Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 1 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`
`
`
`
`No. 23-60167
`
`IN THE
`United States Court of Appeals
`for the Fifth Circuit
`
`ILLUMINA, INC. AND GRAIL, INC.,
`Petitioners,
`
`v.
`FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION,
`Respondent.
`
`
`
`
`Petition for Review of an Order of the Federal Trade Commission
`
`
`BRIEF FOR AMICI CURIAE INTERNATIONAL CENTER OF
`LAW AND ECONOMICS AND LAW AND ECONOMICS
`SCHOLARS ON BEHALF OF PETITIONERS
`
`Gene C. Schaerr
`
`
`Donald M. Falk
`SCHAERR | JAFFE LLP
`
`SCHAERR | JAFFE LLP
`1717 K Street NW, Suite 900 Four Embarcadero Center,
`Washington, DC 20006
`
` Suite 1400
`(202) 787-1060
`
`
`San Francisco, CA 94111
`gschaerr@schaerr-jaffe.com
`(415) 562-4942
`dfalk@schaerr-jaffe.com
`
`Counsel for Amici Curiae
`
`JUNE 12, 2023
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 2 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`
`
`
`SUPPLEMENTAL STATEMENT OF INTERESTED PERSONS
`No. 23-60167
`Illumina, Inc. and Grail, Inc. v. Federal Trade Commission.
`
`Pursuant to 5th Cir. R. 29.2, the undersigned counsel of record
`
`hereby certifies that, in addition to the persons and entities listed in the
`
`Petitioners’ Certificate of Interested Persons, the following listed persons
`
`and entities as described in the fourth sentence of Rule 28.2.1 have an
`
`interest in the outcome of this case. These representations are made in
`
`order that the judges of this court may evaluate possible disqualification
`
`or recusal.
`
`Amici Curiae:
`
`International Center for Law and Economics
`
`Alden F. Abbott
`
`Brian Albrecht
`
`Thomas C. Arthur
`
`Dirk Auer
`
`Stephen N. Dnes
`
`Kenneth G. Elzinga
`
`Luke M. Froeb
`
`Harold Furchtgott-Roth
`
`
`
`
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 3 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`Daniel J. Gilman
`
`Janice A. Hauge
`
`Justin (Gus) Hurwitz
`
`Keith N. Hylton
`
`William J. Kolasky
`
`Thomas A. Lambert
`
`Stan J. Liebowitz
`
`Abbott B. Lipsky, Jr.
`
`John E. Lopatka
`
`Daniel A. Lyons
`
`Geoffrey A. Manne
`
`Scott E. Masten
`
`Alan J. Meese
`
`Daniel P. O’Brien
`
`Jeffrey T. Prince
`
`Paul H. Rubin
`
`Vernon L. Smith
`
`Michael E. Sykuta
`
`Liad Wagman
`
`ii
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 4 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`Jonathan W. Williams
`
`John M. Yun
`
`Counsel for Amici Curiae:
`
`Donald M. Falk
`
`Gene C. Schaerr
`
`Schaerr | Jaffe LLP
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`iii
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 5 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`In accordance with Federal Rule of Appellate Procedure 26.1,
`
`amicus curiae International Center for Law and Economics states that it
`
`is not publicly traded and has no parent corporations. No publicly traded
`
`corporation owns 10% or more of amicus. The legal name of amicus
`
`International Center for Law and Economics is International Policy
`
`Network US d/b/a International Center for Law & Economics.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`/s/ Donald M. Falk
`Donald M. Falk
`
`Counsel of Record for Amicus Curiae
`International Center for Law
`and Economics
`
`
`
`iv
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 6 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`TABLE OF CONTENTS
`
`IDENTITY AND INTEREST OF AMICUS CURIAE AND
`
`SUPPLEMENTAL STATEMENT OF INTERESTED PERSONS ............ i
`TABLE OF AUTHORITIES ..................................................................... vii
`SOURCE OF AUTHORITY TO FILE BRIEF ...................................... 1
`RULE 29(a)(4)(e) STATEMENT ................................................................ 2
`INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY OF ARGUMENT ............................ 3
`ARGUMENT ............................................................................................... 7
`I.
`Differently. .................................................................................... 7
`A.
`Vertical Merger Cases. ........................................................ 7
`B.
`Incentives Given the Merger’s Efficiencies. ..................... 10
`1.
`Mergers ..................................................................... 13
`2.
`Consideration to Evident Benefits .......................... 15
`3.
`Actual Harm ............................................................. 17
`4.
`Analysis .................................................................... 20
`
`The FTC Did Not Undertake the Necessary Fact-
`Specific Examination of the Merged Firm’s
`
`Vertical and Horizontal Mergers Should Be Scrutinized
`
`Prima Facie Standards and the Government’s
`“Ultimate Burden” Differ
`in Horizontal and
`
`Presumptions Suitable to Horizontal Mergers
`Are Not Fit for the Analysis of Vertical
`
`The Commission Failed
`
`to Give Due
`
`The Commission’s Speculative Prima Facie
`Case Fails to Account for the Likely Risk of
`
`Evidence of Likely Procompetitive Effects
`Should Not Be Ignored at Any Stage of
`
`v
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 7 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`Differential Treatment of Vertical and Horizontal
`
`In Theory, The Competitive Implications of
`
`II. The Open Offer Undercuts the Commission’s Prima Face
`Case and Its Disregard of Potential Remedies. ......................... 21
`III. The Economics of Vertical Integration Support the
`Mergers. ...................................................................................... 24
`A.
`Vertical Mergers Are Ambiguous. .................................... 25
`B. Empirical Research Establishes that Vertical
`Mergers Tend to Be Procompetitive In Practice. ............. 28
`C. New Research Does Not Undermine the Prevailing
`View of Vertical Mergers. .................................................. 31
`CONCLUSION ......................................................................................... 37
`APPENDIX A ............................................................................................ 38
`CERTIFICATE OF SERVICE .................................................................. 43
`CERTIFICATE OF COMPLIANCE ........................................................ 44
`
`
`
`
`
`
`vi
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 8 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`TABLE OF AUTHORITIES
`
`Page(s)
`
`Cases
`
`Bus. Elecs. Corp. v. Sharp Elecs. Corp., 485 U.S. 717 (1988) ................... 9
`Chicago Bridge & Iron Co. v. FTC, 534 F.3d 410 (5th Cir. 2008) ............ 8
`Cont’l T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977) ....................... 9
`Dr. Miles Med. Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co.,
`220 U.S. 373 (1911) ................................................................................. 9
`FTC v Penn State Hershey Medical Center,
`838 F.3d 327 (3d Cir. 2016) ................................................................... 15
`FTC v. H.J. Heinz Co., 246 F.3d 708 (D.C. Cir. 2001) ...................... 14, 15
`FTC v. Wilh. Wilhelmsen Holding ASA,
`341 F. Supp. 3d 27 (D.D.C. 2018) ......................................................... 15
`Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc.,
`551 U.S. 877 (2007) ........................................................................... 9, 25
`New York v. Deutsche Telekom AG,
`439 F. Supp. 3d 179 (S.D.N.Y. 2020) .................................................... 21
`Otto Bock HealthCare N. Am., Inc., 168 F.T.C. 324 (2019) .................... 15
`Republic Tobacco v. North Atlantic Trading Co.,
`381 F. 3d 717 (7th Cir. 2004) .................................................................. 7
`United States v. AT&T Inc., 310 F. Supp. 3d 161 (D.D.C. 2018),
`aff’d, 916 F.3d 1029 (D.C. Cir. 2019) .............................................. 10, 20
`United States v. AT&T, Inc.,
`916 F.3d 1029 (D.C. Cir. 2019) .............................. 7-8, 10, 14, 15, 20, 21
`United States v. Baker Hughes,
`908 F.2d 981 (D.C. Cir. 1990) ..................................................... 8, 15, 24
`United States v. General Dynamics Corp., 415 U.S. 486 (1974) ............. 23
`
`vii
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 9 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`United States v. H&R Block, Inc., 833 F. Supp. 2d 36
`(D.D.C. 2011) ............................................................................. 13, 14, 15
`United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365 (1967) ................. 9
`Statutes and Rules
`
`15 U.S.C. § 18, Clayton Act § 7, ......................................................... 13, 17
`Fed. R. App. P. 29(a)(2) .............................................................................. 1
`Fed. R. App. P. 29(a)(4)(e) .......................................................................... 2
`
`Other Authorities
`
`Phillip Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law
`(4th ed. 2017). .......................................................................................... 5
`Henry Ogden Armour & David J. Teece, Vertical Integration
`and Technological Integration, 62 Rev. Econ. & Stat. 470
`(1980) .................................................................................................. 4, 25
`Dennis W. Carlton, Transaction Costs and Competition Policy,
`73 Int’l J. Indus. Org. 1 (2019) .......................................................... 4, 25
`Malcom B. Coate & Andrew N. Kleit, Exclusion, Collusion, and
`Confusion: The Limits of Raising Rivals’ Costs, FTC Bureau of
`Economics Working Paper No. 179 (1990) ...................................... 27-28
`James C. Cooper, et al., Vertical Antitrust Policy as a Problem of
`Inference, 23 Int’l. J. Indus. Org. 639 (2005) ............................. 28, 29-30
`Gregory S. Crawford, et al., The Welfare Effects of Vertical
`Integration in Multichannel Television Markets, 86
`Econometrica 891 (2018) ................................................................. 16, 35
`Dep’t of Justice, Antitrust Division and FTC,
`2020 Vertical Merger Guidelines (2020) ........................... 3-4, 11, 15, 27
`Dep’t of Justice, Antitrust Division & FTC, Horizontal Merger
`Guidelines (Aug. 19, 2010) .................................................................... 11
`
`viii
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 10 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`FTC, Competition and Consumer Protection in the 21st Century:
`FTC Hearing #3: Multi-Sided Platforms, Labor Markets, and
`Potential Competition (Oct. 17, 2018) (transcript), available at
`https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/public_events/141
`3712/ftc_hearings_session_3_transcript_day_3_10-17-
`18_0.pdf. ............................................................................................ 35-36
`FTC, Competition and Consumer Protection in the 21st Century;
`FTC Hearing #5: Vertical Merger Analysis and the Role of the
`Consumer Welfare Standard in U.S. Antitrust Law, (Nov. 1,
`2018) (transcript), available at
`https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/public_events/141
`5284/ftc_hearings_session_5_transcript_11-1-18.pdf. ................... 33, 35
`Justine Hastings, Vertical Relationships and Competition in
`Retail Gasoline Markets: Empirical Evidence from Contract
`Changes in Southern California: Reply, 100 Am. Econ. Rev.
`1227 (2010) ............................................................................................. 34
`Justine S. Hastings & Richard J. Gilbert, Market Power,
`Vertical Integration, and the Wholesale Price of Gasoline,
`33 J. Indus. Econ. 469 (2005) ........................................................... 33-34
`Francine Lafontaine, Vertical Mergers, in FTC, Competition
`and Consumer Protection in the 21st Century; FTC Hearing #5:
`Vertical Merger Analysis and the Role of the Consumer Welfare
`Standard in U.S. Antitrust Law, (Nov. 1, 2018) (presentation
`slides), available at
`https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/public_events/141
`5284/ftc_hearings_5_georgetown_slides.pdf. .................................. 30-31
`Francine Lafontaine & Margaret E. Slade, Presumptions in
`Vertical Mergers: The Role of Evidence, 59 Rev. Indus. Org.
`255 (2021) ............................................................................................... 31
`Francine Lafontaine & Margaret Slade, Vertical Integration and
`Firm Boundaries: The Evidence, 45 J. Econ. Lit. 629, 677
`(2007) ...................................................................................................... 28
`
`ix
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 11 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`Fernando Luco & Guillermo Marshall, The Competitive Impact
`of Vertical Integration by Multiproduct Firms, 110 Am. Econ.
`Rev. 2041 (2020) ............................................................................... 32-33
`Geoffrey A. Manne, Kristian Stout & Eric Fruits, The Fatal
`Economic Flaws of the Contemporary Campaign Against
`Vertical Integration, 69 Kansas L. Rev. 923 (2020) ............................. 32
`Daniel O’Brien, The Antitrust Treatment of Vertical Restraint:
`Beyond the Possibility Theorems, in Konkurrensverket,
`Swedish Competition Authority, Report: The Pros and Cons of
`Vertical Restraints 22, 36 (2008) ..................................................... 26-27
`Janusz A. Ordover, Garth Saloner & Steven C. Salop,
`Equilibrium Vertical Foreclosure, 80 Am. Econ. Rev. 127
`(1990) ...................................................................................................... 27
`David Reiffen & Michael Vita, Comment: Is there New Thinking
`on Vertical Mergers? 63 Antitrust L.J. 917 (1995) ..................... 4, 25, 26
`Patrick Rey & Jean Tirole, A Primer on Foreclosure, in 3
`Handbook of Industrial Organization 2145 (Mark Armstrong
`& Robert H. Porter, eds.) (2007) ........................................................... 22
`Michael A. Salinger, Vertical Mergers and Market Foreclosure,
`103 Q.J. Econ. 345 (1988) ...................................................................... 26
`Steven C. Salop, Revising the Vertical Merger Guidelines, in
`FTC, Competition and Consumer Protection in the 21st
`Century; FTC Hearing #5: Vertical Merger Analysis and the
`Role of the Consumer Welfare Standard in U.S. Antitrust Law,
`(Nov. 1, 2018) (presentation slides), available at
`https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/public_events/141
`5284/ftc_hearings_5_georgetown_slides.pdf. ....................................... 32
`Steven C. Salop & David T. Scheffman, Cost-Raising Strategies,
`36 J. Indus. Econ. 19 (1985) .................................................................. 27
`
`x
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 12 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`Christopher T. Taylor, et al., Vertical Relationships and
`Competition in Retail Gasoline Markets: Empirical Evidence
`from Contract Changes in Southern California: Comment,
`100 Am. Econ. Rev. 1269 (2010) ........................................................... 34
`Oliver Williamson, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism
`(1985) ........................................................................................................ 4
`Joshua D. Wright & Jan M. Rybnicek, US v. AT&T Time
`Warner: A Triumph of Economic Analysis, 6 J. Antitrust
`Enforcement 3 (2018) ............................................................................ 11
`Chenyu Yang, Vertical Structure and Innovation: A Study of the
`SoC and Smartphone Industries, 51 Rand J. Econ. 739 (2020) .......... 16
`John M. Yun, Vertical Mergers and Integration in Digital
`Markets, in The GAI Report on the Digital Economy (Joshua
`D. Wright & Douglas H. Ginsburg, eds., 2020) at 245 ........................ 30
`
`
`xi
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 13 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`
`
`
`IDENTITY AND INTEREST OF AMICUS CURIAE AND
`SOURCE OF AUTHORITY TO FILE BRIEF
`The International Center for Law & Economics (“ICLE”) is a
`
`nonprofit, nonpartisan, global research and policy center aimed at
`
`building the intellectual foundations for sensible, economically grounded
`
`policy. ICLE promotes the use of law and economics methodologies, and
`
`economic findings, to inform public policy, and has longstanding
`
`expertise in antitrust law. 
`
`Amici also include 29 scholars of antitrust, law, and economics at
`
`leading universities and research institutions across the United States.
`
`Their names, titles, and academic affiliations are listed in Appendix A.
`
`All amici have extensive expertise in antitrust law and economics, and
`
`several served in senior positions at the Federal Trade Commission or
`
`the Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice.
`
`Amici have an interest in ensuring that courts and agencies
`
`correctly apply the standards for evaluating horizontal and vertical
`
`mergers, and take into account the benefits commonly associated with
`
`vertical mergers.
`
`
`
`Amici are authorized to file this brief by Fed. R. App. P. 29(a)(2)
`
`because all parties have consented to its filing.
`
`
`
`
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 14 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`RULE 29(a)(4)(e) STATEMENT
`Amici hereby state that no party’s counsel authored this brief in
`
`whole or in part; that no party or party’s counsel contributed money that
`
`was intended to fund the preparation or submission of the brief; and that
`
`no person other than amicus or its counsel contributed money that was
`
`intended to fund the preparation or submission of the brief.
`
`
`
`
`
`2
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 15 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY OF ARGUMENT
`The FTC’s decision to require Illumina to divest Grail rests on at
`
`least two misguided premises. The first is that the same scrutiny applies
`
`to both horizontal and vertical mergers. The second is that benefits
`
`typically associated with vertical mergers do not apply here.
`
`A horizontal merger combines firms that compete in the same
`
`relevant market, which necessarily reduces the number of firms engaged
`
`in head-to-head competition and may eliminate substitutes. That
`
`reduction inherently tends to increase prices, but the price effect may be
`
`trivial. In addition, market responses (competitive repositioning or new
`
`entry) or other benefits of the merger (savings in transaction and other
`
`costs, enhanced investment incentives) may neutralize or offset the
`
`impetus to higher prices. But because those benefits are not automatic
`
`(and the reduction of direct competition is), they must be proven rather
`
`than assumed if the merger otherwise poses a significant risk of
`
`anticompetitive effects.
`
`A vertical merger, in contrast, combines firms with an upstream-
`
`downstream (e.g., seller-buyer) relationship—that is, “firms or assets at
`
`different stages of the same supply chain.” Dep’t of Justice, Antitrust
`
`3
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 16 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`Division and FTC, Vertical Merger Guidelines 1 (2020). Examples
`
`include a manufacturer’s acquiring a distributor or a firm providing a
`
`manufacturing input.
`
`The economic consequences of combining complements rather than
`
`substitutes are fundamentally different. Whereas the first-order effect of
`
`a horizontal merger is upward pricing pressure, the first-order effect of a
`
`vertical merger is downward pricing pressure. Vertical mergers typically
`
`entail the elimination of double marginalization (“EDM”), which is akin
`
`to downward pricing pressure
`
`(and often considered alongside
`
`efficiencies). David Reiffen & Michael Vita, Comment: Is There New
`
`Thinking on Vertical Mergers? 63 Antitrust L.J. 917, 920 (1995). Vertical
`
`integration also typically internalizes externalities in research and
`
`development, resulting in greater investment. Henry Ogden Armour &
`
`David J. Teece, Vertical Integration and Technological Innovation, 62
`
`Rev. Econ. & Stat. 470 (1980). Like horizontal mergers, vertical mergers
`
`often confer other benefits such as operational and transactional
`
`efficiencies. Dennis W. Carlton, Transaction Costs and Competition
`
`Policy, 73 Int’l J. Indus. Org. 1 (2019); Oliver Williamson, The Economic
`
`Institutions of Capitalism 86 (1985).
`
`4
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 17 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`Thus, while both types of mergers can create benefits from cost
`
`savings, their intrinsic effects move in opposite directions: higher prices
`
`and less investment with horizontal mergers, and lower prices and more
`
`investment with vertical mergers.
`
`1.
`
`The FTC’s conclusion that the same scrutiny applies to
`
`horizontal and vertical mergers, Opinion 75, conflicts with precedent
`
`(and long-standing economic research). Courts and economists alike
`
`recognize that vertical integration typically is procompetitive, and it is
`
`widely accepted that vertical mergers and horizontal mergers should be
`
`evaluated under different presumptions. As the leading antitrust treatise
`
`puts it, “[i]n the great majority of cases no anticompetitive consequences
`
`can be attached to [vertical integration], and injury to competition should
`
`never be inferred from the mere fact of vertical integration.” 3B Phillip
`
`Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 755a (4th ed. 2017). That
`
`vertical mergers can be anticompetitive—under specific facts and
`
`circumstances—does not establish that vertical integration is likely to be
`
`anticompetitive (it is not) or that there is no useful antitrust distinction
`
`between vertical and horizontal mergers (there is).
`
`5
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 18 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`The Commission did not simply presume that this vertical merger
`
`would be anticompetitive, however. It also discounted both the likelihood
`
`of efficiencies in vertical mergers and specific evidence of efficiencies
`
`associated with the already-consummated merger. As a result, the
`
`Commission did not properly assess the likely competitive effects of the
`
`merger.
`
`2.
`
`The Commission also disregarded evidence of a current and
`
`operative constraint on any potential anticompetitive effects of the
`
`merger. Illumina’s Open Offer appears to be contractually binding, and
`
`addresses the risk of foreclosure that is the primary competitive concern
`
`here. Proper consideration of the Open Offer should have shifted the
`
`Commission
`
`further away
`
`from presuming harm. Instead, the
`
`Commission gave it no weight.
`
`3. The existing standards for vertical merger scrutiny are
`
`informed by, and consistent with, economic research regarding vertical
`
`mergers and other forms of vertical integration. That research shows that
`
`the Commission was wrong to hold that vertical and horizontal mergers
`
`should be analyzed identically, and wrong to disregard the well-
`
`established benefits of vertical integration. While economic theory
`
`6
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 19 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`indicates that vertical mergers can be anticompetitive, the weight of the
`
`empirical evidence overwhelmingly indicates that they tend to be
`
`procompetitive or competitively neutral. Indeed, the large majority of
`
`vertical mergers that have been studied have been found to be
`
`procompetitive or benign. That suggests that case-specific evidence is
`
`paramount in assessing both potential anticompetitive effects and
`
`countervailing pro-consumer efficiencies.
`
`ARGUMENT
`I. Vertical and Horizontal Mergers Should Be Scrutinized
`Differently.
`A. Prima Facie Standards and the Government’s
`“Ultimate Burden” Differ in Horizontal and Vertical
`Merger Cases.
`
`Courts have long recognized that horizontal and vertical mergers
`
`are categorically different. “As horizontal agreements are generally more
`
`suspect than vertical agreements,” courts are “cautious about importing
`
`relaxed standards of proof into vertical agreement cases.” Republic
`
`Tobacco v. North Atlantic Trading Co., 381 F. 3d 717, 737 (7th Cir. 2004).
`
`Thus, for vertical mergers, “unlike horizontal mergers, the government
`
`cannot use a shortcut to establish a presumption of anticompetitive
`
`effect.…” United States v. AT&T, Inc., 916 F.3d 1029, 1032 (D.C. Cir.
`
`7
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 20 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`2019) (“AT&T II”). In a vertical merger case, “the government must make
`
`a fact-specific showing that the proposed merger is likely to be
`
`anticompetitive,” and the “ultimate burden of persuasion… remains with
`
`the government at all times.” Id. (emphasis added; cleaned up).
`
`As the ALJ’s Initial Decision (ID) recognized (at 132), the burden-
`
`shifting approach is not bound by any specific, sequential form. Then-
`
`Judge Thomas stressed in United States v. Baker Hughes, 908 F.2d 981,
`
`984 (D.C. Cir. 1990), that “[t]he Supreme Court has adopted a totality-of-
`
`the-circumstances approach…, weighing a variety of factors to determine
`
`the effects of particular transactions on competition.” As the ALJ aptly
`
`put it, the Baker Hughes “‘burden-shifting language’” provides “‘a flexible
`
`framework rather than an air-tight rule’”; “in practice, evidence is often
`
`considered all at once and the burdens are often analyzed together.” ID
`
`132 (quoting Chicago Bridge & Iron Co. v. FTC, 534 F.3d 410, 424-24 (5th
`
`Cir. 2008)).
`
`The differential treatment of vertical and horizontal mergers
`
`parallels the Supreme Court’s vertical restraints jurisprudence. The
`
`potential anticompetitive effects of vertical restraints are similar to those
`
`8
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 21 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`posed by vertical mergers, as both obtain between firms at different levels
`
`of the supply chain.
`
`Over time, the Supreme Court has eliminated per se condemnation
`
`for vertical restraints. In 1977, the Court rejected per se illegality for
`
`vertical non-price restraints, Cont’l T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433
`
`U.S. 36, 49, 52 n.19, 58 (1977) (overruling United States v. Arnold,
`
`Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365 (1967)), later confirming that “a vertical
`
`restraint is not illegal per se unless it includes some agreement on price
`
`or price levels.” Bus. Elecs. Corp. v. Sharp Elecs. Corp., 485 U.S. 717, 735-
`
`36 (1988). Eventually, the Court repudiated the last vertical per se
`
`prohibition—of vertical minimum price restraints. Leegin Creative
`
`Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877 (2007) (overruling Dr.
`
`Miles Med. Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373 (1911)). In these
`
`decisions, the Court emphasized that any departure from the evidence-
`
`specific rule of reason “must be based on demonstrable economic effect,
`
`rather than . . . upon formalistic line drawing.” Bus. Elecs., 485 U.S. at
`
`724.
`
`These decisions reflect a nearly categorical repudiation of
`
`presumptions of illegality in dealings involving entities at different levels
`
`9
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 22 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`of the supply chain. Here, however, the Commission took the opposite
`
`approach, presuming anticompetitive effect while rejecting the
`
`significance of rigorously established benefits in a way that approaches a
`
`per se standard. This Court should reject that departure from sound law
`
`and economics.
`
`B. The FTC Did Not Undertake the Necessary Fact-
`Specific Examination of
`the Merged Firm’s
`Incentives Given the Merger’s Efficiencies.
`The FTC had to show that Illumina has a greater incentive to
`
`foreclose rivals following—and because of—the merger. Instead, the
`
`Commission adopted a standard of review that elides the requirement
`
`that, in a vertical merger case where there is “no presumption of harm in
`
`play,” “the government must make a fact-specific showing that the
`
`proposed merger is likely to be anticompetitive” both at the prima facie
`
`stage and in the final analysis. United States v. AT&T Inc., 310 F. Supp.
`
`3d 161, 192 (D.D.C. 2018) (“AT&T I”), aff’d, 916 F.3d 1029 (D.C. Cir.
`
`2019); see AT&T II, 916 F.3d at 1032.
`
`To be sure, there is little recent case law regarding the standard of
`
`review for vertical mergers because the federal antitrust agencies have
`
`rarely challenged,
`
`let alone
`
`litigated, vertical acquisitions. The
`
`10
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 23 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`Department of Justice challenge to the AT&T/Time Warner merger
`
`marked “the first time in 40 years that a court has heard a fully-litigated
`
`challenge to a vertical merger.” Joshua D. Wright & Jan M. Rybnicek,
`
`US v. AT&T Time Warner: A Triumph of Economic Analysis, 6 J.
`
`Antitrust Enforcement 3 (2018).
`
`Nevertheless, up to now, the agencies have considered likely
`
`structural benefits, transactional efficiencies, and potential remedies,
`
`along with potential harms, in toto and on net, in assessing a merger’s
`
`likely competitive impact. Hence, the Vertical Merger Guidelines—
`
`jointly adopted by the FTC and the Antitrust Division of the Department
`
`of Justice in June 2020 (although withdrawn by the FTC while this case
`
`was pending)—state that “[t]he Agencies do not challenge a merger if
`
`cognizable efficiencies are of a character and magnitude such that the
`
`merger is unlikely to be anticompetitive in any relevant market.” Vertical
`
`Merger Guidelines at 11. Even under the Horizontal Merger Guidelines,
`
`“[t]he Agency will not challenge a merger if cognizable efficiencies are of
`
`a character and magnitude such that the merger is not likely to be
`
`anticompetitive.” Dep’t of Justice, Antitrust Division & FTC, Horizontal
`
`Merger Guidelines § 10 (Aug. 19, 2010).
`
`11
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 24 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`But here the Commission did not seriously account for likely
`
`efficiencies or other benefits that may be derived from practices
`
`inconsistent with foreclosure. Put simply, Illumina’s ability to profit from
`
`the merger without foreclosing rivals reduces its incentive to foreclose.
`
`Although the foreclosure incentive may remain on some margins, the
`
`question of the greater incentive cannot be resolved without assessing
`
`the incentives against foreclosure as well as those for it.
`
`Illumina’s post-merger incentive to foreclose rivals may be
`
`constrained by:
`
`● its interest in revenue realized from a broader array of
`
`sequencing clients than the relatively few engaged in multi-
`
`cancer early detection (MCED) research;
`
`● the procompetitive—and pro-consumer—cost advantages it is
`
`likely to realize from integration with Grail;
`
`● the relatively low risk of entry by close substitutes for Galleri in
`
`the near, or even foreseeable, future;
`
`● the Open Offer;
`
`● reputational or transactional harms that may result from
`
`refusing to deal with firms in its industry; and
`
`12
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 25 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`● the
`
`litigation and regulatory risks attending attempted
`
`foreclosure.
`
`But the FTC presumed away these and other factors that could mitigate
`
`the risk of harm.
`
`1. Presumptions Suitable to Horizontal Mergers Are
`Not Fit for the Analysis of Vertical Mergers
`The Commission maintains that the same scrutiny applies to
`
`efficiencies claims in vertical and horizontal transactions. To justify this
`
`conclusion, the Commission declined to “simply take managers’ word for
`
`efficiencies without independent verification, because then the efficiency
`
`defense ‘might well swallow the whole of Section 7,’ as managers could
`
`present large unsubstantiated efficiencies claims and courts would be
`
`hard pressed to find otherwise.” Opinion 75-76 (quoting United States v.
`
`H&R Block, Inc., 833 F. Supp. 2d 36, 91 (D.D.C. 2011). But this is a non
`
`sequitur, and wrong for three reasons.
`
`First, the Commission need not (and the ID did not) “simply take
`
`managers’ word for efficiencies.” As the Initial Decision noted, courts and
`
`academic authorities both recognize procompetitive effects, including
`
`efficiencies, generally observed with vertical integration. ID 133-35, 196.
`
`13
`
`

`

`Case: 23-60167 Document: 124 Page: 26 Date Filed: 06/12/2023
`
`See also ID 135 (noting case-specific evidence regarding research and
`
`development efficiencies, EDM, and the acceleration of access).
`
`Second, to support its rejection of competitive benefits, the FTC
`
`continued to conflate the legal standards for horizontal and vertical
`
`mergers, relying only on serial string citations to horizontal merger
`
`cases. Opinion 75-76. Because a vertical merger puts direct, downward
`
`pressure on prices and upward pressure on complementary
`
`investments—the inverse of horizontal merger effects—the reliance on
`
`horizontal cases highlights the Commission’s failure to recognize the
`
`fundamental difference between horizontal and vertical integration. See
`
`AT&T II, 916 F.3d at 1032.
`
`Third, ignoring that distinction, and the resulting need for a “fact-
`
`specific showing” of the likely anticompetitive effects of a vertical merger,

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.