throbber
LEADING ARTICLE
`
`Pharmacoeccnorncs 1997 May: it (5) 389-397
`I l rcnavo/9710005 0389/$04 50/0
`43.‘ Adis International Ltrnvtacl. Alright‘-. reserved
`
`The Effect of Pharmacoeconomics
`
`on Company Research and
`Development Decisions
`
`Henry Grabowski
`
`Department of Economics, Duke University, Durham, North Carolina, USA
`
`Summary
`
`There is a strong rationale for integrating phamiacoeconomics into research
`and development (R&D) project selection and termination decisions. The average
`cost for the typical new drug introduction now exceeds $US300 million. Further-
`more, a growing proportion of phase III projects are terminated because of eco-
`nomic factors relative to efficacy and safety concerns. While the use of
`pharmacoeconomic studies by payers is still evolving, the pressures on firms to
`show that new products are cost effective will only intensify in future periods.
`Accordingly, it is imponant for firms to begin analysing the cost effectiveness of
`new drug candidates early in the R&D process.
`The cost effectiveness of a new therapy can be simulated prior to clinical
`testing using different assumptions about the efficacy, tolerability. pricing and
`fonnulation of the new therapy. These models can be refined and updated as data
`become available from clinical testing and other sources. A key objective is to
`make uncompetitive projects fail sooner while channelling development re-
`sources to projects with high expected returns. Cost—effectiveness analysis should
`be an integral component of the firms‘s strategic action plan and its return on
`investment analyses.
`
`The use of pharmacoeconomics in research and
`development (R&D) decisions has been growing
`over time. Nevertheless. few companies appear to
`currently employ it as an integral part of their stra-
`tegic decision-making approach to selecting and
`terminating projects. A 1993 survey found that only
`40% of major phannaceutical companies used
`pharmacoeconomics for R&D decisions, com-
`pared with over 90% in the case of marketing and
`reimbursement decisions.'” This
`situation is
`
`changing. however, given the new competitive dy-
`namics now at work in the industry.
`The primary objective of this article is to con-
`sider how pharmacoeconomics can be employed in
`the R&D process to improve a company’s produc-
`tivity and return on its investment. Ideally, phar-
`macoeconomic analysis should begin early in the
`development stage. It should be refined in an iter-
`ative fashion as new data become available from
`
`clinical trials and other sources, as a major function
`
`Dr. Reddy's Laboratories, Ltd., et al_ v. Helsinn Healthcare S_A_
`Page 1 of 9
`Trial PGR2016-00007
`
`Helsinn Healthcare Exhibit 2038
`
`

`
`390
`
`Grabmuski
`
`Q
`I
`
`INFA-:
`NCFS
`
`~ 300
`
`200
`
`—l5O
`
`— 100NumberofNCE:8.NDAs
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`R&DexpenditureSUSDIIIIOHS,1990Vcl|L)QS1
`
`
`1980
`1081
`1982
`1983
`1984
`1085
`Kiss
`1os7
`1988
`1083
`1996
`1001
`Year
`
`J
`
`0
`
`1995
`
`Fig. 1. Expenditures on research and development (R&D). and the numbers oi new chemical entities (NCEs) and invcstigational
`new drug applications (INDAs). between 1980 and 1992.|3‘4l
`
`of pharmacoeconomics in the internal decision-
`making process is to identify uncompetitive pro-
`jects at an earlier stage.
`
`1. The New Competitive Dynamics
`
`Although there is great optimism at the present
`time about the scientific potential for important
`new drug discoveries, there is also mounting evi-
`dence that R&D costs are growing rapidly in real
`temts. DiMasi et al.”] found that it took an average
`of $US23l million (1987 values) and 12 years to
`discover and develop a typical drug in the mid-
`1980s. This figure includes the cost of candidates
`that fail in the R&D process, and the interest or
`time costs associated with the long investment pe-
`riod for new drugs. If this number were simply up-
`dated for general economy-wide inflation. the cur-
`rent cost of discovering and developing a new drug
`introduction would exceed $US300 million (1995
`values). However, there is reason to believe that the
`
`rise in R&D costs for new drugs significantly ex-
`ceeds general inflation.
`
`Figure I shows the annual R&D expenditures of
`Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of
`
`America (PhRMA) member companies between
`1980 and 1992. It also shows the annual number of
`
`invcstigational new drug applications (INDAS) and
`new chemical entities (NCEs) approved by the US
`Food and Drug Administration (FDA). It indicates
`that R&D expenditures have increased several-fold
`since the early 1980s, while the annual numbers of
`lNDAs and NCEs have changed only moderately.
`DiMasi and colleagues at the Center for the
`Study of Drug Development are currently under-
`taking an update of their prior analyses of R&D
`costsm Although the issue of R&D costs is best
`analysed with a representative sample of NCES, the
`aggregate data series in figure 1 strongly suggest
`that R&D investment costs per new drug introduc-
`tion have continued to increase significantly in real
`terms over the past decade.
`What are the reasons for the rapid increase in
`R&D costs over time? Among the factors cited in
`the literature are increased research on drugs for
`
`'0 Ads htemotlonot Limited. All rights reserved.
`
`Pharnocoeconomics I997 May; 11 (5)
`
`Page 2 of 9
`
`

`
`Research and Development Decisions
`
`391
`
`difficult-to-treat chronic diseases, higher discov-
`ery costs, and much higher out-of-pocket costs in
`the development phase.
`With respect to this last factor, various studies
`indicate that approved NCES now involve an in-
`creasing number of phase III trials, as well as an
`increasing number of patients per trial.‘-“"' This is
`an important reason to begin pharmacoeconomic
`studies early, so that the economic prospects of a
`new drug candidate can be evaluated before under-
`taking costly phase III trials.
`Another reason for beginning pharmacoecono-
`mic studies early is that returns on new drugs are
`highly variable. The distribution of returns across
`various cohorts of new drug introductions are
`highly skewed across NCEs.'7-3' For example, fig-
`ure 2 shows the present values of net revenue,
`grouped according to decile, for 1980 to 1984 US
`NCE introductions. The top decile has an estimated
`present value of net revenues that is more than 5
`times the average capitalised R&D cost. Hence,
`these products recoup a disproportionate share of
`the returns on R&D. Furthermore, only the top 3
`deciles have present values of net revenue that ex-
`
`ceed average R&D costs. The products below the
`third decile do not typically cover the average dis-
`covery costs or the costs of the large numbers of
`products that fail in the development process.
`This analysis indicates the importance of inno-
`vative drugs to a company’s returns on R&D and
`its ongoing viability in the phamiaceutical indus-
`try. In particular, companies must enhance the like-
`lihood of producing drugs with the economic char-
`acteristics of those in the top deciles if they are to
`earn positive, long tenn returns on their total port-
`folio of projects. Furthermore, most companies are
`dependent on a small number of very high volume
`products for the majority of their sales and profits.
`A large number of these blockbuster products have
`patents that are due to expire in the next few
`years,l9‘ with rapid sales losses now being com-
`monplace when gencric products enter the market;
`a recent analysis indicates that major products can
`be expected to lose more than 50% of their sales
`within the first few months of generic entry.'“"
`The implications of figure 2 can also be consid-
`ered from the perspective of public and private
`payers. Historically, the drugs in the top decile
`
`
`
`
`
`Alter-laxPV(SJSmlll|0l'lSL1990values)
`
`1200-
`
`7:588II
`
`Averaqe R&D cost
`
`Declle
`
`9
`
`10
`
`Fig. 2. Present values (Pvs) of alter-tax net revenue. grouped according to decile, for new chemical entities introduced in the US
`between 1980 and 1984.17‘ Abbreviation: R&D = research and development.
`
`«:3 Adis International Limited. All rights reserved,
`
`Phormocoeconornics I997 May: I l (5)
`
`Page 3 of 9
`
`

`
`392
`
`Grabowski
`
`have been the first or second products launched in
`their particular therapeutic class. They are typically
`launched at premium prices, and are the products
`that generally result in the rapid growth of phanna-
`ceutical budgets of payers. With the increased cost
`consciousness exhibited by payers in the 1990s,
`there is an increasing burden on companies to show
`that innovative new products really do provide sig-
`nificant value for money to users.“ '1 Products that
`cannot demonstrate this through superior therapeu-
`tic propenies will need to offer significant price
`discounts, relative to current entities, to be cost
`effective.
`
`A recent analysis of drugs launched in the US in
`I992 and 1993 shows that this competitive process
`is well under way."’] The vast majority of new drugs
`were launched at significant discounts relative to
`the market leader in their therapeutic class. In the
`markets of countries in which drug products are
`subject to price regulations and reimbursement
`controls, there is also a growing need for compa-
`nies to justify price premiums for innovative prod-
`ucts on the basis of cost effectiveness and other
`
`pharmacoeconomic analyses} ' " '31
`In this more competitive environment, it is in-
`cumbent on companies to undertake early strategic
`analysis of their R&D portfolios, with phar-
`macoeconomic analysis being one of its main tools.
`R&D resources should be directed towards prod-
`ucts that can provide users with high value for
`money. Early indicators, using pharmacoeconomic
`analysis, may identify products that cannot earn an
`acceptable rate of return and these should be can-
`didates for early termination.
`
`2. Pharmacoeconomics and the
`
`Drug-Development Process
`
`2.1 Early-Stage Development Planning
`
`The R&D process for pharmaceuticals involves
`sequential decision-making under uncertain condi-
`tions. At each stage, the company can incur incre-
`mental costs to obtain additional information and
`then decide whether it wishes to continue to the
`
`next stage.l"‘~'5l
`
`There are a set of natural decision points or mile-
`stones in this process. These involve the decision
`to establish a discovery programme in a particular
`disease area, to form a project team for preclinical
`development of a promising compound, the first
`human testing of the compound, the first efficacy
`testing in patients, the decision to undertake large-
`scale clinical testing, regulatory submission and
`marketing launch. As a compound moves through
`each stage of development, the resource commit-
`ments also grow significantly. This relates primar-
`ily to the increased number of patients and trials at
`each stage.‘
`Companies should begin internal modelling
`analysis on the cost effectiveness of a product well
`in advance of the go/no-go decision on phase III
`trials. Before committing major resources to a de-
`velopment project, a company should know the po-
`tential value of a new therapy. It is also important
`to understand, at an early stage, who the key deci-
`sion—makers are in selecting treatment regimens
`and how they are likely to weigh gains in clinical.
`economic or quality-of—life outcomes.
`The first step in this planning process is to un-
`dertake an impact analysis of the illness using cur-
`rent treatment options. The main objective of this
`analysis is to find out what factors account for most
`of the disease impact, and also to obtain a bench-
`mark on the cost effectiveness of current thera-
`
`pics.‘ '‘’-'7' Using information from the impact anal-
`ysis, a simulation model can then be constructed,
`which analyses the desired effects of the new drug
`candidate on the burden of the illness, using the
`target clinical profile. This model can be used to
`estimate both patient progression through the
`health states and the cost effectiveness of various
`
`options involving different assumptions about the
`efficacy, tolerability, pricing and formulation of the
`new therapy.
`
`First human testing (phase 1) is performed on a small
`I
`number of individuals to obtain safety infnnnation on dosage
`ranges. A few hundred individuals are required in first clinical
`trials that assess efficacy (phase ll). This leads to the key go’no-go
`decision point on whether to undertake (expensive) phase III
`testing on several thousand patients to show ‘substantial evi-
`dence‘ of tolerability and efficacy to regulatory authorities.
`
`vo Adls International Limited. All rights reserved.
`
`Phamocoeconomics I997 May: It (5)
`
`Page 4 of 9
`
`

`
`Research and Development Decisions
`
`393
`
`In the early stages of the R&D process, it is very
`important for the company to learn as much as pos-
`sible about the sensitivity of the product’s cost ef-
`fectiveness to changes in various parameters. This
`analysis must be done with reference to existing
`treatment options, and is incremental in nature (i.e.
`how much would the proposed product alter cost
`effectiveness compared with the usual standard of
`care and other products?).“"‘ If it is found, for ex-
`ample, that the cost effectiveness of the product
`under consideration is highly sensitive to the costs
`of treating adverse effects. this will be an important
`input to the target profile of the drug. In addition,
`this kind of information will be useful in planning
`data-collection efforts to ensure that the correct in-
`
`puts are obtained in the clinical trial process and
`from other data sources. The simulation model
`
`may also be useful in determining the indications
`toward which the drug should be targeted, if the
`analysis shows that the product could be especially
`cost effective for particular subpopulations.
`As an illustrative example, it is useful to con-
`sider the steps that are necessary to construct a sim-
`ulation model for a company considering a new
`antineoplastic therapy.’ The first step is to model
`the progression of patients through different health
`states, according to existing antineoplastic therapy
`regimens. Each state is associated with different
`costs and patients’ levels of well-being. Data inputs
`for the clinical parameters include the rates of pro-
`gression, mortality and adverse effects.“9] Costs
`analysed in the model include those associated
`with drug administration. treatment of adverse ef-
`fects, and treatment and monitoring of the under-
`lying disease symptoms. Data pertaining to clinical
`parameters and resource use can be obtained. at
`this stage, from the published literature, expert
`opinions and, possibly, patient questionnaires. The
`model provides outputs in terms of measures such
`as cost per increased year of survival (possibly
`quality-adjusted), and can be used to simulate the
`
`This pedagogical example is based on a discussion with
`2
`Dr Josephine Mauskopf of Glaxo Wellcome, Inc.. Research
`Triangle Park. North Carolina, US. which recently launched
`a product for non—small-cell lung cancer.
`
`cost effectiveness of a new treatment regimen with
`alternative profiles of clinical outcomes and eco-
`nomic values, and then to compare this with exist-
`ing treatments.
`Sharples et al.”‘’' developed a model ofthis kind
`in the area of transplantation, which investigated
`the primary clinical events after cardiac transplan-
`tation and linked them with survival and costs. Em-
`
`ploying a Markov modelling approach. they used
`observed survival rates, and estimated resource use
`
`and costs for patients in this environment. The
`model was estimated using data from a UK hospital
`that performs cardiac transplants. The authorsl2°‘
`showed how this model can be used to analyse the
`cost effectiveness of a proposed new immunosup-
`pressive therapy. This was accomplished by trac-
`ing its projected effects on the transition prob-
`abilities between disease states and the associated
`
`resource use and costs. This is another example of
`how a pharmacoeconomic simulation model can be
`utilised by companies in the R&D planning pro-
`cess to assess candidate drug treatments.
`This internal modelling analysis is not only use-
`ful in assessing the potential of self-originated
`drug candidates, but also those arising from licens-
`ing and partnership opportunities. The number of
`new products that originate outside the traditional
`pathways of the major company R&D organi-
`sations has grown dramatically in recent years,
`with the emergence of the biotechnology industry
`and related developments.'2” Agreements between
`companies are now structured with various mile-
`stones and key decision pointsml Pharmaco-
`economic analysis can be useful both for the nego-
`tiation of terms, and to facilitate the sale and the
`
`licensing out of compounds that the companies
`choose not to pursue.
`
`2.2 Strategic Planning and
`Go/No—Go Decisions
`
`The simulation model formulated in the earlier
`
`stages of development can be refined as clinical
`data become available, and used in conjunction
`with economic modelling to formulate a strategic
`action plan. In particular, the company can use it
`
`-3 Adis Intemohoncl Limited. All rights reserved
`
`Phormacoeconomics 1997 May: ll (5)
`
`Page 5 of 9
`
`

`
`394
`
`Grabmvski
`
`with traditional retum-on-investment analyses that
`incorporate cost, demand and other relevant com-
`petitive considerations.““l Before making the
`go/no-go decision on phase III trials, it is important
`to determine whether the set of prices that can
`achieve the company’s target return on investment
`is feasible in terms of what payers are expected to
`pay, based on the product’s projected cost effec-
`tivencss.
`
`In a recent paper on clinical success rates,
`DiMasi[27" found that there is a clear tendency for
`economics to become an increasingly important
`reason for project termination as product candi-
`dates progress through the development cycle. In-
`deed. economics has become the leading cause of
`product terminations that occur 4 years or more
`after INDA f"iling.[23l For the 1980 to I984 cohort
`of INDA filings, 43% of these later-stage termina-
`tions were the result of economic factors. com-
`
`pared with 31% for efficacy problems and 21% for
`tolerability problems.
`Economics also accounts for an increasing rel-
`ative share of INDA terminations for recent time
`
`cohorts, compared with older ones. In this regard,
`economic factors explained 27% of all NCE termi-
`nations in the I980 to 1984 cohort, compared with
`22% for the cohort beginning a decade earlienml
`More significantly, at December 1993, economics
`was the cause of 29% of all research abandonments
`
`for the 1985 to 1989 cohort of INDA filings, al-
`though it should be noted that this is a relatively
`short time period to observe INDA terminations.
`As a consequence, there is still a large proportion
`of open INDAS, and the results for this cohort are
`biased toward causes that are revealed relatively
`soon after INDA filing (i.e. factors associated with
`tolerability and efficacy). Hence, the share of aban-
`donments related to economic factors can be ex-
`
`pected to grow significantly for this cohort as more
`time elapses.
`While the majority of projects are terminated
`before 4 years, and efficacy is the most important
`overall factor in project failures. the projects tenni-
`nated in the later stages obviously result in the larg-
`est financial losses to the company.
`
`DiMasi’s findingsml are consistent with the
`changing cost consciousness on the part of payers
`(section I). His findings also point to the increasing
`importance of utilising pharmacoeconomic analy-
`ses as a strategic decision—making input during the
`clinical trial period. As initial data on formulation,
`tolerability and efficacy become available from
`phase I and II trials, the modelling analysis of cost
`effectiveness that began in earlier periods (using
`best-guess estimates) must be updated in an itera-
`tive fashion. Information on resource use and costs
`
`should also be refined during this period. Ideally,
`uncertainty surrounding the project’s cost effec-
`tiveness and the likelihood of the company achiev-
`ing its rate-of-retum target can be substantially re-
`duced before undertaking expensive phase III
`clinical trials.
`
`Paul Freiman, former chief executive of Syntex
`Corporation, Palo Alto, California, has provided 2
`case-history examples of how pharmacoeco-
`nomics have helped to shape the R&D portfolio of
`that company (personal communication). The first
`product example involved a new cholesterol-
`lowering drug with a novel mechanism of action.
`about which the company’s scientists were very
`excited. The current group of major cholesterol-
`lowering drugs, the HMG-CoA reductase inhibi-
`tors, has an established market presence, with 4
`drugs launched between 1988 and 1994. Each suc-
`ceeding product entrant in this class has been
`launched at a significant price discount relative to
`
`the pioneer drug, lovastatin.[3‘” In addition, the pro-
`posed product would have had a limited time on the
`market before 2 of the leading products in this class
`experienced patent expiration. Accordingly, the
`analysis conducted on this project indicated that a
`significant therapeutic gain in terms of cholesterol
`lowering, and thus mortality. was necessary for the
`new product to be both profitable and cost effec-
`tive. When the early clinical trials showed that, des-
`pite its novel mode of action, the product was only
`expected to be similar to existing entities in terms
`of efficacy and other key properties, it was termi-
`nated.
`
`to Adis International Limited. All rtgits reserved.
`
`Phorrnocoeconomics 1997 Mcv: l
`
`1 (5)
`
`Page 6 of 9
`
`

`
`Research and Development Decisions
`
`395
`
`The second case history involved the develop-
`ment of an antiemetic drug in the serotonin; (5-
`hydroxytryptamineg; 5-HT3) receptor antagonist
`class. This is a relatively new drug class, with only
`2 products on the US market in the first part of the
`l990s, ondansetron and granisetron. Animal data
`suggested that the proposed product would have a
`significant incremental gain in efficacy over these
`existing products. However, a specific, larger gain
`in efficacy was projected as being necessary for
`this product to demonstrate cost effectiveness at
`the price level that would be profitable on rate-
`of-return grounds. This outcome reflected the mar-
`keting lag of the product relative to the first 2 en-
`trants, as well as other economic considerations,
`
`such as the patent expiration dates of the early en-
`trants. Accordingly, when the targeted gain in effi-
`cacy was not realised in phase II studies, this pro-
`duct was terminated before undertaking major
`phase III clinical trials.
`Of course the use of pharmacoeconomics is not
`restricted to terminating uneconomic projects. For
`example, early modelling may indicate that a pro-
`duct candidate is highly cost effective compared
`with existing entities for a wide range of values
`centred around the target clinical profile. This in
`turn may result in higher projected market size
`and/or price for the product and cause the firm to
`assign a higher priority status to the project in its
`overall development programme.
`These examples show how pharmacoeconomic
`analysis can be employed in the R&D process to
`focus the company’s phase III development efforts
`on those projects with the greatest potential to be
`both technically and economically successful.
`Many products that were clearly profitable to de-
`velop in periods before cost constraints were com-
`mon (e.g. products with novel modes of actions,
`incremental advances in efficacy, etc.) now de-
`serve greater attention by drug companies, as buy-
`ers increasingly demand evidence that the pur-
`chase of new products is really cost effective
`and/or cost beneficial. In response to this new
`environment, many companies are now in the
`process of streamlining their development pro-
`
`gramme into fewer projects with more intensive
`resource commitments.l35-3°‘ Pharrnacoeconomics
`
`has an important role to play in the ‘weeding out’
`process, in conjunction with traditional return-
`on-invcstment analyses.
`
`2.3 Concerns and Qualifications
`
`2.3.1 Adequacy of Data
`To many company scientists, R&D directors
`and executives.
`the use of pharmacoeconomic
`analysis as an integral part of the go/no-go decision
`may be controversial. For one thing, it can be ar-
`gued that there will be too much uncertainty, at this
`point, about a product’s cost effectiveness to make
`a decision using available data. This may be true
`much of the time, but even if this is so, the company
`has little to lose from integrating pharmacoecono-
`mic analysis into the strategic decision-making
`process. As discussed. the analysis can be highly
`beneficial in targeting information that should be
`collected in phase Ill clinical trials and from other
`sources, in order to demonstrate cost effectiveness
`
`to prospective users. In addition, the cost of inter-
`nal modelling analyses, undertaken to this point, is
`likely to be small compared with the costs of un-
`dertaking clinical trials.
`As several
`researchers have observed,
`
`the
`
`randomised clinical trial design, while being the
`best approach to evaluate a product’s efficacy, pro-
`vides an artificial environment in which to observe
`
`many of the key inputs necessary for cost effective-
`ness and other pharmacoeconomic analysis.'37-331
`The problems include the use of placebo compara-
`tors in clinical trials rather than the usual standard
`
`of care, a focus on intermediate endpoints rather
`than ultimate health outcomes, the use of nonrcp-
`resentative populations, and the employment of ex-
`traordinary measures to ensure patient compliance
`with treatment regimens. As a consequence. phar-
`macoeconomic analysis typically requires signifi-
`cant data collection outside the clinical trial setting
`
`(and/or modelling) to supplant the evidence on ef-
`ficacy that arises from clinical trials.
`
`Co Adls lntemallonol Umited. All rights reserved.
`
`Pharmcxzoeconomics 1997 May; ll (5)
`
`Page 7 of 9
`
`

`
`396
`
`Gmbowski
`
`2.3.2 Inappropriate rermlnafion
`A second issue concerns the risks of terminating
`a project. identified as a likely loser. that could
`have resulted in a successful product. There are
`clearly 2 types of errors present in this situation.
`While the risk of prolonging projects that would
`ultimately be unsuccessful is reduced. the possibi-
`lity of terminating projects that would ultimately
`have proven to be successful is increased. The com-
`pany obviously must strike a balance between these
`2 types of errors.
`Some products introduced for one indication
`find an important use for another
`indication
`through serendipity in the clinical use of a product.
`To the extent that this is an important, but totally
`unpredictable, discovery pathway, attempts to
`make the decision process more rational and objec-
`tive (from the perspective of company decision-
`makers) may lead to inadvertent costs in the form
`of lost products (from society’s perspective).
`It is a principal thesis of this article that there
`are large benefits to be gained from identifying and
`terminating uncompetitive projects sooner, and
`that this issue warrants priority attention in the
`pharmaceutical
`industry. Several
`indicators are
`consistent with this point of view, including the
`growing percentage of NCE projects that are ter-
`minated in phase 111 because of economic factors,
`the failure of most NCES to fully recover R&D
`costs, and the continued introduction of many
`closely related products into crowded therapeutic
`classes. These trends were less of an issue to indus-
`
`try decision—makers in the 1970s and 19805, when
`expenditures on healthcare services were growing
`at double—digit rates. However, with the current
`pressures and constraints on healthcare expendi-
`tures in virtually all developed countries, it is pru-
`dent for companies to reconsider their R&D allo-
`cation decision-making as they have recently done
`with other areas of their business operations.
`
`2.3.3 Appropriate Use of Economics
`
`A final key issue is whether pharmacoeconomic
`analysis is really being used by decision—makers in
`the healthcare field to make product selection and
`utilisation decisions. If not, how can companies
`
`justify using them internally in R&D allocation de-
`cisions? We recently organised a conference at
`Duke University (Durham, N.C., USA) on the use
`of pharrnacoeconomic analysis by public and pri-
`vate decision-makers in the US and 6 other coun-
`
`tries. The resulting papers will be published
`soon.“” As expected, we found that the use of
`phannacoeconomic analysis in healthcare alloca-
`tion decisions is very mixed in nature.
`Managed care organisations (MCOs) in the US
`are clearly at the forefront, on the demand side, in
`applying these studies in drug adoption and utilisa-
`tion decisions.”'’' A high percentage of MCOS re-
`ported using external assessments in their drug-
`adoption and formulary decisions. At the same
`time. our symposium pointed to some definite hur-
`dles and barriers to the use of pharmacoeeonomie
`studies in both the public and private sectors. The
`expressed concerns ranged from methodological
`issues to questions about the relevance, timeliness
`and credibility of these studies. A discussion of all
`the relevant issues is beyond the scope of this arti-
`cle, but the core issues have recently received con-
`siderable attention in the literature.‘3°-3”
`
`Despite the expressed concerns, there is a strong
`prevailing view among the private-sector decision-
`makers who were surveyed in our symposium vol-
`ume (and several public-sector ones as well) that
`the importance of pharmacoeconomic analysis in
`healthcare decisions will evolve and grow rapidly
`in the future. Given the long timeframes associated
`with R&D decisions, it behooves pharmaceutical
`companies to begin internalising these approaches
`into their R&D allocation decisions.
`
`3. Conclusions
`
`The pressures on pharmaceutical companies to
`demonstrate the cost effectiveness of their new
`
`product introductions will only intensify in the
`coming years. Almost all major companies have
`recognised this fact and have begun to invest large
`sums in health economic analysis. However, to
`date, most of this effort has started late in the de-
`
`velopment process and has been done in an effort
`
`© Ads Inlernatloncl Llrnited. AI rlghts reserved.
`
`Phcumacoeconomics 1997 May; 11 (5)
`
`Page 8 of 9
`
`

`
`Research and Development Decisions
`
`397
`
`to influence product adoption and reimbursement
`decisions.
`
`The use of pharmacoeconomics in R&D plan-
`ning and selection decisions has been more limited
`in nature. Nevertheless, there is a strong rationale
`for integrating phannacoeconomic analysis di-
`rectly into strategic decision-making, starting as
`early as possible in the R&D process. As the eco-
`nomic hurdles for new products continue to rise,
`pharmacoeconomics has a key role to play in shap-
`ing the target profile of a new drug and helping to
`ensure that a company's R&D resources are being
`committed to those projects that are the most likely
`to produce a positive return on R&D investment.
`
`[xi
`
`References
`I . Kunze ZM, Lumley CE, Walker SR. Socioeconomic evaluation
`of medicines: a survey of the international pharmaceutical
`industry. Carshalton: Centre for Medicines Research. I993
`DiMasi J, Hansen R, Grabowski H, et al. The cost ofinnovation
`in the pharmaceutical industry. J Health Econ l99l: I0:
`107-42
`3. Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Association. PMA Annual Sur-
`vey Report: Trends in U.S. Pharmaceutical Sales and R&D,
`Washington. DC. I993
`4. DiMasi J. Seibring MA. Lasagna L. New drug development in
`the United States from I963 to 1992. Clin Pharmacol Ther
`I994: 55 (6): 609-22
`5. US. Congress Office of Technology Assessment. PItan'naceu-
`tical R&D: costs. risks and rewards. Washington, DC: Gov-
`emment Printing Office. I993
`6. The Boston Consulting Group. The changing environment for
`U.S. pharmaceuticals. New York: Apr 1993
`7. Grabowslti H. Vemon J. Retums to R&D on new drug introduc-
`tions in the |980s. J Health Econ I994; I3: 383-406
`8. Grabowslti H, Vernon J. A new look at the returns and risks to
`pharmaceutical R&D. Manage Sci I990: 36 (7): I67-85
`9. Shaw HK. Catalysts for change: the impact of generic drugs on
`the pharmaceutical industry. Burlington (MA ): Spectrum, Re-
`port 38. Decision Rcsourccs. Dec 28. I992
`I0. Grabowski H. Vernon J. Longer patents for increased generic
`competition in the US: the Waxman—Hatch Act after one de-
`cade. Pharmacoeconomics I996; l0 Suppl. 2:
`I I0-23
`ll. Sloan F, Grabowski H, editors. The role of cost-effectiveness
`analysis in public and private sector decisions. Soc Sci Med
`I997. In press
`I2. Davies L. Coyle D. Drummond M, et al. Current status of eco-
`nomic appraisal of health technology in the European Com-
`munity: report of the network. Soc Sci Med I994: 38 (I2):
`I60I-7
`I3. Druinmond M. Rutten F. Brenna A, et. al. Economic evaluation
`of pharmaceuticals: a European perspective. Pharmaco-
`economics I993: 4 (3): I73-86
`
`I4. Raiffa H. Decision analysis: introductory lectures on choices
`under uncertainty. New York: McGraw

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket