throbber

`
`Koios Pharmaceuticals v. Medac
`
`Medac Exhibit 2054
`
`IPR2016-01370
`
`Page 00001
`
`Medac Exhibit 2054
`Koios Pharmaceuticals v. Medac
`IPR2016-01370
`Page 00001
`
`

`

`THE OXFORD HANDBOOK OF
`
`THE ECONOMICS
`
`OF THE
`
`BIOPHARMACEUTICAL
`
`INDUSTRY
`
`Page 00002
`
`Page 00002
`
`

`

`
`
`CONS ULTING EDITORS
`
`MICHAEL SZENBERG
`
`LUBIN SCHOOL OF BUSINESS, PACE UNIVERSITY
`
`LALL RAMRATTAN
`
`UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY EXTENSION
`
`Page 00003
`
`Page 00003
`
`

`

`THE OXFORD HANDBOOK OF
`
`THE ECONOMICS
`
`OF THE
`
`BIOPHARMACEUTICAL
`
`INDUSTRY
`
`Edited by
`
`PATRICIA M. DANZON
`
`AND
`
`SEAN NICHOLSON
`
`Page 00004
`
`Page 00004
`
`

`

`OXFORD
`UNIVERSITY PRESS
`
`Oxford University Press, Inc., publishes works lhat further
`Oxford University's objective of excellence
`in research, scholarship, and education.
`Oxford New York
`
`Auckland Cape Town Dar es Salaam lIong Kong Karachi
`Kuala Lumpur Madrid Melbourne Mexico City Nairobi
`New Delhi Shanghai Taipei Toronto
`With offices in
`
`Argentina Austria Brazil Chile Czech Republic France Greece
`Guatemala Hungary
`Italy
`Iapan Poland Portugal Singapore
`South Korea Switzerland Thailand Turkey Ukraine Vietnam
`
`Copyright © 2012 by Oxford University Press
`
`Published by Oxford University Press, Inc.
`193 Madison Avenue, New York, New York 10016
`www.0up.com
`
`Oxford is a registered trademark of Oxford University Press
`
`All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced,
`stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by anyineans,
`electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording. or otherwise.
`without the prior permission of Oxford University Press.
`
`Library of Congre5s Cataloging—in-Publication Dala
`The Oxford handbook of the economics of the biopharmaceulica] industry 1‘
`edited by Patricia M. Danzon and Sean Nicholscm.
`p. cm.
`Includes bibliographical references and indexes.
`lSBN 978—0-19-974299-8 (cloth : alk. paper)
`1. Pharmaceutical industry.
`2. Biopharmaceutics-Economic aspects.
`I. Danzon, Patricia Munch, 1946—
`II. Nicholson, Sean.
`III. ‘I‘ille: Economies of the biopharmaceutical industry.
`HD9665.5.094 2012
`338.4’76157-dc23
`2011040815
`
`1 3 5 7 9 3 6 4 2
`Printed in the United States of A merica
`on acid—free paper
`
`Page 00005
`
`Page 00005
`
`

`

`CONTENTS
`
`Contributors
`
`1.
`
`Introduction
`
`PATRICIA M. DANZON AND SEAN NICHOLSON
`
`PART I PHARMACEUTICAL INNOVATION
`
`2. R&D Costs and Returns to New Drug Development:
`A Review of the Evidence
`
`JOSEPH A; DIMASI AND HENRY G. GRABOWSKI
`
`3. Financing Research and Development
`SEAN NICHOLSON
`
`4. Cost of Capital for Pharmaceutical, Biotechnology,
`and Medical Device Firms
`SCOTT E. HARRINGTON
`
`5. The Regulation of Medical Products
`ANUP MALANI AND TOMAS PHILIPSON
`
`6. Incentives to Innovate
`DARIUS LAKDAWALLA AND NEERA] SOOD
`
`7. Patents and Regulatory Exclusivity
`REBECCA S. EISENBERG
`
`vii
`
`1
`
`21
`
`47
`
`75
`
`'
`
`100
`
`143
`
`167
`
`PART II THE MARKET FOR PHARMACEUTICALS
`
`8. Pricing and Reimbursement in US Pharmaceutical Markets
`ERNST R. BERNDT AND JOSEPH P. NEWHOUSE
`
`9. Regulation of Price and Reimbursement for Pharmaceuticals
`PATRICIA M. DANZON
`
`201
`
`266
`
`Page 00006
`
`Page 00006
`
`

`

`
`
`vi
`
`10.
`
`IL
`
`11
`
`13.
`
`14.
`
`15.
`
`16.
`
`17.
`
`18.
`
`Drugs and Vaccines for Developing Countries
`ADRIAN Towss, ERIC KEUFFEL, HANNAH E. KETTLER,
`AND DAVID B. RIDLEY
`
`Insurance and Drug Spending
`MARK V. PAULY
`
`Consumer Demand and Health Effects of Cost-Sharing
`DANA P. GOLDMAN AND GEOFFREY F. JOYCE
`
`Measuring Value: Pharmacoeconomics Theory and Practice
`ADRIAN TOWSE, MICHAEL DRUMMOND,
`AND CORINNA SORENSON
`
`Price Indexes for Prescription Drugs: A Review of the Issues
`ANA AIZCORBE AND NICOLE NESTORIAK
`
`Empirical Evidence on the Value of Pharmaceuticals
`CRAIG GARTHWAITE AND MARK DUGGAN
`
`Promotion to Physicians and Consumers
`DON KENKEL AND ALAN MATHlos
`
`The Economics of Vaccines
`FRANK A. SLOAN
`
`Mergers, Acquisitions, and Alliances
`HENRY G. GRABOWSKI AND MARGARET KYLE
`
`Index
`
`CONTENTS
`
`302
`
`336
`
`355
`
`394
`
`463
`
`493
`
`524
`
`552
`
`579
`
`Page 00007
`
`Page 00007
`
`

`

`
`
`CHAPTER 5
`
`THE REGULATION OF
`
`MEDICAL PRODUCTS
`
`ANUP MALANI AND
`
`TOMAS PHILIPSON
`
`IMPROVEMENTS in health have been a major component of overall gain in eco-
`nomic welfare in the last century (Cutler and Richardson 1998; Murphy and Tape]
`2006). Part of these health gains are attributable to medical research (Cutler and
`McClellan 2001; Murphy and Topel 2003; Lichtenberg 2003; Cutler et a1. 2007). hi
`the same time, the cost of health care has tripled in real terms since 1965 and new
`accounts for more than 17 percent ofthe gross dornestic product (GDP). Evidence
`exists to suggest that a large share of this cost growth is driven by technologi-
`cal innovation (Newhouse 1992), including the cost ofmedical products such as
`drugs. The large role of innovation in explaining both improvements in health
`and health care cost growth suggests that it is important to understand the medi‘
`cal research and development (R&D) process and how it is regulated.
`In virtually all developed countries and many developing countries, the 3°“
`ernment provides regulatory oversight over the quality of products generated bl
`medical innovation. In the United States, this oversight is conducted by the US
`Food and Drug Administration (FDA), which regulates drugs, medical devices»
`biologics (products made from living organisms, such as vaccines and blood pIGd'
`ucts), cosmetics, radiation-emitting electronic products, veterinary products. and
`f90ds' According to the FDA: the products it regulates account for more than 0116'
`filth ofUS consumer spending. In the area of medical products, the agencyreview
`w ether drugs and many deVices are safe and effective both before and after lhfl
`have been cleared for sale.
`has :2:;::::;:: in which the FDA regulates the qualit),r of drugs and‘devilclt‘:
`Impact on the cost of their development. The FDA “3‘1"”est a
`
`3
`
`i
`
`!
`!
`l
`
` .4‘
`
`Page 00008
`
`Page 00008
`
`

`

`2
`
`__
`
`-_
`
`I
`
`II
`
`1 l | lII
`
`I
`I
`
`=
`
`' I
`
`1 |
`
`
`
`Page 00009
`
`THEREGULATIONOFMEDICALPRODUCTS
`
`companies conduct clinical trials to demonstrate that their medical products are
`safe and effective. These trials account for a large portion of the total development
`costs of these products (DiMasi et al. 2003; Adams and Brantner 2006). In addi-
`tion, completion of trials does not guarantee that a product will be approved. This
`risk of nonapproval compounds the cost of product development (DiMasi et al.
`2003}.
`
`101
`
`Despite the central role of the FDA in regulating the quality and R&D costs of
`medical products, economists have conducted relatively little theoretical or empir-
`ical research on the efficiency of FDA policies. Ironically, if a product application
`Were presented to the FDA with the scant amount of evidenCe that currently exists
`on the efficiency of the policies of the agency itself, such an application would
`likely be rejected on the basis of insufficient evidence. In this chapter, we synthew
`size and extend, in a nontechnical manner, recent research on the FDA. Our aim is
`
`to shed light on whether the policies ofthe agency itselfare safe and effective when
`measured in terms of economic efficiency.
`The first section provides an overview of the role of the FDA in regulating
`
`pharmaceuticaldrugsandmedicaldevices.Thesecondsectionsurveystheexist-
`
`ing efficiency rationales for government regulation of the information about and
`the quality of medical products and then canvasses the literature for empirical
`studies on the effects of FDA regulation on innovation and costs. The final section
`examines the growing role of tort law—specifically, products liability litigation—in
`
`supplementing FDA regulation of drug quality.
`To understand the relationship of this chapter to others in this book, it is
`helpful to break government influence on medical product innovation into five
`parts. The first is the use of property rights over innovation to encourage invest-
`ment in R&D. The second is direct government spending on R&D. The third
`is premarketing screening of new drugs and devices by the FDA. The fourth is
`postmarketing regulation of medical products by courts (and perhaps the FDA).
`The last is demand for medical products by government-run health insurance
`systems such as Medicare and Medicaid. This chapter focuses on the third and
`fourth categories; that is, the role of quality and safety regulation in directing
`innovation.
`
`FDA REGULATION OF DRUGS, DEVICES,
`
`AND BIOLOGICS
`
`Drugs
`
`The US government began regulating drugs with the 1906 Food and Drug Act.
`That statute prohibited companies from selling misbranded or adulterated
`
`Page 00009
`
`

`

`PHARMACEUTICAL INNOVATION
`
`drugs. Using a modern example, aspirin would be misbranded ifits label stated
`that it was ibuprofen. A drug is adulterated ifit is tainted with a poison or some
`other dangerous substance. The 1906 Act was targeted mainly at quack pat-
`ent medicines and regulated drugs largely after they had already been sold to
`consumers.
`
`extremely toxic, are performed on terminally ill cancer patients.
`
`Since 1962, drug development can be broken down into two parts. The first
`is in vitro and animal testing. If this proves successful, a company may apply to
`the FDA for permission to conduct clinical trials on humans. The application is
`called an Investigational New Drug (IND) application (FD8IC Act, §505(i)). The
`FDA uses the power to approve human testing to regulate the nature of trials con—
`ducted by a company. The FDA works with companies to determine appropriate
`endpoints for clinical evaluation and the sample size required for trials. It may also
`provide guidance on the level ofefficacy or safety that would help clear the way for
`drug approval.
`Clinical testing in turn has three phases. Phase 1 involves studies to determine
`the toxicology ofa drug. A small number of healthy humans2 are gradually given
`increasing doses of a drug to determine how toxic it is. If the dosage can be raised
`to pharmacologically effective closes with tolerable side effects, the drug passes
`phase 1. Phase 2 involves medium—sized studies to identify early evidence that the
`drug is effective in humans. These studies often do not have a control group. Ifthe
`drug demonstratésefficacy relative to historical controls or the expectations of
`the company and the FDA, the drug passes phase 2. In phase 3, the company must
`typically conduct two large, well—controlled trials of a drug’s safety and efficacy.
`
`The United States government did not screen drugs before permitting them to
`be Sold to consumers until the enactment of the Federal Food, Drug, and Cosmetic
`Act (FD8:C Act) in 1938. That statute required that drugs be proved safe before they
`could be sold to consumers. Companies did not have to prove drugs were effective,
`though the FDA could prevent marketing of a drug if the agency could demon-
`strate it did not work. In practice, however, there was no premarket screening of
`drugs for efficacy. In 1962, following a public health scare in which a number of
`children were born with serious birth defects after their mothers used thalido—
`
`mide to reduce morning sickness during pregnancy, the US Congress amended
`the FDStC Act to require that a company provide substantial evidence that its new
`drug is both safe and effective before it could sell that drug (FD&C Act, §§505(a)
`and (d)).1
`
`. This is also the standard now applied to biologics, which are defined by the Public
`Health Service Act §351(i) as “any virus, therapeutic serum, toxin, antitOXin, vaccine,
`blood, blood component or derivative, allergenic product, or analogous product
`applicable to the prevention, treatment or cure ofa disease or c0ndition ofhuman
`beings.” That Act states that biologics are to be regulated under the FD8ZC Act, and the
`FDA has interpreted the term “drug” in the FD&C Act to cover biologics.
`. An exception is cancer drugs. Phase 1 studies of these drugs, because they are
`
`Page 00010
`
`

`

`
`
`THE REGULATION OF MEDICAL PRODUCTS
`
`
`Preclinical
`Clinical
`LApproval
`Market
`.
`y
`*3
`Q
`Toxtcology E gag
`;
`
`
`
`
`
`
`a a a.
`“5: 2 3
`H
`
`
`
`j"
`'3
`
`.
`
`.
`
`_
`
`.I
`
`-.
`'
`
`
`:
`_' :
`I
`
`_
`-
`
`5
`5
`
`_
`
`'
`
`;
`I
`l
`
`i
`
`
`
`
`
`=
`._.
`u
`:
`3
`a“
`s
`«I:
`
`‘“
`safety
`efficacy
`.
`side eflects
`
`H
`1‘3
`.12:
`tn
`
`safety
`
`safety
`dosing
`‘
`c[l1cacy
`
`a E
`i- "'2
`2
`g a
`4:
`
`w
`s :3 “3
`E E g
`E .1. 3
`m H
`9* a a
`
`$15.2 million $23.5 million $86.5 million
`21.6 months lg] months 30.5 months
`61.011 years
`
`0.6 to 2 yearsl 11 to 14 years
`
`Expenses
`Time
`lto 6 years
`Overall probability ofsuccess
`30%
`14%
`9%
`8%
`
`"h-
`—p
`b
`r
`r— —*
`It
`
`Conditional probability of success
`90%
`64%
`48%
`40%
`75%
`
`-+— + —+
`v— +— —r
`
`r-
`
`Figure 5.1 Overview of the drug development process.
`Source: From Philipson and Sun, zoos.
`
`The trials are typically randomized and blinded and use placebos or conventional
`treatments as controls.
`Ifa new drug passes phase 3 with significant evidence of efficacy and a reason-
`able safety profile, the company may file a New Drug Application (NDA) to obtain
`approval from the FDA to market the drug. The FDA reviews the data to ensure
`that there is substantial evidence of efficacy and that the drug has been demon—
`strated to be safe. In practice, the FDA balances the value of efficacy from the
`drug against the cost in terms of side effects when deciding to approve a drug. For
`example, the agency may tolerate greater side effects from a drug that treats a more
`serious medical condition or a drug that dramatically improves health outcomes.
`The overall review process, from preclinical testing to NBA approval, is illustrated
`in Figure 5.1, which is reproduced from Philipson and Sun (2008}.
`Drugs are approved for particular uses. This does not prevent doctors from
`prescribing an approved drug for alternative uses. Such “off-label” uses are quite
`common, for example, in oncology. Use—specific approval does, however, prevent
`companies from advertising unapproved uses to doctors and patients.3 If a com-
`pany seeks to market a drug for as yet unapproved uses, it must conduct studies to
`demonstrate that the drug is safe and effective for those uses.
`
`3. Because of First Amendment protection for truthful commercial speech. however,
`companies can share peer—reviewed articles about unapproved uses, so long as they are
`not accompanied by nonacademic marketing [Washington Legal Foundation v Henney,
`1999}.
`
`=
`
`_
`
`;
`
`_
`
`
`
`Page 00011
`
`Page 00011
`
`

`

`
`
`104 PHARMACEUTICAL INNOVATION
`
`The incomplete regulation of off-label use highlights an important limitation
`in the federal regime for drug regulation. A drug need only be approved for one use
`to be available for almost any use that doctors may pursue. This affects a drug com-
`pany’s decision about the specific use for which to seek approval from the FDA. A
`company will consider the use for which proving safety and efficacy is easiest as
`well as the use for which marketing is most important. It also affects the value of
`the FDA’s regulation. If only a fraction of uses are screened by the FDA, the drug
`market is only partially regulated by the FDA.‘
`The FD&C Act does not merely require a drug to be safe and effective; it also
`rquires that the drug be labeled so that a doctor can prescribe the drug to patients
`in a manner that will ensure proper sorting of drugs to patients. The FDA screens
`a new drug’s label before the drug is approved for marketing and may require that
`the label be amended as the agency receives new information about a drug after
`approval. The label must describe not only indications for use but also inter alia
`contraindications and side effects.
`Clinical testing does not end once a drug has been approved for marketing.
`I Although the FDA does not have the formal authority to require clinical testing
`after a drug is approved, it may hold up drug approval unless the drug company
`“voluntarily” agrees to conduct so-called phase 4 clinical trials. Although some of
`these phase 4 obligations involve placebo—controlled trials, many require long—term
`and large-scale observational studies. The purpose of these studies is to identify
`side effects that are serious but so rare that even phase 3 trials are not sufficiently
`
`provided.
`
`large to detect them.
`One problem identified soon after passage of the 1962 Amendments to the
`FDSrC Act was that companies stopped developing and fully testing drugs for rare
`conditions-The financial burden of clinical testing exceeded the small expected
`revenue from these drugs. Congress addressed this problem in 1983 with the
`Orphan Drug Act. That statute provided companies that developed drugs for rare
`conditions, defined as diseases that affect fewer than 200,000 people annually, tax
`credits to offset their clinical testing costs and seven "years of market exclusivity
`(FDSrC Act §§526, 527).
`-
`i
`'
`.-
`,
`A second "set of_ problems with the 1962 Amendments was that they both
`reduced effective patent life for pioneer new drugs and hampered entry of generic
`versions of these drugs into the market. The long time needed for the FDA to
`review NDAs reduced effective patent life, defined as the number of remaining
`years a company has to market a drug under its patent monopoly following FDA
`approval. This in turn reduced the incentive to innovate. Once a patent expired,
`
`4. This gap in the regulatory regime is partly addressed by the tendency of insurance
`companies to refuse reimbursement for off—label prescription of drugs. But such
`off~label use is difficult to monitor and can often be evaded by administering drugs
`on an inpatient basis at a hospital (rather than in a physician’s office), because hospital
`reimbursement is largely based on a patient’s diagnosis, not the specific treatment
`
`Page 00012
`
`

`

`
`
`_THE REGULATION OF MEDICAL PRODUCTS 105
`
`
`
`however, the Amendments required a generic drug company to perform the same
`Clinical trials that were performed to gain approval for the pioneer drug. The low
`expected profits on generic drugs made such testing unprofitable. Although the
`second problem offset the first, it was not the how Congress intended the patent
`system and the FDSIC Act to interact.
`'
`In 1984 Congress addressed both problems with the so—called Hatch-Waxman
`Act. This statute extended a drug company’s patent on a pioneer drug to partly
`offset the time required for clinical testing and FDA review. The extension was
`capped at 5 years and could never extend effective patent life beyond 15 years.5 In
`return, generic drug companies were not required to conduct trials demonstrating
`that their drugs were safe and effective. Instead, they could market their drugs so
`long as they demonstrated that their drugs were bioequivalent to a pioneer drug
`whose patent had expired or had been invalidated (FD8<C Act §5o5(j)).
`Congress once more took aim at long FDA review times in 1992 with the
`Prescription Drug Users Fee Act (PDUFA). That Act required drug companies to
`pay a user fee to fund resources the FDA could use to speed up the drug approval
`process. In return, the Act required the FDA to commit to deadlines for complet-
`ing its drug reviews. PDUFA was written to expire in five years, but it has repeat-
`edly been renewed.
`
`years.
`
`Devices
`
`Medical device regulation has lagged behind drug regulation in the United
`States. Whereas the 1906 Food and Drug Act prohibited the misbranding or
`adulteration of drugs, devices did not have such restrictions until passage of the
`1938 FDSIC Act. Likewise, whereas the 1938 Act and then the 1962 Amendments
`introduced premarket screening of drugs, there was no premarket screening of
`devices until 1976.
`The 1976 Medical Device Amendments introduced three tiers of regulation
`that finally provided for prernarket screening of certain devices. This new regime
`first sorted devices into three classes and then prescribed different levels of regu-
`lation for the difference classes (FD&C Act §513). Class I devices are Subject only
`to prohibitions on misbranding and adulteration. Class 11 devices are subject to
`these prohibitions and also to certain performance standards developed by the
`FDA. For example, for a device to be labeled an x-ray machine it must meet cer-
`tain guidelines for the quality of its beam and the amount of radiation that the
`
`5. The statute also guaranteed that the FDA would not permit any generic drug
`manufacturer to market a drug within 5 years. This was important to pioneer
`companies, because a generic maker is permitted to sue to invalidate a pioneer’s drug _
`patent before it formally expires. The delayed FDA approval ensured that, even if a
`generic won its patent suit, the pioneer company would enjoy market exclusivity for 5
`
`Page 00013
`
`

`

`
`
`106 PHARMACEUTICAL INNOVATION
`
`EVALUATION OF FDA REGULATION
`
`Rationale for Government Regulation
`
`FDA regulation of medical products has two basic components. The first is pro-
`duction and dissemination of information and analysis about the quality of drugs
`and devices. This is embodied in the FDA’s requirements that companies produce
`data to demonstrate safety and efficacy and that drug and device labels report indi-
`cations as well as contraindications and adverse effects. The second is a minimum
`quality regulation. This is directly embodied in the FDA’s rule that drugs and cer-
`tain devices cannot be sold until they have been demonstrated to be safe and effec—
`tive. It is indirectly implemented in the FDA’s rule that class II devices must meet
`«a
`certain performance standards.
`
`machine may leak (21 CFR 1020.30). Finally, class III devices are regulated much
`like new drugs. Manufacturers must provide data that demonstrate both safety and
`effectiveness. The Amendments sort devices into a class based largely on whether
`the FDA believes that the level of regulation implied by that class is Sufficient to
`reasonably ensure that the device is safe and effective for consumers. Roughly 30
`percent of devices fall in class I, 60 percent in class II, and 10 percent in class III
`(Hutt et al. 2007).
`Since the 1976 Amendments, the development of device regulation has largely
`tracked that of drug regulation. The Orphan Drug Act and the Hatch—Waxman
`Act included provisions for devices. And in 2002, Congress extended PDUFA tO
`apply to medical devices.
`
`(Malani et al. 2009).
`
`Production of Information
`In order to justify the government provision of information, One must explain
`why markets do not produce enough information and why the government should
`step in to do so. Perhaps the production of information is a public good and free—
`riding causes inefficiently iow levels of information to be produced (Musgrave
`1959}. Alternatively, the government may be more efficient at providing informa-
`tion. Perhaps the government has more expertise, or perhaps patients (and doctors
`they might hire to help them) have cognitive limitations.‘S Or perhaps there are
`
`6. This concept is embedded in the average patient standard that the FDA employs. By
`barring drugs that may benefit some patients but not the average patient, the FDA is
`assuming that they are better at sorting different patients to a drug than doctors are
`
`Page 00014
`
`

`

`107
`THE REGULATION OF MEDICAL PRODUCTS
`
`economies of scale in data analysis. It may be more efficient for one entity to ana-
`lyze the data than for each patient to do it on her own.
`Even if one concludes that the government should provide information ab0ut a
`product, there remain important questions about which party—the medical prod-
`uct company, a third private party, or the government—is best suited to produce__ .
`that information and who should pay for the production of that information. The
`producer of the medical product may have private information about the product
`that places it in the best position to test the product. For example, it knows which
`patient group is most likely to benefit. The drug producer and its consumers are
`also entities who gain from information that the product is safe and effective.
`An alternative to testing by the producer is testing by a third private party or
`the government. One concern with permitting medical product companies to test
`their own products is that their studies may be biased in favor of their products.
`Studies have documented that clinical trials conducted by authors with financial
`conflicts from drug companies tend to report larger treatment effects than studies
`without such conflicts (Bekelman et a1. 2003; Lexchin et al. 2003). However, gov—
`ernment—run studies may take longer to complete, and this is a problem because
`delay is costly to producers, who lose monopoly profits under their patents, but not
`to the government. Another problem is that government studies may have a bias
`toward finding that drugs have side effects. Indeed, the FDA has been criticized for
`being overly cautious with drugs, because although the agency is not given credit
`for new effective drugs, it is blamed when it permits an unsafe drug to enter the
`market. (To be fair, the FDA has also been criticized for being captured by the drug
`
`them to do so. A more precise cost-benefit analysis would weigh the cost ofthe
`
`industry.)
`The question of who should fund the FDA’s mission to produce information is
`in part a question about efficiency and in part a question about equity. There is a
`large optimal taxation literature that discusses which sorts oftaxes are able to raise
`a given quantum of revenue with minimum distortions. The lessons there apply to
`the FDA context. However. one consideration that favors taxing medical product
`companies to fund clinical research is that doing so may bypass the administrative
`costs of collecting taxes from third parties. Questions about equity are perhaps
`beyond the ken of economists. But one factor implying that a company and its
`consumers should not be disproportionately taxed to pay for research on the com-
`pany’s product is that information suggesting that a product is not safe or effective
`benefits individuals who do not consume the company’s product and perhaps the
`company’s competitors. This favors a broader tax, although perhaps not so broad
`as to extend to individuals who are not in the market for a medical product.
`Whereas efficient and fair production of information is important, the cen-
`tral concern with the government’s decision to produce information is whether
`the benefits of that information are worth the costs? In chapter 2 of this volume,
`
`7. Medical product companies would conduct R&D and thus produce some information-'-
`about product quality even in the absence ofany government regulation requiring
`
`Page 00015
`
`

`

`
`
`108 PHARMACEUTICAL INNOVATION
`
`DiMasi and Grabowski document the large and growing costs of clinical testing.
`According to DiMasi et al. (2003), a commonly cited study, the cost of completing
`three phases of clinical testing is roughly $200 million. Ofcourse many drugs are
`abandoned before testing is completed. Typically only one in five completes testing
`and is approved bythe FDA for sale. If the cost of testing is normalized by the num-
`ber of successful drugs, one obtains estimates of clinical testing costs in the range
`of $800 million per approved drug.
`Whichever estimate is used, this cost must be balanced against the benefits of
`clinical testing. Note that this is not the same question as whether the revenue from
`a nieuical product exceeds the cost ofclinical testing. The revenue reflects both the
`value of the medical product and the value of information about the product. To
`the extent that doctors would use the medical product without the information, the
`revenue does not reflect the value of information. If, however, doctors would use
`the product on a different population ofpatients when provided with the informa-
`tion, then the additional benefit to this new population of users minus the avoided
`costs to the old users is a benefit ofinformation.
`In an early, seminal paper on the value of FDA regulation, Peltzman (1973)
`attempted to capture some of these ideas in a graph along the lines of that in
`Figure 5.2, panels A and B. Suppose that a typical consumer’s demand for a drug
`before the FDA provides any information on the drug is represented by the line
`DD. The price of the drug is p, so the equilibrium quantity is (1.3 (These initial
`demand and supply curves are drawn in bold to distinguish them.) The graph
`does not capture all facets ofthe drug market, specifically the fact that there may
`be a monopoly producer that charges a price higher than marginal cost and that
`changes price in response to demand shifts. But it is a useful simplification that
`makes the following important point: because the consumer may not have accu-
`rate information about the value ofthe drug, we cannot conclude from the graph
`that the surplus is the triangular area under DD but above p?
`After the FDA provides the consumer information, demand might shift either
`in (panel A) or out {panel B) to line D’D’ (Peltzman 1973; McGuire et a1. 1975). A shift
`inward could occur if the FDA demonstrated that the drug is less safe and effective
`than previously thought. A shift outward could reflect either an FDA assessment that
`
`welfare calculations.
`
`additional information the government requires against the benefit of that additional
`information.
`_
`
`. To keep matters simple, we ignore complications from, for example, health insurance
`(Lakdawalla and Sood 2006, 2009) and pharmaceutical advertising (Lakdawalla et al.
`2006). These features make the calculation of welfare more complicated.
`. We ignore philosophical issues such as whether welfare can be calculated by using
`subjective expected utility. With subjective utility, consumer perceptions are important
`to welfare and the area under DD but abovep may provide some measure ofwelfare.
`Instead, for simplicity, we assume that only objectively verified benefits matter for
`
`Page 00016
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`
`Units
`qq‘
`D
`0’ Units
`5'
`i
`ofdrug
`ofdrug
`.
`g”
`A: Decrease in demand following disclosure
`B: Increase in demand following disclosure
`'
`
`'
`
`-
`
`I
`
`
`
`
`
`U$iunit
`
`D
`
`UMunir
`
`D
`
`D'
`
`q
`
`0
`
`q’
`
`L] D'
`
`D
`
`Units
`Units
`*1)
`of drug
`ofdrug
`'
`D: Minimum qualily standard above [3
`C: Minimum quality standard below p
`Figure 5.2 Welfare effect from production ofinformation and
`minimum quality standards.
`
`I
`,
`the drug is more safe or effective than previously thought,” patients’increased con-
`fidence in estimates about a drug’s value, or (looking past our model of a represen~
`tative patient) a better sorting of patients to drugs. These shifted demand curves can
`be used to calculate welfare because they reflect “true” information. Whichever way
`demand shifts. the price of the drug may rise to p’ because of the cost ofeither pro-
`ducing information or conveying that information to consumers.11
`
`10. Peltzman {1975) argued that this scenario is unlikely because companies have an
`incentive not to undersell their drugs prior to regulation. However, this does not rule
`out an increase in demand resulting from the other causes listed.
`11.Producing information can entail both fixed and variable costs, which may not be
`reflected in price in a straightforward fashion. For example, the cost of information_
`may depend on the quantity of the drug consumed in equilibrium. To keep matters
`simple, we ignore this comple‘irity in Figure 5.2.
`
`-_:
`
`.
`
`-_:'
`I
`
`r
`
`-
`
`'i
`
`'
`
`_
`
`'
`
`"
`
`'
`
`_
`
`-
`
`'
`
`-
`
`g
`
`;
`
`I
`
`Page 00017
`
`Page 00017
`
`

`

`If demand shifts inward to DU as in panel A. the consumer’s surplus before
`production of information (“preregulatiOn”) has two parts. The first part is the
`area under DD and above p. This triangle represents the “true” surplus from con-
`sumption up to quantity q*. The second part is actually a loss, equivalent to the
`gray triangle. This is consumption between (3* and q that costs more than it is
`truly worth to the consumer. After the production of information (“postregula—
`tion”), the consumer’s surplus is the area under D'D' but above p’. The higher price
`reflects the cost of producing informatiOn. The net gain from the production of
`information is the gray—shaded triangle minus the line-shaded area. The former
`represents the avoidance of excessively costly consumption, and the latter reflects
`the cost of informatiOn. The net gain could be positive and thus increase welfare or
`
`negative and thus decrease it.
`If, instead, demand shifts out to D’D’ as in panel B after the production of
`information, the preregulation surplus is the area under D’D’ and above p, but it is
`bounded on the right by the quantity 9*. This area represents the true surplus from
`preregulation consumption of quantity 9*. The postregulation surplus is the area
`under D'D’ and above p'. This is consumer surplus at the elevated level of demand
`after accounting for higher prices due to the cost of producing information. The
`net gain from regulation is the gray-shaded triangle minus the line-shaded rectan—
`gle. The former is extra surplus extracted clu

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket