Baltimore, MD, USA; 2>MME LLC, Mentelair, Nj, USA; Sanofi-Aventis Pharmaceuticals, Bridgewater, NJ, USA; "Department of Health
`Systems Management, Tulane University School of Public Health and Tropical Medicine, New Orleans, LA, USA
`
`ABSTRACT
`
`Objectives: The assignmentofprices or costs to pharmaceuticals can be
`Good Research Practices—Use of Drug Costs for Cost Effectiveness
`Analysis {DCTF) subgroups met to develop core assumptions and an
`ecucial to results and conclusions that are derived from pharmacocco-
`outline before preparing six draft reports. They solicited comments on the
`nomic cost effectiveness analyses (CEAs). Although numerous pharmace-
`economic practice guidelines are available in the hterature and have been
`outline and drafts from a core group of 174 external reviewers and more
`promulgated in many countries, these guidelines are cither vague orsilent
`broadly from the membership of ISPOR at two ISPOR meetings and via
`the ISPOR website.
`:
`about how drug costs should be established or measured. This is parricu-
`Results: Drug cost measurcments should be fully transparent and reflect
`larly problematic in pharmacocconomic studics performed frem the “soci-
`etal” perspective, because typically the measured cost of a brand name
`the ner payment most relevant to the user’s perspective. The Task Force
`pharmaceutical is not a tue economic cost but also includes transfer
`recommends thar for CEAs of brand name drugs performed from « soci-
`etal perspective, either 1} CEA analysts use a cost chat more accurately
`payments from some membersof socicry (patients and third party payers)
`to other membersof society (pharmaccutical manufacturer stockholders)
`reflects truc societal drug costs (e.g., 20-60% of average sales price), or
`in large part as a reward for biomedical innovation. Moreover, there are
`when that is roo unrealistic to be meaningful for decision-makers, 2) refer
`numerous and complex institutional factors that influence how drug costs
`to their analyses as froma “limited societal perspective.” CEAs performed
`from a payer perspective should use drug prices actually paid by the
`should be measured from other CEA perspectives, both internationally
`and within the domestic US context. The objective of this report is to
`relevant payer nec of all rebares, copays, or other adjustments, When such
`price adjustments are confidential, the analyst should apply a cypical or
`provide guidance and recommendations en how drug costs should be
`average discount chat preserves this confidentiality.
`measured for CEAs performed from a numberofkey analytic perspectives.
`Methods: ISPOR Task Force on Good Research Practices—Use of Drug
`Conclusions: Drug transaction prices not only ration current use of medi-
`Costs for Cosr Effectiveness Analysis (Drug Cost Task Force [DCTF]) was
`cation but also ration future biomedical research and development. CEA
`appointed with the advice and consene of the ISPOR Board of Dircctors.
`researchers should tailor the appropriate measure of drug costs to the
`Members were experienced developers or users of CEA modcis, worked in
`analytic perspective, maintain clarity and transparency on deug cost mea-
`academia,
`industry, and as advisors to governments, and came from
`surement, and report the sensitivity of CEA results to reasonable drug cost
`measurement alternatives.
`several countries, Because how drug costs should be measured for CEAs
`Keywords: cost effectiveness analysis, drug costs, drug research and devel-
`depend on the perspectives, ive Task Force subgroups were created 10
`develop drug cost standards from the societal, managed care, US govern-
`opment, health-care market segmentation, health-care reimbursement,
`payer perspective,
`" ment, industry, and international perspective. The ISPOR Task Force on
`
`based on the key cost effectiveness analysis (CEA} modeling
`Background to the Task Force
`perspectives and their experience as developers or users of CEA
`The ISPOR Task Force on Good Research Practices—Use of Drug
`models for that particular perspective. These individuals were
`Costs for Cost Effectiveness Analysis (DCTF) was recommended
`recognized as scientific leaders in the field, who worked with that
`by the ISPOR Health Science Policy Counci! on December 13,
`perspective in academia, industry, and as advisors to governments,
`2004 and approved bythe ISPOR Board of Directors on May 15,
`and who camefromavariety of countries and health-care settings.
`2005, Joel Hay and Jim Smeeding were appointed as Task Force
`Because howdrug costs should be measured for CEAs depend on
`leaders by the ISPOR Board. The core members of the Task Force
`the perspectives,
`five Task Force subgroups were created to
`who became the leaders of the Task Force subgroups were chosen
`develop drug cost standards fromthe societal, managed care, US
`government, industry, and international perspective. Therefore,
`this Task Force Report is given in six parts. Part I:
`issues and
`recommendations; Part I: a societal perspective; Part
`Ill: a
`managed care perspective; Part 1V: US government perspective;
`Part V: industry perspective; and Part V1: international perspec-
`tive. The Task Force Report refleecs che authors’ own experiences
`
`Address correspondence to: Jocl W. Hay, Department of Clinical Phar-
`macy, Pharmaceutical Economics & Policy, University of Southern Cali-
`fornia, CHIP# 140}, 1540 E. Alcazar Street, Los Angeles, CA 90089-9004,
`USA, E-mail jhay@use.edu
`10.111 44}.1524-4733.2009.00663.x
`
`© 2009,International Society for Pharmacoeconomics and Outcomes Research (ISPOR)
`
`1098-3015/10/3
`
`3-7
`
`Page 1 of 5
`
`Z2tO
`
`DEPOSITION
`EXHIBIT
`
`Biogen Exhibit 2206
`Mylanv. Biogen
`IPR 2018-01403
`
`Page 1 of 5
`
`Biogen Exhibit 2206
`Mylan v. Biogen
`IPR 2018-01403
`
`

`

`Hay etal.
`
`companies would quickly discontinue pharmaceutical R&D. Bur
`patent protection creates clear political, economic and social
`tensions, because certain drugs could be provided to some
`patients and/or payers at a price that would cover the marginal
`costs of production, but are not high enoughto generate optimal
`profits to the innovative manufacrurer. As has been the case of
`AIDS drugs in Africa, patients get sick and die without access to
`existing medications partly to protect
`the patent monopoly
`reward system to ensure pharmaceutical innovation for future
`generations.
`It is often in the interest of both the pharmaceutical manu-
`facturer andits consumers to allow price discrimination among
`different market segments. That is, the pharmaceutical manufac-
`turer, particularly when holding patents on brand name drugs,
`can often make more profits and also make their products more
`accessible to more market segments by charging different prices
`to different consumers, based on the consumers’ different
`demand elasticities (willingness-to-pay). This strategy is most
`effective when such price discrimination is confidential or parallel
`imports are restricted, because this minimizes the potential for
`supply leakage berween market segments,
`Drug price discrimination is most cbvious in comparing
`prices for the same brand name pharmaceuticals in different
`countries (e.g,, the price of a hypertension drug in Canada, the
`United States, Mexico, and China}. Although many health-care
`providers can price discriminate across market segments,
`this
`strategy is often challenged politically, because consurners in the
`richer (higher priced) market segments usually resent having to
`pay more for the same pills as consumers in the poorer (lower
`priced} market segments. Unlike hospira! or physician services,
`pharmaceuticals are generally available as tangible and tradable
`products, and when drug price discrepancies become too large
`between different market segments (or countries) there will be
`substantial arbitrage through legal,
`illegal, or grey market
`re-importation activities,
`Measurement of drug costs depends firstly on the perspective
`of the analyst. Depending on the country or region, the drug cost
`burden is ultimately shared in varying degrees between govern-
`ment or other third party payers and patients. There are drug
`supply chain intermediaries (e.g., wholesalers, retailers, etc.) who
`receive payments for maintaining inventories, productdistribu-
`tion, and dispensing. There can also be demand-side intermedi-
`aries {e.p., pharmaceutical benefits managers, group purchasing
`organizations, etc.) who receive payments for negotiating price
`discounts or rebates and managing drug product lists and for-
`mularies. At cach step of these demand and supply chains, drug
`acquisition costs may vary in complex and nontransparent ways.
`Given this background, drug valuation (costing) for economic
`evaluation is complicated. The complexity is compounded when
`one considers thar each economic evaluation is carried out from
`a specific perspective (e.g., hospital, government payer[in a large
`or small country], managed care organization, patient, societal,
`ete.) and the various perspectives reflect tangibly different objec-
`tives, impacts, allocation priorities, market power, and demand
`elasticities. At the societal perspective level, particularlyin coun-
`tries with large domestic innovative pharmaceutical
`industry,
`there is a clear tension between encouraging pharmaceutical
`innovation with brand name drug prices thar are substantially
`higher than marginal drug production costs and encouraging
`less-expensive medications to reduce health-care costs.
`For managed care organizations, or for smaller countries
`without domestic innovative pharmaceutical industries, there is
`little direct incentive to encourage pharmaceutical innovation,
`because such innovation disproportionately benefits other con-
`sumers, payers, or countries. In these organizations,it is prefer-
`
`4 d
`
`eveloping drug costs for use in CEA models and publications, but
`is not intended as a comprehensive review of the literature.
`The Task Force held its first meeting at
`the ISPOR 10rh
`Annuai International Meeting in Washington DC in 2005 and
`held open forums and/or group leader breakfast meetings at the
`ISPOR 8th Annual European Congress in Florence in 2005, at
`the ISPOR 11th Annual International Meeting in Philadelphia in
`2006, and at the 14th Annual International Meeting in Orlando
`in 2009, The Task Force reviewed other ISPOR guidance docu-
`ments that were developed co inform good scientific conduct
`[1-3]. The Task Force subgroups held teleconferences and used
`electronic mail to exchange outlines and ideas during the subse-
`quent months. The ISPOR Task Force on Good Research
`Practices~-Use of Drug Costs for Cost Effectiveness Analysis
`{DCTF} subgroups mer to develop core assumptions and an
`outline before preparing draft subgroup reports. Several telecon-
`ferences af the Task Force subgroup leaders were held to discuss
`the draft reports, incorporate feedback, and makerevisions. Each
`part of the Task Force Report was prepared by Task Force
`subgroup cochairs and members and circulated to 174 Task
`Force primary reviewers (who were self-identified from a broad
`range of perspectives). After this review, new drafts was prepared
`by the Task Force subgroups and made accessible for broader
`review by all ISPOR members. Comments for these reports by
`Task Force primary reviewers and ISPOR membership are pub-
`lished at the ISPOR website. All opinions reflect those of the
`authors and not necessarily their affiliations.
`
`Introduction
`
`The primary purpose of economic evaluation (specifically, CEA
`as recommended in numerous international payer guidelines [4])
`in health care is to provide valid and reliable information to
`health-care policymakers and decision-makers regardingthe rela-
`tive value of alternative health-care interventions. The key ratio-
`nale supporting these economic evaluationsis that the market for
`health-care interventions is so severely distorted by insurance
`coverage, third-party payments, information failure, taxes, sub-
`sidies, and numerous competition barriers that prices do not
`serve the normal economic function of guiding efficient resource
`allocation. Unlike a competitive market, in health care, Adam
`Smith’s “invisible hand” of price signals is so severely withered
`and atrophied that it must be replaced by the virtual reality glove
`of the economic analyst to ensure that scare resources are allo-
`cated appropriately [5].
`Although there are many areasof health care where prices are
`distorted, perhaps no area is subject to more complexity, confu-
`sion, imprecision, misunderseanding, or conflicting methods than
`that of what price measurements to use for the cost of pharma-
`ceuticals in economic evaluations [6]. The fundamental reason
`for this is that pharmaceuticals are launched into the market only
`after lengthy governmental review of safety and efficacy(e.g., the
`US Food and Drug Administration or the European Medicines
`Agency}. Prescription drugs are only sold by licensed medical
`professionals under strict regulations regarding allowable usage
`indications, patient populations, and appropriate marketing.
`Pharmaceutical research, development, and innovation are
`rewarded and encouraged primarily through patents,giving the
`innovative manufacturer {the patent holder)
`a
`time-limited
`monopoly over drug pricing for the patented drug. Because
`parencs
`reward
`innovation
`by
`transferring brand-specific
`monopoly profits (the excess of drug price over drug marginal
`cost} from consumers to innovator pharmaceutical producers,
`they distort competitive drug prices with the specific intenc of
`encouraging future drug R&cD. Withour patent protection, drug
`
`Page 2 of 5
`
`Page 2 of 5
`
`

`

`ISPOR Drug Cost Task Force Report Overview
`
`5
`
`able to take maximum advantage of one’s local monopsony
`market power to drive drug prices as low as possible for both
`payment and evaluation purposes. Because such organizations or
`countries cannot impact R&D innovation substantially, it is in
`their interest to “free-ride” on larger payers and countries whose
`drug payments do have a significant impact on drug manufac-
`turer profits and R&D incentives.
`Frank Ramsey showed in 1927 thar a monopolist facing
`segmented markets (e.g., consumers with high income/high insur-
`ance coverage vs.
`low income/low insurance coverage) would
`achieve both higher profits and higher social welfare by setting
`prices in each market segment
`inversely proportional
`to the
`market segiment elasticity of demand [7,8]. It is beneficial to both
`pharmaceutical producers and many consumers to engage in
`market segmentation; but becauseit is difficult to prevent leakage
`from lower-priced markets to higher-priced markets, the phar-
`maceutical
`industry engages in extraordinarily complex and
`often secretive negotiations with different customers with the
`explicit purpose of preventing richer market segments from
`knowing the actual transaction prices in the more demand-elastic
`market segments.
`For example, in the United States, the Medicaid programis
`required by law to receive the lowest manufacturer price avail-
`able to private and certain public purchasers for single source
`drugs. Nevertheless,
`this transaction price is fully disguised
`through secret volume rebates paid from the pharmaceutical
`manufacturers to the state Medicaid programs. Thus, even
`though they are all directly involved in the purchase and sales of
`Medicaid drugs, Medicaid patients,
`retail pharmacists, drug
`wholesalers, and other intermediaries have no idea what the real
`transaction prices are for the Medicaid drug purchases.
`Similar secretive price discounting mechanisms, often trig-
`gered by volume targets, formulary placement and multidrug
`purchasing from the same manufacturers, as well as rebares for
`formulary placement, make it extremely difficult to know what
`any given government or third-party payer actually pays for
`specific pharmaceutical products, Moreover, there is no require-
`ment
`to make such information publicly known. Generally
`speaking, those organizations with the greatest marker power
`(e.g,, single-payer government health-care systems) and those
`with the highest demand elasticity will capture greater discounts
`from publicly quoted or published prices, while those with the
`least market power and lowest demand elasticity will achieve
`smaller discounts and pay close to fall price.
`It should be kept in mind that the traditional method for
`rewarding pharmaceutical R&D through patent protection and
`monopoly prices for new drugs is the result of historical prece-
`dent and instirutional
`inertia. It
`is an imperfect system for
`rewarding biomedical
`innovation;
`often
`allocating scarce
`resources towards “me-too” patentable new molecules rather
`than towards genuine innovations, although leaving critically
`important innovations {e.g., low-dose aspirin for heart disease or
`generic antibiotics for ulcers) to languish for years without being
`widely researched or adopted due to inability to obtain patent
`protection and to profit from valuable innovations [9].
`Moreover, it is vitally important to provide adequate incen-
`tives for biomedical
`research in general and pharmaceutical
`R&Din particular. There is consensus among health economists
`that the societal returns to biomedical R&D are on the order of
`10-100 to 7 [fO,22]. Cutler er al. have recently estimated that
`within the US population, averagelife year gains from 1987 to
`2000 were approximately 1 to 2 years and the average quality-
`adjusted life year (QALY) gains were 3 to 4 years [12]. Valuing
`these QALY gains az a societal willingness to pay of $150,000,
`and assuming that 2 In 3 of these gains are due to medical care
`
`innovations [13],
`improvements, mostly due to biomedical
`implies that medical care gains added $90 trillion, or approxi-
`mately $2.7 erillion annually to the societal wealth of the US
`population during this time period. The global value of biomedi-
`cal innovation would be several times larger than these estimates.
`Several alternatives to the patent system have been proposed
`to reward biomedical R&cD [6-8,14]. These include userlicenses,
`government patent buyouts, rewards or tax-funded pharmaceu-
`tical R&c¢D. Whether such alternative mechanisms can be imple-
`mented to incentivize pharmaceutical R&D without requiring a
`monopoly pricing structure for brand name pharmaceuticals,it
`would be feasible to use marginal cost (or generic) drug prices in
`economic evaluations of pharmaceutical interventions, particu-
`larly when done from a societal perspective. In fact, given that
`the monopoly profits awarded to drug manufacturer patent-
`holders is not a true cost, but rather a transfer payment from one
`member ofsociety to another [15], there is a strong argumentto
`exclude these profits from drug costs when conducting economic
`evaluations from a societal perspective.
`In fact, one can demonstrate that government buy-outs of
`drug patents with all drugs being sold at generic pricing levels
`could achieve a much better outcome for government programs,
`private consumers, and third party payers without damaging the
`incentives for pharmaceutical R&D, Currently, the brand name
`pharmaceutical spending on R&D is about $60billion [16]. US
`federal drug spending is $81 billion 417]. Each year, the US
`federal government could buy out all drug patents (by fully
`subsidizing the private costs of pharmaceutical R&D) and still
`save money because it would be able to purchase all drugs at
`generic prices. US consumers would additionally benefit by more
`than $100 billion per year if all drugs were generic.
`Beyond these theoretical concerns,
`there are institutional
`complexities and opaque payment structures in every country
`and health-care financing system that make drug cost measure-
`ment difficulr even when the analytic perspective is straight
`forward and clear. For example,
`in the US managed care
`environment, a particular medication could experience a dozen
`or more different transaction prices depending on whereit is in
`the supply chain from manufacturer, to wholesaler, to retailer, to
`patient, and where it
`is in the payment/reimbursement chain
`from manufacturer to managed care organization, to pharma-
`ceutical benefits manager, to patient, to rebate coupon. Although
`this report is not an exhaustive compilation ofall of the com-
`plexities and variations in drug transaction costs, it docs give
`examples from many of the typical scenarios that CEA analysts
`will encounter around the globe. More importantly, it provides
`guidance and recommendations based on the authors’ and
`reviewers’ experience and understanding of what works best,
`
`Purposes of the Report
`
`The purposes of this Task Force Report are: 1} to develop a
`coherent set of guidelines for those developing or reviewing drug
`cost measurements in CEAs; and 2) to develop a formatfor good
`research practices in drug cost measurement that is useful for
`decision-makers from various perspectives. The intended audi-
`ence is research analysts who perform CEA analyses for healeh-
`care decision-makers as well as health-care decision-makers who
`are responsible for local or national formularies, Others who
`may find this document useful
`include members of the press,
`patient advocacy groups, health-care professionals, drug and
`other technology manufacturers, and those developing guidelines
`for their settings. The panel
`recognizes thar the methods for
`measuring and reporting drug costs continue to develop. This
`
`Page 3 of 5
`
`Page 3 of 5
`
`

`

`Hay et al,
`
`6.
`
`prices in either the base case or sensitivity analyses of phar-
`macoeconomic models. It is also appropriate to include
`longer-term trends in applicable drug prices {net of general
`inflation) for chronic disease medications.
`ISPOR should publish a website where current DCTF rec-
`ommendations for drug costing are updated as important
`new information becomes available.
`7. Population-based estimates of drug costs should incorpo-
`rate predicted adherence and persistence with drug therapy.
`§. When done from a patient/consumerperspective, the total
`net out-of-pocket payments for medications should be used
`as the drug cost measurement.
`Implications of extreme
`changes in marginal or average drug costs on patient drug
`utilization (e.g., completion of deductible expense limits,
`reaching maximumcoverage benefits, Medicare-type cover-
`age “doughnut holes,” etc.) should be fully evaluated and
`explained.
`9. For international comparisons, drug units should be stan-
`dardized in terms of volume/veight of active ingredient,
`regardless of package and dosing frequency or strength
`variations across countries.
`10. Drug costs should be measured in local currency per unit of
`active ingredient and should be converted to other curren-
`cies using Purchasing Power Parity indexes or a currency
`exchange rate relevant to the decision-maker.
`11, When using drug prices fromdifferent years, the consumer
`price index (preferably the medical care componentprice
`index or the pharmaceutical componentprice index) for the
`local currency should be applied before the currency
`conversion.
`
`Acknowledgments
`We acknowledge the valuable assistance of Daniel Kim, Dorothy
`Novilus, and the ISPOR staff.
`
`Sourceof financial support: None.
`
`References
`
`tw
`
`wr
`
`1 Mauskopf JA, Sullivan SD, AnncmansL, et al, Principles of goad
`practice for budget
`impact analysis: report of the ISPOR task
`force on good research practices—budget impact analysis. Value
`Health 2007;10:336-47,
`Weinstein MC, O’Brien B, HornbergerJ, et al. Principles of good
`practice for decision analytic modeling in health care evaluation:
`report
`of
`the
`ISPOR ‘Task
`Force
`on
`good
`research
`practices—modeling studies. Value Health 2003;6:9-17,
`3 Ramsey 5, Wilike R, Briggs A, et al. Good research practices for
`cost-effectivencss alongside clinical trials: the ISPOR RCT-CEA
`Task Force report. Value Health 2605;8:521-33,
`4 ISPOR. Pharmacocconomic guidelines around the world. Avail-
`able from: http/Avww.ispor.org/PEguidelines/index.asp [Accessed
`February 71, 2009).
`HayJ. Application of cost effectiveness and cost benefit analysis
`to pharmaceuticals. In: Santoro M, Gorrie T, eds. The Grand
`Bargain: Ethics and the Pharmaceutical
`Industry in the 21st
`century. New York NY: Cambridge Universiry Press, 2006.
`6 Hoyle M. Future drug prices and cost-cffectiveness analyses.
`Pharmacoeconomics 2008;26:589-602,
`7 Ramsey FP. A contribution to the theory of taxation. Econ }
`1927;37:47-61.
`§ Danzon
`P. Neglected
`2007;449:176-9,
`9 Hay J, Yu W. Brug patents and prices, can we achieve better
`outcomes? In: Triplett J, ed. Measuring the Prices of Medical
`Treatments. Washington, DC: Brookings Press, 1999.
`
`diseases:
`
`at what
`
`price? Nature
`
`6 r
`
`eport highlights areas of consensus as well as areas where con-
`tinued methodological developmentis needed.
`The Good Research Practices for Measuring Drug Costs in
`Cost Effectiveness Analyses Report is published in six parts based
`on analytic perspective. The next five articles in this issue of
`Valve int Health report the issues and recommendations for phar-
`maceutical pricing from the different perspectives, including: 1)
`Societal [18]; 2) Managed care [19]; 3) Medicare, Medicaid, and
`other US Government Payers [20]; 4) Industry [21]; 5) European
`countries and other international country perspectives [22],
`These perspective-specific analyses are presented to provide guid-
`ance and recommendations on how to obtain and use appro-
`“priate drug cost measurements when conducting economic
`evaluations of health-care interventions for different health-care
`decision-maker audiences.
`is over-
`task force report
`We recognize that
`this initial
`represented by topics relating to US payment and reimbursement
`issues, This happened despite strong efforts by the task force to
`recruit ISPOR members from all countries and regions andis not
`meantto give offense to anyone. The task force membersserve as
`volunteers, and because of a large number of drug payment
`policy issues coming forward in the US context recently, there
`were more people motivated to address these topics. We certainly
`hope and expect that this is just the first chapter of an ongoing
`effort to assess drug cost evaluation issues globally and thar
`future reports of the DCTF will be comprehensively representa-
`tive of global drug evaluation concerns, whether they be different
`countries,
`regions, stakeholder perspectives, methodological
`approaches, or other issues. We certainly encourage any reader
`who sees gaps that need to be addressed to join the DCTF and
`add their perspective in future reports.
`
`General Recommendations
`
`Abthough mostof the Task Force’s recommendations are specific
`to each of the analytic perspectives thar we focused on, there are
`some general recommendations that we believe apply to drug
`cost measurement in any cost effectiveness analysis setting or
`application.
`
`1. More clarification of the “societal perspective” is needed.
`‘For CEAs of brand name drugs performed from a societal
`perspective, either CEA analysts:
`i} use a cost that more
`accurately reflects true societal drug costs (e.g., 20-60% of
`average sales price), or whether that is unrealistic and nor
`meaningful for decision-makers; orii} refer to their analyses
`as conducted from a “limited societal perspective.”
`2. Drug cost values and measurements should be transparent
`and made available to any reader or user of a CEA, with the
`data sources and rationale fully documented.
`3. One-way and/or threshold CEA sensitivity analyses should
`demonstrate how muchhigher/lower drug costs would have
`to be to alter pharmacoeconomic model conclusions.
`4, CEAs performed from a payer perspective should use drug
`prices actually paid by the relevant payer net of all rebates,
`copays, or other adjustments. When such price adjustments
`are confidential, the analyst should apply a generic average
`discount that preserves this confidentialicy. As a corollary of
`this, when done from a government perspective, drug costs
`should be net of any sales tax, value-added tax, or other
`taxes that are direct revenue offsets to the payer. Program
`eligibility and coverage issues should be clearly stated or
`referenced.
`5. For drugs that are off-patentorlikely to be off-patent in the
`near future, it is appropriate to consider multisource drug
`
`Page 4 of 5
`
`Page 4 of 5
`
`

`

`ISPOR Drug Cost Task Force Report Overview
`
`the value in healch care? Value Health
`
`10 Hay J. Where's
`2006;9:13-4,
`11 HayJ. Prices and innovation in pharmaccuticals and biorechno}-
`ogy. In: Farquhar I, Summers K, Sorkin A, eds. Research in
`HumanCapital and Development,vol. 16, The Value of Innova-
`tion: Impacts on Health, Life Quality, and Regulatory Research,
`Bingicy, UK: Emerald Group Publishing; 2008:81-99,
`12 Cutler DM, Rosen AB, Vijan $ The valuc of medical spending in
`the United States, 1960-2000. N Engl J Med 2006;355:920-7.
`13 Luce B, Mauskopf J, Sloan F, ct al. The rerurn on investment in
`health care: 1980-2000. Value Health 2006;9:146-56.
`14 Goldman DP, Jena AB, Philipson T, Sun E. Drug licenses: a
`new model for pharmaceutical pricing. Health Aff 2008;27:122-
`9.
`15 Posner RA. The social costs of monopoly and regulation, J Polit
`Econ 1975;83:807-28,
`16 PARMA. R&D spending by U.S. Biopharmaceutical companies
`reaches record $58.8 billion in 2007, Available from: http://www.
`phrma.org/news_room/press_releases/us_biopharmaceurical_
`companies_r&d_spending_reaches_record_$58.8_billion_in_
`2007/ [Accessed June 12, 2009].
`17 Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services. National health
`expenditure historical data. Available from: www.cms.hhs.gov/
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`NationalHeaithExpendData/O2_NationalHealthAccounts
`Historical.asp [Accessed func 13, 2009}.
`Garrison LP, Mansley EC, Abbott TA HI, et al. Gaod research
`practices for measuring drug costs in cost-effectiveness analyses: a
`socictal perspective: the ISPOR drug cost task force report—Part
`il. Value Health. In press.
`Mansley EC, Carroll NV, Chen KS, ct al. Good researchpractices
`for measuring drug costs in cost effectiveness analyses: a managed
`care perspective: the ISPOR drug cost task force report—PartII].
`Value Health, In press.
`Mullins CD, Seal B, Scoane-Wazquez E, etal. Good research
`practices for measuring drug costs in cost cffectivencss analyses:
`medicare, medicaid and other US government payers perspectives:
`The ISPOR drug cost task force report—Part IV. Value Health.
`In press.
`Mycka JM, Dellamano R, Kolassa EM, et al. Good research
`practices for measuring drug costs in cost effectiveness analyses:
`an industry perspective:
`the ISPOR drug cost
`task force
`report~-Part V. Value Health, In press.
`Shi L, Hodges M, Drummond M,ct al. Good research practices
`for measuring drug costs in cost effectiveness analyses: an inter-
`national perspective: the ISPOR drug cost task force report-—Part
`VI. Value Health. In press.
`
`Page 5 of 5
`
`Page 5 of 5
`
`

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket