throbber
D0wm’0ardedfm:n UVA-DARE. me r'rJ.s'rmn‘i:J:1a! reprJsirr)rj-'r;f'II1e U:I1‘w.r.s'fr_v qfA:n.wer:IanI (UM)
`hrr;).'//fncfl. handle. net/ I I 245/2,6596}
`
`File ID
`Filename
`Version
`
`uvapub:8596 1
`Thesis
`unknown
`
`SOURCE (OR PART OF THE FOLLOWING SOURCE}:
`Type
`PhD thesis
`Title
`The world's first stock exchange: how the Amsterdam market for Dutch
`East India Company shares became a modern securities market, 1602-1700
`L.O. Petram
`FGw: Instituut voor Cultuur en Geschiedenis (ICG}
`2011
`
`Author(s}
`Faculty
`Year
`
`FULL BIBLIOGRAPHIC DETAILS:
`
`http:H'11dl.hand1e.net;'1124531.342 701
`
`('<>pyr'fghf
`
`it is nor pe’.*'.'r.':'r.'r.>d :0 downfoad or R) finm-cird/di.m'fb1rre we ran 0:-part qffl wm‘1m.ur the consent ofrhcz cm.'hor(.x‘J emu’/or
`cop_1>rur'g:':.' hofderfsj, otherrhun_/firsiricdyperzsanai. Indh=."d:ra)‘ use. 3.-niexs me work is rmde:-an open cumem Fir.-ence (like
`("rear:'1-‘e ('rJ:mn0n.\‘}_
`
`Uv.«l-DzIRI;‘ .''.v u .w+r‘1'."c(* ,r::'ovfo'¢’d by the :|':'h.rmj1‘ nfmc Um'w2r.s:'I_1‘ afA.'u.-;nm."r.-in rJ:r:;:.‘fIrkrm*..-rarer. M)
`fprrgedcrre.‘ 3014- I 3-]! J
`
`1
`
`TS1012
`
`1
`
`TS 1012
`
`

`
`THE WORLD’S FIRST STOCK EXCHANGE
`
`How the Amsterdam market for Dutch East India Company
`
`shares became a modern securities market, 1602-1700
`
`Lodewijk Petram
`
`2
`
`

`
`Frontcoverz Gen-it Adliaensz. Berckheyde, Town hall on Dam Square (1672), detail,
`Rjjksmuseum Amsterdam
`
`3
`
`

`
`THE WORLD’S FIRST STOCK EXCHANGE
`
`How the Amsterdam market for Dutch East India Company
`
`shares became a modern securities market, 1602-1700
`
`ACADEMISCH PROEFSCHRIFT
`
`tL’1‘\-1:rkr"ijgi11g V2111 dc graad van doctor
`aan de Unix-'e1‘siteiL van Amsterdam
`
`op gezag \-"an do Rector Maglfificlls
`prof. dr. D.C. van den Boom
`Lt:-.n over:-itaan van rrrcn door h(*.L College voor promotics in gcstciclc
`commissie, in hot openbaar Le verclecfigen in do Auia der U11iVf.’.I'Silt‘it
`
`op vrijdag 28januari 201 1, to 13.00 our
`
`door
`
`Lodewijk Otto Petram
`
`gclJorcn to Apcldoorn
`
`4
`
`

`
`5
`
`

`
`CONTENTS
`
`List of figures
`
`List of tables
`
`List of maps
`
`List of abbreviations
`
`Introduction
`
`Confexl, fzisioriogropfgy and tnoog-'
`Scope and mzaciure
`.S‘ou:rce*s
`
`Part I - Taking the measure of the market
`
`1
`
`A chronology of the market
`Introduction
`
`1' 602 - 77:9 s‘z£oscrij:£ion
`I 607 - T722 einergonre gyro darn.-‘alive: niorket
`1 609- I 0 - Isonr: Jo M'nire
`I 60.9 {:9 -- Firs! dioidersd ciinrié-nzions
`
`I 61' 1' - Exchange building
`1 622 - T729 relation oeitonzn lite co-nrtpnny and its 5;''1oJ'ef1oz'(t'er5
`.3 6305 and 1' 640.5‘ - Intenrzodiolion and o rfzongtirqg tron:/,=oJitz'on ofitfte trading conznznnigv
`I 6603 - Tranifrzg .c£'nb5 and rosconma
`Conrfrtriortr
`
`2
`
`Long-term developments
`Intmdzrclion
`
`.-"M{oi'k££ ortiz.-fig):
`..-’\"ionoer yonder’:
`.S'I':on= pm and dirndenrir
`Divergent (J'eoez'o,{Jn1£n£§.' Anmemirtrrr and /Jrrip/taint’ rrznrfcets
`Concfnrions
`
`VII
`
`VII]
`
`VIII
`
`IX
`
`6
`
`17
`E7
`E7
`20
`24
`
`28
`30
`32
`36
`45
`
`59
`:39
`59
`
`6'4
`65
`68
`74
`
`6
`
`

`
`Part II — The organization of the market
`
`3 Contract enforcement
`
`!n.£r0dm?£ion
`
`77:3 £'8‘g(I£'_}(;'(Ifi?£’E£»‘0F':"f
`Pnllate erfiarcerrnent rnerfzanisvrr.
`(§‘onw'I:5i0n5
`
`Appendix - Sitar! summaagv qfmur! cases
`
`4
`
`Risk seeking and risk mitigation
`Introduction
`
`Carartterpary-' risk
`Poryfifio risk
`Corzdusirms
`
`5
`
`Information
`Introducliorz
`
`:'m.Ie3Im'.s" in/formation needs‘ in thefiitti decade rgf.-9'22 sea-‘eratemtfz cer.*.a'.m_)J
`;’VIrn'ke.‘. reartiom to iJ*_I/?J?‘:P?i’£’1:"-fr}???
`The injimmztian. networks cy‘"CIz-nstiarz andjewisfr share .'.‘mdm‘
`Cu::ciusir»n5
`
`Conclusions
`
`Epilogue — Reassessing Coryizsién de co7y‘iz5"iones
`
`Summary (in Dutch)
`
`Appendices
`Appendix A - iilontiafv 5:303‘? price A.rns“.fe:'dam rfzambfl !'()(:, 1'602-! 698
`Appendix B - Dividend dirtn'.bu(io:1.s‘ I’()(;, 1602-! 700
`Ap/)e.rm’i.t C - Gfossagy
`
`Acknowledgements
`
`Bibliography
`Pn}?1a1_'p somws
`Ptzbiisfzed pn'.m.(.1g2 sozrmzr
`Semna’r1:_)v Eizerrzture
`
`Index of names and places
`
`91
`
`.91’
`
`97
`I 07
`I 1 4
`
`H5
`
`1 18
`I 18
`
`I20
`134
`I 45
`
`148
`I 48
`
`I50
`156'
`I 65
`I 75
`
`180
`
`186
`
`190
`
`196
`I 96
`204
`206
`
`210
`
`21 1
`21' I
`2 I I
`213
`
`219
`
`VI
`
`7
`
`

`
`LIST OF FIGURES
`
`Figure 1.1 Forward contract used in a transaction between V\"i11em Muijlman and
`Philips de Bacher, 2 September 1644.
`Figure 1.2 Amsterdam Exchange of Hendrick de Keyser, etching by C._]. Visscher
`(1612)
`Figure 1.3 Amsterdam Exchange of Hendrick de Keyser, interior, painting bvjob
`Adriaensz. Be1'ckheyde(between 1670 and 1690)
`Figure 2.1 5-day period share transfers, \’0C Amsterdam chamber, 1609
`Figure 2.2 5-day period share transfers, \-‘OCI Amsterdam chamber, 1639
`Figure 2.3 5-day period share transfers, VUC Amsterdam chamber, 166?
`figure 2.4 5-day period share transfers, \’()(: Amsterdam chamber, 16??
`Figure 2.5 5-day period share transfers, VOC: Amsterdam chamber, 1688
`Figure 2.6 Monthly ‘.’()C: share price, Amsterdam chamber, September 1602
`February 1698. Missing values derived from linear interpolation.
`Figure 2.7 Monthly ‘.-"QC share price, Amsterdam chamber, September 1602 -
`February 1693
`Figure 2.9 Yeariy high-low-average \-'()(: share price, Amsterdam chamber, 160?-
`1698
`
`Figure 2.10 Yearly dividends as a percentage of the nominal value of \-'O(: shares,
`1620-1699
`
`54
`
`55
`
`56
`76
`77
`78
`79
`80
`
`81
`
`82
`
`83
`
`84
`
`85
`Figure 2.12 Dix-idend as a percentage of" market value, 1620-169?
`86
`Figure 2.13 Real dividend and \-'0(: share price, 1630-98
`Figire 2.14 Share price data ofthe Amsterdam, Nlicldelburg, Enkhuizen and Hoorn
`chambers of the VOC, 161 1-1685
`8?
`
`Figure 4.1 Forward and repo transactions represented in diagram Form
`Figure 4.2 Size of loans granted on shares pledged as co11atera1, 16-19-1688
`Figure 5.1 vat: share price, 7_]uly 1671 - 31 December 1672
`Figure 5.2 V-"QC: share price, Ibjanuary 1688 - 22 November 1688
`
`146
`147
`178
`179
`
`VII
`
`8
`
`

`
`LIST OF TABLES
`
`Table 1.1 Spot transactions of Christolfel andjan Raphoen, 1626-42
`Table 2.1 Total number of shareholders’ accounts, Amsterdam chamber \"O(:, 1602
`and 1679-1695; number of active accoullts and share t1'ansfers, 1609, 1639,
`1667, 1672 and 1688
`
`38
`
`64
`
`Table 2.2 Share price data oftlte Middelburg, Enkhuizen, and Hoorn chambers of
`the \--'()(1
`
`75
`
`Table 3.1 Court of Holland, Extended sentences
`Table 3.12 Court. of Holland, Case files
`
`High Council, Extended sentences
`Table
`Table 4.1 Estimated costs of_]eronimus V"e1ters' forward and repo transactions
`
`1 15
`l 17
`
`1 17
`125
`
`LIST OF MAPS
`
`Map 1.1 Main share trade locations in the first decade of the seventeenth century
`Map 1.2 Main share trade locations after the opening ofthe Exchange (161 1)
`
`57
`58
`
`VIII
`
`9
`
`

`
`LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS
`
`BT
`
`Bibliotheea Thysiana, Leyden
`
`I),-\S
`
`_].R. Bruijn, 17.8. Gaastra and I. Sehéffer, I)::I:!:—A.s‘.=Ta!ir .w':z'pping in the :’7!f2 and
`
`i6’.!‘iz centzmies {3 \-'0ls., The Hague 1979-87).
`
`1-11c:
`
`N.-\
`
`PA
`
`PIG
`
`RAL‘
`
`English East India Company
`
`Nationaal Arehief, The Hague
`
`Persmuseum Amsterdam
`
`P0rtugees-Israelitiselle Gemeente
`
`Het Utrechts Arehief
`
`S.-X.-'\
`
`Stadsarehiel‘Amsterdani
`
`VOC:
`
`Vereiiigde Dost-Indisehe Compagnir:
`
`\-\-‘IE:
`
`\'Ve5t-Indisehe Compagnie
`
`.\.-Nbte on Ch".?‘?'t’??£_‘)‘
`
`The Dutch currency, the guilder gf), was divided into ‘.20 stlziverzr; eaeh s.fuir..'er' was sub-
`
`divided into 16 penrairzgen. In addition to wilders, the Dutch also used pounds Flemish
`
`(})V1). The nominal value eni'V-‘OC shares was, for example, often expressed in pounds
`
`Flemish. One pound Flemish equaled six guilders. To make eurrene.y figures more
`
`easily comprehensible,
`CCl"H.S.
`
`l have e0n\-'erled everything into guilders divided into 100
`
`10
`
`IX
`
`10
`
`

`
`11
`
`11
`
`

`
`INTRODUCTION
`
`‘This little game could bring in more money than contracting charter parties for ships
`
`bound for England’, wrote Rodrigo Dias Henriques to Manuel Levy Duarte on 1 No-
`
`vember 1691.‘ Dias Henriques was referring to the ‘game’ of trading shares of the
`
`Dutch East India Company (Verenigde Oost-Indische Compagnie, VOC, founded
`
`1602) and its derivatives* on the Amsterdam securities market. He acted as exchange
`
`agent for Levy Duarte and performed a high number of transactions on his account.
`
`The most notable feature of the exchange dealings of these Portuguese Jewish mer-
`
`chants was that they consisted solely of very swift trades; Dias I-Ienriques made sure to
`
`always settle the transactions within a few days or a fortnight at most. He actively
`
`speculated on short-term share price* movements, while at the same time making sure
`
`that his portfolio did not become too risky - and, judging by his quote, he was rather
`
`good at it. Dias Henriques could perform these swift dealings because by the end of
`
`the seventeenth century, a very active secondary market* for securities existed in Am-
`
`sterdam.
`
`Modern securities markets have two functions: price discovery* and the provi-
`
`sion of liquidity*. The interaction of traders in the marketplace, in other words, de-
`
`termines the price of the assets that are traded on the market. The liquidity fiinction
`
`means that as a result of the concentration of traders in the marketplace, traders can
`
`easily buy or sell assets. Straightforward as these market functions may seem, they play
`
`a very important role for investors: they allow investors to reallocate their asset hold-
`
`ings at low cost, enabling them to manage their financial risks according to their per-
`
`sonal preferences? Securities markets thus provide major advantages to investors.
`
`The secondary market for VOC shares became the first securities market in his-
`
`tory that provided these advantages to investors. Hence it was in seventeenth-century
`
`Amsterdam that ‘the global securities market began to take on its modern form’.3 Us-
`
`ing hitherto unexplored source material from the archives of the VOC, judicial institu-
`
`tions of the Dutch Republic and merchants who were active on the securities market,
`
`' Dias Henriques to Levy Duarte, 1 November 1691, SM, PIG, inv. or. 677, pp. 897-8.
`‘ Words market with an asterisk (*) are further explained in Appendix C - Glossary.
`3‘ Maureen O’Ha.ra, ‘Presidential address: Liquidity and price discovery’, 3:3-Irma! ryffinance 58 (2003)
`1335-1354, there 1335.
`3 Ranald C. Michie, He global‘ securities market.’ (I histogr (Oxford 2006) 26.
`
`12
`
`12
`
`

`
`this book analyzes how the secondary market for VOL shares could develop into tl1e
`
`world's first modern securities market.
`
`Context, I'tirmnTograj2fy and £»’:ea:9=
`
`How the secondary market for \-'OC shares started ofi" in the first decade of the seven-
`
`teenth century is well known.‘ In 1602, the States General of the Dutch Republic
`
`granted the \--’()C a charter For a period of 21 years, with the provision that an interim
`
`liquidation would follow after ten yearsf’ Inhabitants of the Dutch Republic were
`
`called upon to invest in the new company. The \-’0(: thus became a priyate.ly-owned
`
`company in which the authorities of the Dtttch Republic had a large say. The capital
`
`subscription was a great success: in Amsterdam alone,
`
`1 143 investors signed up for
`
`f3,6'/'9,9l5.'5 According to a clause on the first page of the subscription book of the
`
`\-'O(:, shareholders could transfer their shares to a third party. On this same page, the
`
`procedure for registering .share transfers was laid down:
`
`the buyer and the seller
`
`should go to the East India house where the bookkeeper, after two company directors
`
`had approved the transfer, transferred the share from the seller's to the buyer's ac-
`
`count in the capital book?
`
`These clear rules for ownership and transfer of ownership reduced investors’
`
`hesitaney about trading the valuable shares that existed only on paper. Secondary
`
`market trading therefore took a start immediately after the subscription books were
`
`closed.“ However, the real incentive to trade. shares emerged later. The directors of
`
`the VOL: did not liquidate the company after ten years and at the end of the first char-
`
`ter, in 1623, they requested a prolongation of‘ the charter, which the States General
`
`‘f See, pa1rticula1'ly: Oscar (lelderhlom and _]oost _]onker, ‘Completing a financial remlution: The li-
`nance of the Dutch East India trade and the rise of the Amsterdam capital market,
`l:‘).‘l;‘J-ltilili. 7712'
`jmm.=:1't rifernrtnrrtir .f:tr!n.f1' (34 {QUU4} 54 l -572.
`7‘ T’or 21 general account of" the Iouliding ol'tl1c \TJ('., se.e:_].A. van (lcr Chijs, (':‘¢’.'-o’n}vdrrt:Li' (fer ,i't.ic.r’Jtt.*ag mm (19
`I"e.=r:.eri{gde 0.1’. (Jo-mpr.=gm}r we (fer rzizzatrrgrleri z-urn dc .-'\"m‘er!arrd5r.-is regerirqg brtrrgflérsdr de mart up O:Jst—i’mi.=}"l
`(L-'(?fJf‘t‘? mm
`deer .t'tit‘t'a'i;rg 1‘or:rrygrir1grr1 (Leyden I857}. This book also contains 21 transcription of the 16012 charte r. The
`text oflllc first charter can also be lhnntl onlinc: ht1'p://www.vocsite.nl/geschicdcnis/octrooi.html An
`English translation is also online available:
`|ittp:/ /mvw.austra|iaonthcmaporg.au/<:omcnt/\-'icw/50/59
`" The total capital stock of the \’U(: amounted to f6,-129,588; .\'Iiddell)urg coI1trihutedfl,3(lU,~l05
`{2U".»"u‘,I, Enkhuizen f54-0,0(}U [3°»'u}, Delft -'l[i9,4Ul]
`{?°x'u}, Hoorn _f‘.3ti(i,8fi3 {4".«’ujI and Rotterdam
`f l ?3,(}fl[l I.’_3“_.=’uj: l-lcnk den Hcijcr, Dr gexirtrooieerde ro:n,bagn.'}?.' de l-''()(.' 9:: dr’
`l'i"’:'C‘r1t'.t E-‘t‘.'tJ?'.fn'Jf):"t'.T ma dc’ nrtrtrrifxice
`vertrinatsr-r'znp I__De\'enIer ‘?.t]U5_] 61. According to the liistorical purchasing power calculator of the [l'llt"l‘l1£1-
`tional Institute of‘ Social History in Amsterdam {see http:/ /\nvw.iisg.nl/ hpwl calculate.pl1p_‘J, the value
`olthe I602 subscription would amount to almost C100 million today.
`7 A facsimile and transcript of the first page of the subscription book can be found in:J.G. van Dillen,
`Ho’. rittafrta rtrt3:deeNirJ1rder5Jrg1'.tte:' t.-rm (fa Ifm.=m':lm.r{ern’mn (.rl€.i' OrJ.t‘t-Iridurlir Cta:.=i;‘)ng7.=:'e tT'l1t' Hztguc I958] 10:‘)-ti.
`3 Gt?l(lc'l'l')l0l‘t'I antL]o11ker, Tionipleting‘.
`
`13
`
`13
`
`

`
`granted. Again, no intermediate liquidation took place. Consequently,
`
`the capital
`
`stoek* of the \-"on: became defects fixed.“ In the end, the company would stay in busi-
`
`ness for almost two centuries and the capital stock rernained fixed during the entire
`
`period. Since investors generally do not want their money to be locked up for that a
`
`long period of time, they used the secondary market to sell their shareholdings to a
`
`third party.
`
`The fixed capital stock of the \-"O(: was unique. Shipping companies in late-
`
`medieval Italy and, from the mid-sixteenth century onwards, also in England and the
`
`Low Countries. were often equity*-financed, but these companies were always liqui-
`
`dated after a single expedition to the destination. The same went for the Vomrmnpag-
`
`nt'e§n., the predecessors of the \"O(: that had equipped expeditions to the East Indies
`
`from 1594 onwards. The proceeds of the liquidation were divided among the inves-
`
`tors. In many cases, the company was reestablished immediately after liquidation and
`
`participants were given the opportunity to reinvest their money in the. new partner-
`
`ship. Consequently, there was little need for secondary market trading, be.c.ause after
`
`liquidation, investors eottld decide not to reinvest. Investors knew that they could al-
`
`ways get their money back within a few years" time.'" Likewise, it took until the end of
`
`the seventeenth century before a secondary market for shares emerged in England."
`
`Before that time, there were no joint-stock companies with a sufficiently large fixed
`
`capital to get the development ofa securities market going.” The capital stock of the
`
`English East India Company (1~‘.I(:._ founded 1600'], for example, only became fixed in
`
`165?. Before that time, the tilt: repeatedly issued new stock to fund its fleets; the EIC
`
`was thus basically a series of separate companies that worked together as the BIG. '3
`
`Remarkably, already in the later Middle Ages, secondary markets for public
`
`debt had emerged iI1 Italian city states. Venice, Genoa and Florence were the first
`
`'-’ Den Heijel‘, Dr grr2t‘tmniéerde rnmfmgitie, 59,615.
`'“ Oscar Gelderblom, Abe dejong and ‘]oostL]onker, “An Atlrniralty lbt‘ Assia. Isaac le t\-'lai1‘e and con-
`[lieting conceptions about the (‘orporate go\'ernant‘e of tl1e \‘U(.'', in: Jonathan 0.5. Koppell [_ed.}, Tire
`origins gfsftrirdinlrfer r'm't*nrr3r_‘v I,'Basingstoke, forthcoming 201 l_].
`” Anne L. Mttrphy, T716 o:'tfgi:r.r q[En_.g!i.r:‘:_fiarrnriat’ merfrets. Im'e.n'.moit and yieetalation Figfiire the .S'r1tn‘.r‘.= Sea Birbbte
`{Cambridge 2009).
`'9 Ron Harris,
`lndrrsfria-t'.i.:in_g :'.€ng!£sl.=
`2000} ll?-8, 120-1, 127.
`'3‘ The lixerl capital stock ofithe Ii[(i in 165? amounted to £793.78? W.R. Seott, Tier? ron_c!i!1d1'nn and
`_fiH(mrTt’ qfEngh'.rt':.
`.S'rn££i.r;’: and 1risf:jnin!—.i'tod€
`rntnparties to 1720 [I C'nmprIr:t'e.rjhi'florrt;g:: tmdr, rriirmfzrrtion. _fi.:‘a"zirtg
`and ntiniaqg (Clanihridge l9] 2} I29. I92. Michiel de_]ongh, ‘De ontwikkeling van zeggelischapsreeltteii
`ran aandeelliouders in cle 17*‘ en I8" eeuw",
`ll"'nrking;mpcr rj2009';u. At the exeliange rate ol‘ I654 ("the I657
`rate is unavailableju, 793,782 equaled approximately f8.‘.25U.{)U0: N.\’\'. Poslliunius. .M°'rferz’r1r.'r2’s'r:‘tr* prj5ge-
`.m":ir3dmi.t'
`I: (£o:°det'e:r{9:ijzs;r of; 0’! t"mtr.r ran A.r.=:.t‘:‘errt’rr:it r'535—}9I 4.
`I-"I-"ir_s'.n’kr;r:'.rm re _=I;it.mv.m’a:n F6091’ .9}-I Ley-
`dett I94!-3} 592.
`
`Fart‘: rntrrprsrmtrslzijj mar! brts't'rm.s- rngganiaaticrrr, I720-I844 {New York
`
`14
`
`14
`
`

`
`states to consolidate their public debt - a revolution in public finance, because it eased
`
`the process of underwriting new debt issues.” Veiiiee, for example, consolidated all its
`
`outstanding debt in a so-called mtmte in 1262. The original obligations were converted
`
`into shares in the ntrmte and investors could subsequently transfer the title to these
`
`shares by way of assignment. Secondary markets came into being, but these markets
`
`did not have the characteristics of a free market, since new loans were often forced
`
`loans. Hence, the decision to invest was not taken by the investors themselves. lV’Ioreo-
`
`ver, the number of transfers typically rose when a new forced loan was announced,
`
`which indicates that some shareholders were forced to dump their shares on the sec-
`
`ondary market to get the liquidity needed to pay for the upcoming debt issue.‘-3 This
`
`innovation in public finance failed to spread to other parts of Europe, however. In the
`
`Low Countries, the provinces kept issuing short-term debt and it would take until at
`
`least 1672 before secondary trade of any significance took place in government debt in
`
`the Dutch Republic.‘“ The English government recognized the advantages of secon-
`
`dary market trading in the early eighteenth century. It started to use the secondary
`
`market to sell its debt in transferable annuity obligations in the 17203.”
`
`This short overview has identified the factors that led to the emergence of a
`
`secondary market for \-'O(': shares in the Dutch Republic. Very little is known about
`
`the subsequent development of the market, however. Smith studied the trade in de-
`
`rivatives, focusing on official regulations and pamphlets that addressed the share
`
`trade, and Gelderblom ancljonker discussed the history of derivatives trading on the
`
`Amsterdam exchange from 1550 to 1650, mentioning the emergence of several types
`
`of derivatives and analyzing similarities and differences in the trade in equity deriva-
`
`tives and forward* contracts that were used in the grain trade.” Apart from these
`
`" Set‘, partiI:‘ular1_v: Reinhold C. .\-ltlcllcr, ‘Ute l-"flatten lacing}-' r:m.='ket: barrio‘, prtriirs. arm’ the public debt,
`f500 {Baltimore 1997}.
`'7‘_]tI1ius Kirshner, 'EncL;ml:Icring private claims to public debt in renaissance Florence”, in: Vito Pier-
`giovanni {cd,), 73:? grater?! rgftfm batik (I5 ir.=.rt:}‘i:ti'ni.' mm’ the drtlelnfiiiient iji;";ii:iii:_ei.'—im.ti:m.r {aw [Berlin 1993} 19-76.
`Meir Kohn, ‘The capital market before 1600’, Dm‘tmauh‘t C'o£t'egt> ttnnlring fmfier nr. 99-06 (1999) 10-1 1.
`'“_]amcs D. Tracy. .--lfinarsriat rt'::at':ttion in the Habsbtrig .-'\'é?tIrei'i"niir!.<.‘ Rama and r.cw:‘rrn'e:'s in the roam! ' :3fHm.'i"mrrt'.
`!.5!5-1565 (Berkeley 19851. Oscar Gelclerblom and _]oos1_]onker, ‘A cr_unditio:1::| miracle. ’I"l1c market
`forces that shaped Holl:mcl's public debt rnanagement’, l|"nrkirig,‘Jtzper (12010) ‘.21 , ‘.2-1-7.
`'7 Larry Neal, The’ Hit? -r3;f,‘inarii‘ir:I rrIfJitru’i.i1rt.' intmmtiana! rnpitaf i::ri:'.{'rLs' in I'll? Age ufRmsrm {_CIamhridgc 19‘:}(l_‘_I
`10.
`
`.’2()t')—
`
`”‘ ;\-'l.I'" Smith, Tgjral-(gflirir::'.i' in gflécteit mm rile: Ain.s'tera’r:.=:i.i't':‘tr bett.='.\' (T he Hague 1919:]. Oscar Gelderbloni
`and Joost Junker, ‘Amsterdam as the cradle of modern futures and options trading, 155-U~1(i5ll’. in:
`\\’illiam N. Goetzmann and K. Gccrt Rouwenhorsl ['ec|s.}. 77:2 nrigin.i' :if:,wi’m?.' Jiiefinanrinl 3'rinnt'm'ioi:.i' flint
`c‘i':’r1i'.r’r1' rrindetn rrtfiifnl .mark£l.r Oxford 2005} 189-205. The article 'Con1pleting°, by the same authors, has
`been mentioned above. This article Ibeused on the funding offiast India trade in the Dutch Republic
`
`15
`
`15
`
`

`
`studies, most economic historians merely marveled at the sophistication of the market
`
`in the late seventeenth eentuiy. They iisedjosseph de la \*'ega’s high-flown description
`
`of the share trade in Corgjiuiéri de cargfitsiaaes, the famous account of the share market
`
`dating from 1688"‘, as a starting point for their work?“ Others tried to catch the sig-
`
`nificance of the market in very general phrases. Barbour, for example, wrote that
`
`‘Amsterdam gave [existing financial instruments] more precise formulation, greater
`
`flexibility and extension, and used them effectively over a wider field.’2' Braudel"s in-
`
`terpretation of the financial developments in Amsterdam was that ‘ce qui est nouveau
`
`51 Amsterdam, c’est le volume, la lluidité, la publicité, la liberté speculative des transac-
`
`tions. Le jeu s’y méle de facon lréiiétique, lejeu pour le jeu."3'-’ Superficial as these ob-
`
`servations may seem, they touch upon some very important aspects of the market.
`
`The flexibility and enhanced formulation of the financial instruments meant that in-
`
`vestors could use them to manage their financial risks. Moreover, the market could
`
`iiiliill its core functions price discovery and liquidity only because of the increase in
`
`trading activity. This raises the questions which factors led to the sophistication of
`
`financial instruments in Amsterdam? And what caused trading activity to increase on
`
`the Amsterdam market?
`
`In this book, the development of the market will be examined from an institu-
`
`tional perspective. In the most widely used definition, institutions ‘are the rules of the
`
`game in a society or, more formally, are the humanly devised constraints that shape
`
`human interaction."="3 Institutions consist of formal and informal rules. Informal rules
`
`are not enforceable by law; they mostly depend on social sanctions for their enforce-
`
`ment. Formal institutions, such as laws and official regulations, are enforced by the
`
`ant] argued that the emergence ofa secondary market for shares completed tl1e financial revolution of
`the sixteenth ccnttlry, as has been advanced hyjalnes D. Tracy: Tracy, /l_firmm:iriI irrzzr,-Ztttiori.
`'9 Dutch translation oi'l)e la \"ega’s work, with a good introduction by ;\-'I,I*'._j. Smithzjossepli Pt-nso de
`la Vega, Crirgfirntin dc’ cnrgfi4.s‘i:Jnr.i' Ifl[i88_], 31.17,]. Smith [:ed.} (T he Hague I939"). The best English {abridged}
`cditinnzjossttp I1 Penso dc la \-"cga, Chrgfitrinrt dr rn:gfi:.rione.r t'g1']o.re,‘i:‘i dr la Vega I688. Porn‘.-m.r de.i‘rn‘;;tir;e gf‘(i".=e
`.=lm.n‘erdmn Si‘.-ark Etrfiaagr (I688) Hermann Kellenbenz cd. [Cambridge 1957}.
`‘~“'jona1han Israel, amongst others, relies heavily on De la \-"cga._ for example in: Jonathan 1. Israel,
`'_]ews and the stock exchange: the Amsterdam Iinancial erasli of 1688‘, in: idem ('cti._},
`i'J.=}:.r,mra_s- a'itfl':.5n :1
`dia.g()ora.']m-'.r, C9‘p:'u-j’rzc.r mm’ the tt.'rm.'d maritime rnipir.r.i' {}.'340- I 740) {_Le‘\_-‘clen 2UC'2_} 4-=1-9-87. Also: Charles
`Wilson, .-lnglr)—1)m‘r/: r:mm1ri'r.r.’ rlnrljinmw in the r.'igl:£t*ert{:’: F-t‘.'.'ftt9' r._CaInbridgc l9-ll, reprinted in l9{i('i]:. Geof-
`frey Poitras, Tire er.-rfv ltiitnpr qfifinrinrial .=2rmioma"r.c, H78— .-’77€.'frnm rarm:ie?:'r1'm’ aiffftiitefit.‘ In :'g',.I'?? nn:tr:z'£ir.s mm’
`_,ir;ir1t.r£or!r.r [Cheltenh:u'n 2000:] 315. 385-7.
`9' Violet Barbour. C':2p:'ma'i.w::: .Fr:..im.r!.v:'r1'r.-m in we a‘r'z'rntt>r::fl': ren£m_'J' {Baltimore 1950} 142.
`9'-9 Fernand Brande], Lé'5js.*.=.*.\' rte i"r'r!'mng.°.=. C‘izI.i:’i.i'rztinrr ninléiielfe. émnnmie rt ra,rJftaa"i.rn.=.r4.
`.\'l’e—.\'I-‘me .n'én’e II (Paris
`1979} 8 [-2.
`1"‘ l.)ouglass C. North, :':c.m'!ution:.'_,
`
`in.r£itu.'irmrn' ritaiqgr am’ .err;.-wm.='r ;;rg£-izmarirr {Clan1lJri(i_s,rt- i990‘: 3.
`
`16
`
`16
`
`

`
`state. The. institutional framework of markets generally consists ofa combination of
`
`formal and informal institutions.
`
`The theory of institutional economics argues that institutional innovation takes
`
`place because economic actors always search for ways to reduce transaction costs. Put
`
`another way, economic actors always search for ways to obtain benefits from eco-
`
`nomic interaction at the lowest transaction costs possible.“ Acemoglu,johnso11 and
`
`Robinson divide transactions costs into three categories: ‘ll those that increased the
`
`mobility of capital; 2) those that lowered information costs; and 3) those that spread
`
`risk.’93‘ These three categories will be addressed in this study. I will show how the de-
`
`velopment of a sophisticated enforcement mechanism ensured traders that their traits-
`
`actions would be consummated by the market. Because traders had a high level of
`
`certainty that their trades would be completed, they were more inclined towards trad-
`
`ing, which increased the mobility of capital. The market also lowered information
`
`costs. The. use of intermediaries and particularly the creation of trading clubs, whose
`
`participants could easily monitor each other’s beltavior, meant that less effort was
`
`needed to check a possible cottnte1party’s creditworthiness. Furthermore, as a result of
`
`the high trading activity, the share price was constantly updated to the beliefs of the
`
`trading populations.‘-"“ This reduced the need for investors with long-term investment
`
`horizons to find price-relevant information; they could rely on the prices quoted on
`
`the exchange. Lastly, the range of derivative instruments available to the traders by
`
`the second half of the seventeenth century allowed them to mitigate the risk of their
`
`investment portfolios.
`
`55.0/Jr and .r£rttrt.‘m'e
`
`The scope of this book is limited to the seventeenth-century Amsterdam market for
`
`\-'00 shares. The focus on the. scve.nteenth century flows, in the first place, from the
`
`fact that it is widely known, mainly front De la Vega's work, that Amsterdam boasted
`
`‘-"' Sheilagh Ogilvie, "‘\\-'hate\'er is, is right"? Economic institutions in pre-industrial Europe’, Eraimmir
`!2in‘rii_1= i'e*viz’tt' tit} I'I‘2tJ07) 541.1-U8-l, [here (558.
`l\'orlli, l'it_wt.=}'::ti:ii:3, I25. Daron Aczetnoglu, Simon _jo|1nsou am:l_]ames A. Robinson, ‘Institutions as a
`fundamental cause of long-run growth", in: Philippe Aghion and Steven N. Uurlauf [_eds._j:, HamJ'btirJil' of
`mmwiiir gmztrlzi [Anistcrclarn 2t_)05_'i 38.3-472.
`2" According to Ross I.e\-inc. markets with high trading activity provide an incentive for traders to
`gather‘ prict:-relevant ittlurmationi 'Intuiti\'ely, with larger and more liquid ntarkets. it is easier lbr an
`agent who has acquired inforntation to tlisgtiise this private information and make money by trading in
`the market.‘ As a result, prices on liquid markets reveal relatively move information about" the assets
`that are being tradt‘.(l. Ross Levine, ‘Finan('e and growth: Lheory and evidt‘1it‘c", in: Philippe .-\ghion and
`Steven N . Dui'latil‘t'etls.'], flrtririburtl‘ r_:f:r:mamir'grmrfli '.'Amsterdam 2‘t)t}5jI 865-93-l-. there 872.
`
`17
`
`17
`
`

`
`a highly sophisticated securities market by the end of the seventeenth century, but the
`
`path of development towards becoming the first modern securities market has re-
`
`mained obscure. Secondly, a study on the seventeenth-century Amsterdam securities
`
`market provides new material for fixture research on the transfer of‘ financial know-
`
`how from Amsterdam to London in the late seventeenth century. The London securi-
`
`ties market started developing quickly from around 1688 onwards - shortly after the
`
`invasion and subsequent accession to the English throne of Dutch stadhoider W'illia:n
`
`111. Although Murphy has recently argued that the London market developed largely
`
`by itself; the timing of the stock market boom in London still suggests that the Dutch
`
`experience must have had some influence on the developments in England.” This
`
`book on the securities market in Amsterdam will aid new researchers in identifying to
`
`what extent the London financial markets profited from Dutch financial experience.
`
`It
`
`is important to note that Amsterdam was not the only city in the seven-
`
`teenth-centuiy Dutch Republic where a secondary market for company equity ex-
`
`isted. The organizational structure of‘ the \-''O(:, with six semi-independent chambers,
`
`resulted in the emergence of six separate markets. However, due to the smaller capital
`
`stock of‘ the Middelburg, linkhuizen, Hoorn, Delft and Rotterdam cliambers, these
`
`peripheral markets experienced different development paths. Shares in these cham-
`
`bers were, of course, occasionally transferred, but what this study tries to unravel is
`
`how the transition took place from a market where company shares were occasionally
`
`transferred to a tliriving securities market that provided its participants a range of fi-
`
`nancial services. This happened only in Ains-terdam.33 I will also pay some attention to
`
`Middelburg, however. The Middelburg chamber of the \-’OC: had the second-largest
`
`capital stock and consequently, the development of the l\-"Iiddelburg market came clos-
`
`est to that of Amsterdam. As I will show in chapter 5, traders used the liquidity of the
`
`l\-licldelhurg market for arbitrage* purposes; they tried to be the first to use informa-
`
`tion available on the Amsterdam market For transactions 011 the Micldelburg market
`
`and vice versa.'-’‘’ Finally, shares in the Dutch “lest India Company (WICJ, founded
`
`1623) were also traded on the secondary market. However, investors generally kept
`
`away from these shares. The disproportionately large government interference in the
`
`.'-J.
`37 .\'Iu1'plty. 775:2 or{gfrr.i' .'y"Eng{n':‘t_/r::(r:rt'iaE m(n'!rt*.*.r,
`‘J3 The development o['thc markets in equity olithe smallest chambers stalled soon after the suhsc ription
`of I602. Sec cliapter 2. section Divcrgient dcvelopnientsz Alnsterdttln and peripheral markets on page
`68 fl‘.
`
`1"-' Cf. page I59 ll”.
`
`18
`
`18
`
`

`
`it-‘lt: made investors afraid that the company management would behave too opportu-
`
`nistically. Moreox-'er, investors were well aware that the it-'I(.: was a financial disaster. I
`
`will therefore focus on the trade in \-'O(: shares only.
`
`My analysis of the development of the secondary market for \--‘()C: shares into
`
`the first modern securities market is structured in two parts. Part I treats the seven-
`
`teenlh—century history of the market in general. Part It explores in more detail how the
`
`market was organized.
`
`Part 1 starts, in chapter 1, with a chronological overview of the key develop-
`
`ments that shaped the market during the seventeenth century. Subsequently, chapter
`
`2 analyzes long-term developments, such as the increase in trading activity on the
`
`market, the. number of active. traders, the dividend policy of the \-’O(: and the diverg-
`
`ing development of the Amsterdam market in comparison with the peripheral share
`
`markets in the Dutch Republic. The findings of part I show that afier the important
`
`first decade of the century in which the market emerged, the Amsterdam market for
`
`\-'00 shares entered into a second stage. of deve.lopment in the period 1630-50; this
`
`stage brought about the transition into a modern securities market. The two principal
`
`developments during this period were a staggering increase. in trading activity and the
`
`appearance of new groups of traders on the market.
`
`Part 11 goes deeper into the developments that made the organization of risky
`
`financial transactions possible in a market that grew in size and bec.an1e increasingly
`
`anonymous and hence answers the question how the market for \-‘DC: shares could
`
`develop into a modern securities market. Chapter 3 discusses the formal and informal
`
`institutions that guaranteed that traders lived up to their agreements. My argument is
`
`that
`
`the traders built a private enforcement mechanism on top of a formal lega

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket