throbber
THE R&D COST
`OF A NEW
`MEDICINE
`
`Jorge Mestre-Ferrandiz,
`Jon Sussex and Adrian Towse
`Office of Health Economics
`
`THE R&D COST OF A NEW MEDICINE
`
`JORGE MESTRE-FERRANDIZ, JON SUSSEX AND ADRIAN TOWSE
`
`WCK1107
`Wockhardt Bio AG v. Janssen Oncology, Inc.
`IPR2016-01582
`
`1
`
`

`

`2
`
`

`

`THE R&D COST
`THE R&D COST
`OF A NEW
`OF A NEW
`MEDICINE
`MEDICINE
`
`JORGE MESTRE-FERRANDIZ,
`JORGE MESTRE—FERRANDIZ,
`JON SUSSEX AND ADRIAN TOWSE
`JON SUSSEX AND ADRIAN TOWSE
`
`DECEMBER 2012
`DECEMBER 2012
`
`
`HE5
`
`Office of Health Economics
`50 years of research and expertise
`
`3
`
`

`

`Office of Health Economics
`Southside
`7th Floor
`105 Victoria Street
`London SW1E 6QT
`United Kingdom
`www.ohe.org
`
`©2012
`All rights reserved
`Printed in the United Kingdom
`ISBN 978-1-899040-19-3
`
`This publication has undergone a rigorous peer review by the independent OHE Editorial Board
`and other experts in the field. The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily
`represent those of the OHE.
`
`ABOUT THE AUTHORS
`
`Dr Jorge Mestre-Ferrandiz is Director of Consulting at the Office of Health Economics. His
`research interests include pharmaceutical pricing and reimbursement systems worldwide, the
`economics of the pharmaceutical industry, the economics of innovation and incentives for
`encouraging medical R&D.
`
`Jon Sussex is Deputy Director at the Office of Health Economics. His areas of expertise include
`health care expenditure; efficiency, competition and incentives in health care systems; the role of
`the private sector in publicly funded health care; and the economic regulation of the
`pharmaceutical industry.
`
`Prof Adrian Towse is Director of the Office of Health Economics. His current research includes
`the use of “risk-sharing” arrangements between health care payers and pharmaceutical companies,
`including value-based pricing approaches; the economics of pharmacogenetics for health care
`payers and the pharmaceutical industry; economic issues that affect both R&D for and access to
`treatments for diseases prevalent in the developing world; the economics of medical negligence;
`and measuring productivity in health care.
`
`ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
`
`This work was partially funded by an unrestricted research grant from AstraZeneca. We also
`would like to thank CMRI for allowing us to access their data. We are grateful to Prof Pedro-Pita
`Barros, Universidade Nova de Lisboa; Prof Martin Buxton, Brunel University; Prof Patricia
`Danzon, University of Pennsylvania; and Dr Nancy Mattison, The Mattison Group, for
`comments on an earlier draft.
`
`i
`
`4
`
`

`

`CONTENTS
`
`List of Illustrations and Tables
`Executive Summary
`Introduction and Context
`Context: Setting the Scene
`The Cost of a New Medicine—the Mean
`Policy Discussions around the Cost Estimates
`Factors Affecting Development Costs
`Out-of-Pocket Costs
`Success Rates
`Development Times
`Cost of Capital
`Sensitivity Analysis: Impact of Changing the Key Variables
`A New Estimate for Drug Development Costs: Our Analysis
`Data and Methods
`Results
`Comparing Our Analysis with the Published Analyses
`Sensitivity Analysis
`Therapeutic Areas
`Success Rates
`Development Times
`Overall R&D Costs
`Compound Origin: Self-Originated versus Licensed-In
`Firm Size
`Biologics and Biopharmaceuticals
`Drivers of Trends in R&D Costs
`Drivers of Out-of-Pocket Costs
`Drivers of Failure Rates
`Drivers of Development Times
`A New Drug Development Paradigm?
`Summary and Conclusions
`Annex 1. List of Papers Providing Quantitative Evidence
`Annex 2. Sensitivity Analysis
`Glossary
`References
`
`ii
`
`iii
`v
`1
`2
`6
`16
`18
`18
`19
`24
`25
`28
`30
`34
`37
`39
`40
`42
`42
`47
`50
`53
`56
`58
`61
`62
`65
`67
`68
`71
`73
`74
`79
`81
`
`5
`
`

`

`LIST OF ILLUSTRATIONS AND TABLES
`
`Figure 1.1. European and US R&D spending
`
`Table 1.1. Number of new chemical or biological entities (1990–2009)
`
`Table 1.2. Number of new chemical or biological entities (2005–2009)
`
`Figure 1.2.
`
`Structure of the paper
`
`Figure 2.1. The R&D process
`
`Table 2.1.
`
`Comparison of models calculating mean R&D costs
`
`Figure 2.2.
`
`Sample of NMEs: time period when first tested in humans
`
`Table 2.2.
`
`Estimates of the full cost of bringing an NME to market (2011 US$m)
`
`Figure 2.3. Mean R&D costs per successful NME by middle year of study data
`(2011 US$m)
`
`Figure 2.4. Analysis by Paul et al (2010)
`
`Table 2.3. Out-of-pocket mean development costs (2011 US$m)
`
`Table 2.4.
`
`Probability of success (percentages)
`
`Figure 2.5. Trends in attrition rates
`
`Figure 2.6. Number of NMEs required per phase for one successful NME, based on
`recent estimates for probability of success (high and low estimates)
`
`Table 2.5. Development times (months)
`
`Table 2.6.
`
`Cost of capital used in the literature
`
`Figure 3.1. Milestones and intervals used in CMRI’s programmes
`
`Figure 3.2. Relating CMRI’s milestones to “standard” clinical phases
`
`Table 3.1.
`
`Summary of the data on cost per interval (2011 US$m)
`
`Table 3.2.
`
`Success rates by interval
`
`Table 3.3. Development times by interval
`
`Table 3.4. Hypothetical out-of-pocket spending needed for one successful medicine
`(2011 US$m)
`
`Table 3.5.
`
`Capitalised cost per successful medicine (2011 US$m)
`
`Figure 3.3.
`
`Interval times in years, CMRI data
`
`Table 3.6. Out-of-pocket costs for Phases I–III (2011 US$m)
`
`Figure 3.4. Capitalised total cost per successful medicine by cost of capital (2011 US$m)
`
`Table 3.7.
`
`Sensitivity analysis: effect on our base case cost estimate per new medicine
`
`Table 4.1.
`
`Success rates for selected therapeutic area—DiMasi (2001) versus
`DiMasi et al (2010)
`
`2
`
`2
`
`3
`
`5
`
`7
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`15
`
`18
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`24
`
`26
`
`33
`
`34
`
`35
`
`36
`
`36
`
`37
`
`38
`
`39
`
`40
`
`41
`
`41
`
`43
`
`iii
`
`6
`
`

`

`LIST OF ILLUSTRATIONS AND TABLES
`
`Table 4.2.
`
`Probability of market entry
`
`Figure 4.1. Clinical phase transition probabilities for oncology compounds
`
`Figure 4.2. Transition probabilities: oncology versus other drugs, 1993–2002
`
`Figure 4.3. Mean clinical and approval phase times for approved NMEs by therapeutic
`class, 2005–2009
`
`Table 4.3. Durations by disorder and primary indication
`
`Table 4.4. Development and regulatory approval times: oncologic versus other drugs
`
`Table 4.5.
`
`Average clinical period cost per approved new drug by therapeutic
`class (2011 US$m)
`
`Table 4.6.
`
`Costs for new drugs by disorder and primary indication
`
`Table 5.1.
`
`Current and maximum-possible success rates by source of molecule for
`compounds first tested in humans from 1993 to 2004
`
`Figure 5.1.
`
`Phase transition probabilities and clinical approval success probabilities by source
`of compound, for compounds first tested in humans from 1993 to 2004
`
`Table 7.1.
`
`Capitalised costs per investigational biopharmaceutical compound
`(2011 US$m)
`
`Table 7.2.
`
`Pre-approval out-of-pocket outlays per approved new molecule (2011 US$m)
`
`Table 7.3.
`
`Pre-approval capitalised cost per approved new molecule (2011 US$m)
`
`Table 8.1. Distribution of trials included on ClinicalTrials.gov (August 2012)
`
`Figure 8.1.
`
`Proposed flexible blueprint
`
`Figure 8.2.
`
`“Quick win, fast fail” model
`
`Table A1.
`
`List of papers providing quantitative evidence
`
`Figure A2.1. Capitalised total cost per successful medicine by cost of capital (2011 US$m)
`
`Table A2.1. Current, maximum and minimum success rates
`
`Table A2.2. Capitalised cost of a successful medicine under current, maximum and
`minimum success rates (cost of capital = 11%; US$ 2011 prices)
`
`Table A2.3. Capitalised cost of a successful NME altering success rates by ±1%
`(cost of capital = 11%; 2011 prices)
`
`Table A2.4. Effects of altering current success rates by ±10%
`
`Table A2.5. Sensitivity analysis for cycle times (2011 prices)
`
`Table A2.6. Sensitivity analysis: effect on our base case cost estimate per new medicine
`
`45
`
`46
`
`46
`
`48
`
`49
`
`49
`
`50
`
`51
`
`54
`
`54
`
`59
`
`59
`
`60
`
`63
`
`69
`
`70
`
`73
`
`74
`
`75
`
`75
`
`76
`
`76
`
`77
`
`78
`
`iv
`
`7
`
`

`

`EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
`
`Introduction and Context
`How much it costs to research and develop a successful new medicine has been an important
`policy issue at least since the 1960s. Cost estimates matter not just because of intellectual
`curiosity or for industry understanding of its performance, but because they are a key aspect of
`the international debate about the reasonableness of pharmaceutical prices and the magnitude of
`the long-term investments involved.
`
`Debate continues about whether the R&D productivity of the biopharmaceutical industry has
`fallen. Calculations based on annual rates of R&D spending and the number of new molecular
`(chemical or biological) entities launched suggest a declining trend in R&D productivity. But it
`takes a long time to develop a new drug, so comparing current R&D spending levels with the
`current number of new approvals is an inaccurate measure of R&D productivity, at best.
`
`Mean Research and Development Costs in the Literature
`Published estimates of the mean (average) cost of researching and developing a successful new
`medicine suggest an increase in cost over the last decade—from the estimate of US$802m by
`DiMasi et al (2003) at 2000 prices (US$1,031m at 2011 prices) to the estimate by Paul et al
`(2010) of US$1,867m at 2011 prices. In this study, we present a new estimate, US$1,506m at
`2011 prices, which lies within this range. Our analysis explores how these costs have been evolving
`and for what reasons.
`
`Mean estimates of R&D costs per new medicine, and in particular drawing conclusions based on
`comparisons between estimates, should be treated with caution because of important differences
`in the studies, particularly in the use of different databases of drugs. Moreover, important
`differences exist across subgroups of drugs—for instance, by therapeutic area, by firm size and by
`compound origin.
`
`Key Components of R&D Costs
`Four main variables determine the capitalised cost of a new drug estimate: out-of-pocket costs,
`success rates, development times and the cost of capital. Given the long timescales required to
`develop a new drug and the associated risks, we need to allow for both failures and the cost of
`capital to compute the total cost of a new successful drug, i.e. not just the out-of-pocket costs.
`Capitalised cost is the standard accounting treatment for long-term investments. This recognises
`the fact that investors require a return on research that reflects alternative potential uses of their
`investment.
`
`Out-of-pocket costs: Out-of-pocket development costs, before adjusting for failures, appear to
`have increased over time since the first DiMasi et al (1991) article. The most recent estimates, by
`Paul et al (2010) and Adams and Brantner (2010), are very similar for out-of-pocket
`development costs (from Phase I through III) at around US$215-220m in 2011 US$. The
`studies are less consistent in their estimates of the magnitude of the cost of the different clinical
`trial phases.
`
`Success rates: The most recent estimates of probability of success for Phase I, Phase II and Phase
`III are between 49% and 75%, 30% and 48%, and 50% and 71%, respectively. Overall, the
`cumulative clinical success rate appears to have decreased over time. Pammolli, Magazzini and
`
`v
`
`8
`
`

`

`EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
`
`Riccaboni (2011) find significant decreases in success rates, especially in Phase II and Phase III.
`But analyses by DiMasi and colleagues since the early 1990s suggest that success rates across the
`different phases have changed little.
`
`Development times: Overall development time (Phases I–III) appears to have remained relatively
`constant over time, at around 6.5 years (75–79 months) on average. Phase III trials tend to be
`the longest development phase, although the most recent work suggests that development times
`for Phases II and III now are similar.
`
`Cost of capital: The long timescales of pharmaceutical R&D mean that the cost of capital has a
`major impact on the final cost per successful NME. The estimated cost per successful drug is
`highly sensitive to the cost of capital applied. The more recent studies use a real annual cost of
`capital of 11%, up from the 9% used by DiMasi et al (1991).
`
`Our New Cost Estimate
`In this study, we present a new estimate for mean R&D costs per new successful drug based on
`previously unpublished information collected by CMRI in confidential surveys. Our fully
`capitalised R&D cost estimate per new medicine is US$1,506m at US$ 2011 prices (i.e. US$1.5
`b). Time costs, i.e. cost of capital, represent 33% of total cost. Our new estimate lies within the
`range of other recently reported estimates.
`
`Our overall probability of success is lower than those reported by DiMasi et al (2003) and Paul
`et al (2010). Development times in our study are similar to those reported by DiMasi et al
`(2003) and Paul et al (2010). Total out-of-pocket costs are very similar to those in Paul et al
`(2010) and slightly lower than those in DiMasi et al (2003).
`
`Mean Costs May Hide Important Differences
`Published estimates that refer to the mean cost of R&D per new medicine are just that—
`averages. The literature has shown that the costs of R&D vary with the subgroup of drugs
`included in the analysis. The most important factors affecting costs are: therapeutic area, firm
`size, and whether the molecule is a “traditional” chemical compound or a biologic.
`
`Therapeutic area: R&D costs vary substantially across therapeutic area because of considerable
`variation in three key variables: success rates, development times and out-of-pocket costs.
`
`The most recent analyses suggest that the most expensive therapeutic areas in terms of drug
`R&D costs are neurology, respiratory and oncology. This is because drugs in these categories
`experience lower success rates and longer development times. By comparison, anti-parasitics and
`drugs to treat HIV/AIDS have the lowest R&D costs because of higher success rates and shorter
`development times.
`
`Self-originated versus licensed-in: Most of the published calculations of R&D costs to date
`focus on self-originated new compounds because comprehensive data for licensed-in/acquired
`compounds are very difficult to collect. However, an increasing proportion of drugs are now
`licensed in and clinical success rates for such drugs are higher than for self-originated drugs.
`Greater success may be the results of a “screening effect” for licensed-in compounds: many of the
`
`vi
`
`9
`
`

`

`EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
`
`licensed-in drugs are acquired after Phase I or Phase II testing has been conducted by the licensor
`and, thus, already have been shown to be promising candidates before being included in the
`acquiring company’s development portfolio.
`
`This difference also is apparent during early research, i.e. externally-sourced projects are
`significantly more likely to reach clinical testing than internal projects, perhaps for similar
`reasons. Indeed, some expectation of success would be necessary for a company to license or
`acquire any drug candidate.
`
`Firm size: An important variable explored in the literature is the effect of firm size on R&D
`productivity and whether R&D costs per approved drug vary with firm size. For such analyses,
`papers focusing on self-originated compounds might produce biased results because the sample
`for small firms with successful self-originated drugs would be too small to be meaningful.
`
`Results of research on the impact of firm size on R&D productivity and R&D costs are mixed.
`The evidence from the 1990s and early- to mid-2000s seems to suggest that size matters:
`multiple tangible and intangible assets are associated with fully integrated organisations, where
`core capacities can be important across diseases. It remains unclear, however, whether R&D
`productivity is greater for smaller companies than for traditional “big pharma”.
`
`Biopharmaceuticals: To address the problem of limited evidence on biological medicines,
`DiMasi and Grabowski (2007b) expanded their biotech sample from DiMasi et al (2003) with
`project level and aggregate annual expenditure data from a biotech firm. They found that the
`overall clinical success rate for biotech products is 30.2%, which is higher than the 21.5%
`estimate for traditional pharmaceutical products reported by DiMasi et al (2003). Total clinical
`and approval time is 8% longer for biopharmaceuticals, with nearly all the difference being in
`Phase I.
`
`Capitalisation increases biopharma costs relative to traditional R&D costs because of the longer
`development timeline and a slightly higher cost of capital. To account for the latter, DiMasi and
`Grabowski (2007b) use an 11.5% cost of capital for biologics compared to 11% for other
`medicines. Comparisons between biologics and other pharmaceuticals based on this one study,
`however, should be viewed with caution because the sample size for biologics still is small.
`
`Drivers of Trends in R&D Costs
`The key drivers of the main components of R&D costs present three sets of issues grouped
`around out-of-pocket costs, failure/success rates and development times.
`
`Drivers of out-of-pocket costs: A key element of R&D cost is the cost of clinical trials, which is
`affected by the cost per patient and the number of patients required to collect sufficient data.
`The complexity of clinical trials has increased over time, also increasing their costs. Two trends,
`however, appear to be helping to control trial costs. First, outsourcing to clinical research
`organisations (CROs) appears to increase the efficiency of running trials. Second, locating trials
`in emerging markets (Africa, Asia, Eastern Europe, Latin America and the Middle East) can
`reduce costs, both because local costs are lower and because patient recruitment may be faster.
`Nevertheless, although more clinical trials are being conducted in emerging markets, especially
`
`vii
`
`10
`
`

`

`EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
`
`Phase III trials, the majority of clinical trials still are conducted in the US and Western Europe,
`for reasons related to regulatory conditions, relevant expertise and infrastructure.
`
`Drivers of failure rates: Failure rates appear to have increased over time and have fluctuated
`across stages of development. This may be the result of a combination of reasons. First, regulators
`are becoming more risk averse and may be more reluctant to approve some drugs. Second, R&D
`is directed towards tougher challenges that require drugs with novel mechanisms of action and
`for which clinical endpoints may be less clear cut. Third, within companies, projects may
`advance prematurely, for various reasons, to the later stages of clinical development and then fail
`in Phase III.
`
`Other changes have been identified that could counter increased failure rates. These include
`better preclinical screening that ensures earlier project termination; integrating HTA earlier in
`the process to encourage earlier decisions about discontinuing projects for commercial reasons;
`and developing biomarkers and companion diagnostics that can lead to personalised or stratified
`medicine, with greater prospects for success. Alliances between companies, increasingly
`common, also may increase success rates.
`
`In the short run, however, important technological challenges, especially for
`personalised/stratified medicines, may actually lead to higher failure rates and costs as science
`advances and while companies learn how to better develop biomarkers and companion
`diagnostics. It might take some time for biomarkers and diagnostics to be used efficiently, but
`“learning by doing” could drive a more efficient R&D process in the long run.
`
`Drivers of development times: A number of factors affecting development times have been
`identified. First, regulators may be more risk averse, leading to increased regulatory stringency
`and longer regulatory reviews. Second, companies are directing efforts towards areas that are
`intrinsically associated with very long clinical development times. Third, clinical trials are
`becoming increasingly complex and, as a result, take longer to complete. Fourth, trade offs may
`be occurring between time and success rate—for example, longer Phase II development times
`that allow for additional scrutiny before deciding whether to advance to the next phase might
`produce higher success rates in Phase III. A better use of biomarkers might reduce overall
`development times by enabling pre-identification of patients with a high response rate and/or
`low probability of an adverse drug reaction.
`
`A new drug development paradigm? A number of alternatives have been put forward to try to
`make the R&D process more efficient and affordable. The key suggestions include focusing on
`the earlier phases to reduce technical uncertainties before undertaking the more expensive trials
`in the later development stages and allowing for greater flexibility.
`
`Conclusions
`Mean estimates of R&D costs per successful drug are useful in providing an overall picture, but
`should be treated with caution. Important cost differences exist across therapeutic areas, firm
`sizes and compound origins. In addition, many of the cost estimates in the literature focus on
`self-originated new compounds and exclude licensed-in compounds and compounds that have
`been discovered and/or developed via alliances or deals between companies, which are
`
`viii
`
`11
`
`

`

`EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
`
`increasingly common. Other cost estimates do not differentiate at all between self-originated and
`licensed-in compounds, making it difficult to gauge their accuracy. These issues should be
`factored in when drawing conclusions about R&D costs.
`
`With these caveats in mind, it does appear that R&D costs per new successful medicine are
`increasing. The reasons for the increase in R&D costs are multiple—from higher cash outlays to
`higher costs of capital and higher attrition rates throughout the clinical trials process.
`
`Technological challenges are driving these cost increases in part; today’s targeted diseases currently
`are more complex than diseases targeted decades ago, producing a negative impact on R&D costs.
`In addition, as we move towards personalised/stratified medicine, the need to identify the
`appropriate patient population more narrowly increases. Some examples already exist of new
`medicines being developed alongside companion diagnostics that target very specific patient
`subpopulations; this can increase the R&D costs in the short run as companies adapt to this new
`environment. In the long run, however, this “learning by doing” has the potential to make the
`R&D process more efficient.
`
`Companies sometimes may advance projects prematurely through the R&D process when more
`time and resource invested at an earlier stage could prevent an ultimately unsuccessful and more
`expensive Phase III. Companies continue to work to improve the efficiency of R&D decisions by
`addressing those factors within their control—e.g. greater scrutiny in the early R&D stages,
`integrating health economics earlier in the process, and moving some trials to less expensive
`locations and/or using CROs to manage clinical trials. Biopharmaceutical companies also are
`trying to address the more complex scientific challenges through alliances with other companies
`and by working in collaboration with a range of other stakeholders. This allows both risks and
`rewards to be shared, rather than being borne by one party alone.
`
`The R&D costs identified in our study are driven by a combination of factors, including changes
`in technology and decisions taken by companies and regulators. Whether the current drug
`development paradigm needs revising and—if so, how—is clearly an important policy issue that
`merits further investigation.
`
`ix
`
`12
`
`

`

`INTRODUCTION AND CONTEXT
`
`Key Points
`How much it costs to research and develop a successful new medicine has been an important
`policy issue at least since the 1960s1. Cost estimates matter not just because of intellectual
`curiosity or for industry understanding of its performance, but because they are a key aspect of
`the international debate about the reasonableness of pharmaceutical prices and the magnitude of
`the long-term investments involved.
`
`Debate continues about whether the R&D productivity of the biopharmaceutical industry has
`fallen. Calculations based on annual rates of R&D spending and the number of new molecular
`(chemical or biological) entities launched suggest a declining trend in R&D productivity. But it
`takes a long time to develop a new drug, so comparing current R&D spending levels with the
`current number of new approvals is an inaccurate measure of R&D productivity, at best.
`
`Published estimates of the mean (average) cost of researching and developing a successful new
`medicine suggest an increased over the last decade—from the estimate of US$802m by DiMasi
`et al (2003) at 2000 prices (US$1,031m at 2011 prices) to the estimate by Paul et al (2010) of
`US$1,867m at 2011 prices. In this study, we present a new estimate, US$1,506m (at 2011
`prices), which lies within this range. Our analysis explores how these costs have been evolving
`and for what reasons.
`
`Mean estimates of R&D costs per new medicine and, in particular, drawing conclusions based
`on comparisons between estimates, should be treated with caution because of important
`differences in the studies, particularly in the use of different databases of drugs. Moreover,
`important differences exist across subgroups of drugs—for instance, by therapeutic area, by firm
`size and by compound origin.
`
`An important international policy debate continues about how much it costs to research and
`develop a successful new drug (NME2), be it chemical or biological. It is important to
`understand how much a new medicine costs to research and develop, identifying in particular
`the key drivers of changes in these costs over time, for at least two reasons:
`
`1. To help understand the reasonableness, or otherwise, of the prices sought by producers of
`new medicines
`2. Given R&D productivity challenges in recent years, companies must ensure that their
`R&D resources are spent optimally to maximise use of limited resources
`
`Monitoring and understanding R&D cost drivers is important in devising optimal responses to
`change. These responses, however, need to come from both policy makers and biopharmaceutical
`companies. On the one hand, the pharmaceutical industry is highly regulated (R&D, marketing
`authorisation, pricing) so there is a need to explore what actions regulators can take to make
`R&D more efficient—without compromising safety and efficacy and still ensuring that new
`drugs provide value for money. On the other hand, companies need to take appropriate action to
`increase R&D productivity, in part by improving the ability to assess accurately the value of
`pursuing or discontinuing projects.
`
`1 See, for example, Bogue (1965).
`2 Throughout the paper, we use the acronym “NME” (new molecular entity) to refer to a new product, whether chemical or
`biologic. Note that some other researchers instead use “NCE” (new chemical entity) and CMRI uses “NAS” (new active
`substance). See the Glossary for definitions of each term.
`
`1
`
`13
`
`

`

`INTRODUCTION AND CONTEXT
`
`With this as context, the objective of this publication is to provide an up-to-date overview of the
`literature estimating drug R&D costs. In this study, R&D costs are the costs of researching,
`developing and gaining regulatory approval for a successful new medicine. As described in more
`detail in Figure 2.1, R&D costs include pre-discovery costs (or basic research), pre-clinical (or
`discovery) costs, clinical (or development) costs, and costs associated with regulatory review. Pre-
`discovery and pre-clinical stages are sometimes jointly referred to as “discovery research” (the “R”
`of “R&D”). Clinical (or “development”) costs include Phase I, Phase II and Phase III costs (the
`“D” of “R&D”). R&D costs do not include Phase IV costs, studies done after marketing begins.
`We present some new observations on drug R&D costs, using previously unpublished evidence,
`and explore what we believe are the most important factors that are driving change in the key
`variables affecting costs.
`
`Context: Setting the Scene
`Debate continues about whether the R&D productivity of the pharmaceutical industry has
`decreased over time. The rationale of claiming it has decreased relies on comparing annual global
`pharmaceutical R&D spending (the “input”) and the number of NMEs launched (the “output”).
`Figure 1.1 shows pharmaceutical R&D spending since 1990 in Europe and in the US (in euros
`and US dollars, respectively). Rates of growth have suffered some peaks and troughs over the last
`two decades and especially over the last few years. Indeed, R&D spending in the US and Europe
`fell in 2008 and may have fallen again in 2011, but the general trend is a rising one.
`
`Figure 1.1. European and US R&D Spending
`
`Source: EFPIA (2012)
`
`While Figure 1.1 shows the evolution of the “input” variable, i.e. R&D spending, Table 1.1
`shows one way of measuring R&D “output” in the pharmaceutical industry—the number of
`new chemical or biological entities launched in the same time period.
`
`Table 1.1. Number of new chemical or biological entities (1990–2009)
`
`Number
`
`Total
`
`Average per year
`
`Source: EFPIA (2010a)
`
`1990–1994
`
`1995–1999
`
`2000–2004
`
`2005–2009
`
`162
`
`32
`
`146
`
`29
`
`215
`
`43
`
`207
`
`41
`
`2
`
`14
`
`

`

`INTRODUCTION AND CONTEXT
`
`Table 1.2 breaks down the 2005–2009 figures to show new entities reaching world markets since
`2005, year on year.
`
`Table 1.2. Number of new chemical or biological entities (2005-2009)
`
`Year
`
`2005
`
`2006
`
`2007
`
`2008
`
`2009
`
`Number
`
`30
`
`35
`
`25
`
`31
`
`25
`
`Source: EFPIA (2010a)
`
`Wang and McAuslane (2012) find that the European Medicines Agency (EMA) approved 13 and
`23 NMEs in 2010 and 2011, respectively, while the US Food and Drug Administration (FDA)
`approved 19 NMEs in 2010 and 32 in 2011.
`
`The number of new entities launched has decreased from an average of 43 per year between
`1990 and 1994 to around 30 or fewer per year over the last five years.
`
`If we use this data to crudely analyse R&D productivity, we can argue there has been a decline in
`productivity; the input (R&D spending) is growing while the output (measured by the number
`of NMEs) is decreasing. However, as explained in greater detail later in this publication, it takes
`considerable time to research, develop and gain approval for an NME; hence, the outputs we
`observe during recent years are the result of R&D that was done 10–15 years ago. It is important
`that we do not focus solely on the static relationship between R&D spending and NME count as
`the basis for conclusions about whether productivity has increased or decreased. Whether the
`productivity of recent R&D spending has decreased will not be clear until we can count the
`number of new successful entities launched in the next five to ten years.
`
`Closely related to the productivity discussion is another heavily debated issue about the
`pharmaceutical industry: how much it costs to develop a successful NME.
`
`Taking a high-level view, and without looking at the details of each of the studies that estimate
`these costs, the costs of researching and developing a new drug appear to have increased
`significantly over the last decades. Indeed, Barker (2010) argues that “the current model for
`developing new drugs is becoming unaffordable” (page 357). The latest estimate places the cost
`of a successful drug, from the start of the R&D process to marketing approval, at around
`US$1.9b (Paul et al, 2010) in 2011 prices3. In 2003 these costs were estimated to be US$1.0b in
`2011 prices (DiMasi et al, 2003), which itself was a large increase on an earlier estimate of
`US$451m in 2011 prices in the early 1990s (DiMasi et al, 1991).
`
`Later in this publication we present our own new R&D costs estimate, based on our analysis of
`unpublished data collected by CMRI. Our estimate, US$1.5b in 2011 prices, lies within the
`US$1.0b–US$1.9b range. But, as argued in the next section, we need to be cautious when
`comparing the different estimates.
`
`3 Throughout the paper, we have updated all costs estimates to 2011 prices using the US GDP implicit price deflator.
`
`3
`
`15
`
`

`

`INTRODUCTION AND CONTEXT
`
`Ideally, given that our main interest is to identify trends in real costs per successful NME, we
`would base this estimate on information from all successful NMEs over time. But such
`comprehensive information is not available. The various estimates that are available, moreover,
`use different databases, many of which cannot be compared as they contain confidential, project-
`specific information, and drugs of different vintages; conclusions based on comparisons across
`studies that use different databases should be treated with caution. To explore trends, we
`compare across studies that use similar databases and methodologies. This allows us to identify
`how the various elements that make up total R&D cost have been evolving over time.
`
`The R&D cost per new medicine approved is indeed increasing. The reasons for the increase are
`multiple—from higher cash

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket