throbber
GENERIC DRUG INDUSTRY DYNAMICS
`
`David Reii’fen and Michael R. Ward’
`
`Abstractmaecatlse of its unique institutional and regulatory features. the
`generic drug industry provider I useful laboratory for understanding how
`competition evolves. We exploit these features to mtimate a system of
`structural relationships in this industry. including the relationship between
`price and the number ofcompetitors. and between drug characteristics and
`the entry process. Our methidology yields a number of findings regarding
`industry dynamics. We find that generic drug prices fall with increasing
`mimber of competitors. but remain above long-run marginal cost until
`there are eight or more competitors, We also find the size and time paths
`of genenc revenues. rents. and the number of firms are greatly aflected by
`expected market size Finally. we show how estimates du'lved from a
`system of structural equations can be used to simulate the effect of
`changes in an exogenous variable.
`
`I.
`
`Introduction
`
`0th the economics literature and the business press
`suggest that a typical pattern for a “new" industry [or
`what Jovanovic and MacDonald 0994) call an invention] is
`to have an initial phase in which a small number of firms
`each earn significant profits, followed by a phase in which
`rapid entry of new firms leads to increased competition and
`dissipation of some of those profits. often accompanied by
`a shakeout. whereby only a few large firms remain (espe-
`cially if subsequent innovations increase the optimal scale).
`Although this pattern seems to characterize many industries.
`the length of time during which early movers retain their
`profits. how prices adjust during the entry process. and the
`degree of shakcout vary widely across industries (Gon &
`Kleppor. 1982). Because the factors that influence the tim-
`ing of entry and exit are idiosyncratic to each industry,
`empirical studies of this process tend to focus on a single
`industry (see. for example. Gisser. 1999; Klepper & Simons.
`2000). and in a sense constitute a single data point. making
`generalizations tenuous.
`Several characteristics of the generic drug industry result
`in it being a useful laboratory for understanding how com-
`petition evolves within a market. First. each chemical rep-
`resents a distinct experiment. here are a large number of
`individual experiments within the same industry, providing
`multiple observations on similar dynamic processes.‘ Sec-
`ond. information about the market for each drug is observ-
`
`is. 2009. Revision accepted for
`
`Received for publication October
`publication October- 28. 2003.
`' Commodity Futures Trading Commission and University of‘l'exas at
`Arlington. respectively.
`We world like to thank our former employer. Ihe Federal Trade Com-
`mism'on. for admiring the data; David Balm. Denis an. Bill Crowda.
`George Deltas. Craig Deplten. Haj Hadeishi. Ron Hansen. Dan Beckett.
`Paul Pruner. and Mick Vaman for their helpful comments on previous
`drafts of this paper: Dr. lanes Loverde for technical advice: and Sara
`Harkavy for assistance. The views cxpreswd in this paper are solely those
`of the authors. and not necessarily those of their current or past employers.
`' Bresnahan and Reiss (I991) also loolt at industries with multiple (in
`their case. geographic) markets in each industry. Their work focuses on
`characterizing how the static equilibrium varies across markets. rather
`than intramarkct dymicr.
`
`able to researchers.2 For example. because a market begins
`when the patent on an existing drug expires. the date at
`which the market opens to competitors is known in advance
`and the potential revenue can be projected with some
`accuracy by both participants and researchers. Because
`entry occurs at observable points in time. the consequences
`of changes in the number of producers on pricing is mea-
`surable. Moreover, because entry requires Food and Drug
`Administration (FDA) approval, firms must sink significant
`costs to apply for approval prior to knowing when. or how
`many. rivals will enter the market. Hence.
`firms must
`determine if their expected postoentry rents are sufficient to
`justify the costs sunk prior to entry.
`These features enable us to impose restrictions from
`economic theory that identify the key structural relation—
`ships describing the evolution of these markets. No simul-
`taneously determined relationships are the effect of avail-
`able rents on the pattern of entry over time and the effect of
`changes in industry structure (namely. entry) on rents. The
`latter relationship can be estimated because the process of
`FDA approval takes the timing of entry decisions out of the
`hands of individual firms. so that the number of firms at any
`point in time is not determined by the current price. yet the
`price is affected by the number of competitors. Thus we can
`estimate the effect of the number of firms on current price.
`assuming that current industry structure is exogenous. Com-
`bining that with estimates of revenue. we are able to
`calculate the expected rents conditional on the number of
`competitors and the elapsed time since market opening
`We develop an iterative estimator to determine the effects
`of rents on may. A unexpected-profit condition is ex-
`ploited that equates the expected number of entrants to the
`ratio of total generic industry rents to sunk entry costs per
`firm. At
`the same time.
`the rents available to potential
`entrants will depend on the number of entrants. We estimate
`the probability of any number of competitors in each time
`period as a function of the available rents. We then use these
`estimates, together with the industry rents conditional on the
`number of firms and time. to calculate the available rents.
`Equilibrium is obtained when the rents predicted by the
`entry parameters equal the rents assumed in their estimation.
`Our structural estimates yield a number of empirical
`findings. First. consistent with previous worit. we find that
`generic drug prices fall with an increase in the number of
`competitors. Though estimating the relationship between
`market strucnrrc and prices is a necessary component of
`estimating our system of structural relationships. the esti-
`
`7 We use the terms market. generic drug. and chemical interchangeably.
`All three terms simly refer to a prescription drug whose patent has
`expired. In particular. the use of the term mire! may notcorrecpond to its
`antitrust meaning.
`
`"it Review of (immune: and Statistics. February 2003. BTU): 37-49
`0 2005 by the Presktent and Fellow: of Harvard College aid the Massachusetts institute of Technology
`
`1
`
`Exhibit 2066
`Slayback v. Sumitomo
`|PR2020—01053
`
`Exhibit 2066
`Slayback v. Sumitomo
`IPR2020-01053
`
`

`

`38
`
`THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
`
`mated effect of entry on price is also of independent interest.
`for this relationship has been an area of ongoing interest in
`the industrial organization literature.3 We calculate that
`prices for the initial generic monopolist are 20%-30% (or
`perhaps even more) above long-run marginal costs. Generic
`prices steadily decline with an increase in the number of
`producers and begin to approach long-run marginal cost
`when there are 10 or more competitors. Second. more firms
`enter, and enter more quickly,
`in markets with greater
`expected rents. Fatally. we find that the flow of generic
`industry profits increases as revenues grow, but begin falling
`after 5 to l2 months, as entry reduces price-cost margins. In
`amnion, we find that this pattern is awelerated in larger
`markets because competitors enter more quickly.
`An advantage of estimating the set of stnrctural relation-
`ships tint constitute the equilibrium is that one can trace
`through the effect of changes in market characteristics on
`the equilibrium. This can be particularly valuable in evalu-
`ating the effects of alternative policies. To illustrate the use
`of these estimates to inform policy. we simulate the effect of
`an actual change in the competitive environment
`in this
`industry.
`In response to a scandal
`involving illegitimate
`approvals. the FDA increased its scrutiny of generic drug
`applications in mid-1989. Though the policy may have
`allowed the FDA to discover. and therefore reject. more
`substandard applications, it also raised the cost of obtaining
`FDA approval for qualified applicants. Our estimates pro-
`vide a means of determining the effect of the higher entry
`costs on long—run generic prices.
`
`II. Background
`
`Before marketing a new chemical entity. a prospective
`manufacttn'er must obtain FDA approval. To obtain a new
`drug approval (NDA) from the FDA requires demonstrating
`that a drug is safe and efficacious. which is both expensive
`and time-consuming.
`It has been estimated that for the
`average drug that was obtained FDA approval in the 19905.
`its producer had spent over $335 million (in 2000 dollars)
`on development. and an additional $467 million on clinical
`and other testing.‘ In addition, the clinical trial process took
`approximately 8 years.
`Prior to 1984. producing a generic version of most exist-
`ing drugs involved a similar application process. Although
`the generic producer did not face the cost of drug discovery.
`it still bore the costs of demonstrating the safety and
`efficacy of its version. The WaxmamHatch Act in 1984
`created an abbreviated new drug approval (ANDA) proce-
`dure that reduced the regulatory burden for generic produc-
`ers by requiring only that they demonstrate bioequivalence
`to a drug that was already approved by the FDA. The ability
`
`’See Bresnahan (I989) for a discussion and analysis of this literature.
`‘ See DiMasi. Hansen. and Grabowslti (2003). This figure represents the
`expected cost ofa successful drug. in the sense that it is taijustnd for the
`probability that a drug never obtains an NBA.
`
`to avoid safety and efficacy testing considerably reduced the
`cost of obtaining FDA approval. As discussed below. we
`estimate that the cost of applying for an ANDA (including
`the cost of the requisite testing) wm approximately
`$603,000 in the early 19905 (and approximately $338,000 in
`the period immediately following passage of the Act).
`Not surprisingly.
`this expedited approval process has
`increased the number of firms producing generic versions of
`previously patented drugs. Cook (1998) reports that for 13
`major drugs with patents expiring between 1990 and 1993.
`11 had generic entry within 2-months of patent expiration.
`In contrast. she notes that in Caves. Whinston. and Hur-
`wicz's (1991) study of pre-Waxman-Hatch entry (between
`1976 and 1982). only 2 of the top 13 drugs had generic entry
`within 1 year of patent expiration.
`Entry still requires significant up-front expenditures. with
`a payoff that depends both on the FDA's decisions with
`respect
`to a firm’s application, and the timing of FDA
`approval of rivals” ANDA applications. The time it takes the
`FDA to process applications cart be both considerable and
`variable. In the vast majority of cam. the initial ANDA
`application is found deficient, requiring the applicant to
`conduct additional tests or submit additional material. 0f-
`ten, approval is granted only after the applicant has gone
`through two or three resubmissions. Hence. from the appli-
`cant's perspective. the time between initial submission and
`FDA approval is quite variable. Scott Morton (1996) calcu-
`lates that between 1984 and 1994 the time between the
`initial application and approval of ANDAs averaged ap—
`proximately 19 months. with considerable year-to-year vari-
`ation. in addition. entry requires time to obtain an approved
`source of materials and adequate production facilities. In
`total. the applicant has to anticipate 2 to 3 years elapsing
`from the time it begins preparing to enter until it can begin
`selling a generic drug.
`
`III. Modding lndtutry Dynamics
`
`No features of the entry process in this industry are
`imponant
`to understanding industry dynamics. First. an
`entrant‘s tinting of entry into the market is largely not under
`its control. Not only is the date of its approval by the FDA
`uncertain, but each applicant lacks knowledge of when, or
`how many. other ANDAs for that dnrg will be approved.
`Thus, potential entrants make their entry decisions simulta-
`neously (although actual entry will typically be sequential).
`Second. an individual entrant’s share of the aggregate ge-
`netic profits will depend greatly on when it gains approval
`relative to other generic producers. Firms gaining approval
`earlier face fewer competitors irtitially. and are able to sell
`for a longer time. There is some evidence that earlier
`entrants earn greater profits even after rivals have entered.5
`
`’ In addition to anecdotal evidmce from industry participants. Cook
`(I998) shows that sales are highly concentrated arming firms in each
`
`

`

`GENERIC DRUG INDUSTRY DYNAMICS
`
`39
`
`Together these two features create a “lottery" for prospec—
`tive producers of a generic version of a drug. If a firm
`obtains early approval. it is likely to earn a positive return
`on its application-related costs, whereas firms obtaining
`approval later in tire process are likely not to recover their
`sunk costs. Thus,
`in contrast to markes in which entry
`decisions are sequential and competition results in the last.
`or marginal entrant earning zero profit, here the number of
`firms adjusts until
`the average firm earns zero profit.6
`Specifically (assuming I: identical applicants), the expected
`profit for each firm from applying for an ANDA is
`
`A. The Effect of Generic Industry Structure on Profit:
`
`Generic pricecost margins are estimated as a function of
`observable market characteristics. including the number of
`generic competitors. We are interested in a specific aspect of
`the relationship between margins and the number of com—
`petitors, an aspect that is not explicitly examined elsewhere:
`how the marginal effect of an additional competitor on a
`drug's prices changes with the number of firms that already
`have an ANDA for that drug. To address this question. we
`estimate a regression of the form
`
`_ _L g .
`BPl
`ErpeaedProfit —- E["]
`
`n
`
`V
`
`(Emilia)‘A=Em‘A.
`
`(1)
`
`where H, is total generic industry profits at time t with i
`firms in the market. pi, is the probability that I firms are in
`the market at time t. A is the cost of applying for an ANDA,
`and B is the discount factor. V is defined as the present value
`of the stream of expected rents for all generic producers of
`a drug. The goal of the empirical analysis in this paper is to
`estimate the key parameters of equation (1). Specifically. we
`estimate the interrelationships that allow us to calculate the
`11,-, and p. as functions of exogenous. drug-specific vari-
`ables. The remainder of this section details the estimation
`
`procedure. In brief. each Huerta be thought of as the product
`of two factors: total revenue and price-cost margins. Ac-
`cordingly. we calculate the IL, by combining the results of
`regressions of each of price-cost margins and revenues
`against explanatory variables. such as time since patent
`expiration. Given these estimates. we can then determine IL,
`conditional on any given i and I. To calculate the probability
`that a given II, occurs (p..). we estimate two strucurral
`relationships: the relationship between the number of appli-
`cants for ANDAs (n) and rents in a market (V). and the
`relationship between the timing of FDA approval and rents.
`Thus. for any given levels of rents (and given set of
`exogenous variables), we can use these two relationships to
`calculate 9... Note that because total rents both determine
`and are determined by pk. these relationship must be esti-
`mated simultaneously.
`
`markat; even in markets with mom: than m firms. the top two generic
`[reducers typically sell more than 60%ofthe units. Bond and Lean (I977)
`and Banal er a]. 0993) provide severaI examples of drug: for which the
`first entrain had a substantial atlvuruge.
`‘Consequently. in contrast to the markets examined here. in a market
`with sequential entry. din-gee in the profits earned by the first entrant will
`not change subsequent firms' incentive to enter. Another important differ
`ence between generic drug markets (where entry decisions can be viewed
`as aimuhaneout) and other markets is that an exogenous change in the
`number of competitors (for example. due to a merger several years after
`patent expiration) can lead to higher prices without iruiticing entry. even if
`firms omside the market have the same entry costs as the incumbents.
`
`(2)
`
`where P", is the price in the postvpatentexpiration period
`when there are t‘ generic firms with FDA approval producing
`chemical k. and P“ is the price of the branded version of
`product It during the year prior to patent expiration.’ D,- is a
`dummy variable that equals 1 when there are i generic
`producers of chemical k and 0 otherwise. and the X” are
`variables representing demand or cost shifters for drug It.
`Using dummy variables for the number of generic pro-
`ducers imposes no specific structure on the relationship
`between price and the number of competitors. This contrasts
`with some previous work, in which a specific structure on
`the relationship is assumed (for example. an a priori func-
`tional form is imposed on the effect of more firms on
`generic prices)" Each such specification makes implicit
`assumptions about the pattern of price effects that can result
`from entry. For example.
`the implicit assumption made
`when the number of firms is used as an explanatory variable
`is that the effect of an increase by l in the number of firms
`is independent of the initial number of firms. By allowing
`the marginal effect of an additional firm to vary with the
`number of firms. we can examine questions such as the
`number of firms necessary to lead to approximately mar-
`ginal cost pricing. Allowing the marginal effect to vary is
`also important to our goal of accurately measuring the rents
`associated with any specific number of generic competitors.
`This relationship can be viewed as structural only it one
`views the number of firms at any time as exogenous. One
`standard criticism of empirical studies of the relationship
`between market structure and prices is that structure is not
`exogenous. but rather is determined by the profitability of
`
`7 We use the branded price before pacnt exp'ntion. rather than the
`contemporaneous branded price, because the Iarter is likely to be deter-
`nrined jointly with the generic price (a noted in footnote 2 l. the anpirical
`evidence on tit importance of this relationship is mixed). In “It!!!“ the
`branded price before there is any generic entry is likely to be independent
`of the number of generic producers in futtue periods
`3For example.
`in other studies of generic drug common. generic
`price is assumed to vary Enemy with j. the number of
`(Frank and
`Sanrevcr. I997); with j and [1 (Caves. Whinston. a Hurwicz. FBI): or
`mmjand thflViuinsa Mane“. 2004).mediscussedu
`greatu length in section V.
`
`

`

`40
`
`THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
`
`entering the market.9 This criticism implies that the ob-
`served cross—sectional relationship between price and the
`number of firms is an equilibrium relationship reflecting
`market-specific differences. and not a structural one reflect~
`ing the effect of more competitors on price. That is. as
`equation (1) illustrates. the number of firms applying for
`ANDAs adjusts in response to the available rents. However.
`in the generic drug industry. the nature of the FDA review
`process makes it unlikely that the number of firms at a point
`in time is affected by current price. within the time series of
`prices for any one drug. Most ANDA applications are
`submitted before the generic market even exists. and the
`number of competitors at any point in time depends on the
`FDA review process (most applications must be resubmitted
`multiple times). Hence.
`though the eventual number of
`approvals for a drug is related to the aggregate rents. the
`actual number of FDA-approved firms at any point in time
`may plausibly be considered independent of the contempo-
`raneous price. A potential endogeneity issue arises when
`aggregating across drugs bemuse there are unobserved
`difi‘erences between drugs that might affect both prices and
`the number of entrants. We control for these between-drug
`effects by estimating a random—effects model. This model
`allows there to be differences across drugs in the average
`relationship between generic prices and pre-patent—expiration
`branded prices (see Greene. 2003).lo Finally. we tested this
`potential cndogeneity using a Hausman test and cannot reject
`the null hypothes's that market structure is exogenous in the
`pricing equation (l-lausrnan, 1978).“
`In principle. N in equation (2) could be the maximum
`number of entrants observed in the data. In practice. we take
`N to be the minimum number of entrants such that the price
`effect of further entry is negligible. The interpretation of a.)
`is the ratio of the generic price when there are more than N
`generic producers to the branded price that prevailed before
`patent expiration. if all other independent variables were
`equal to 0. The other 01,-, such as as, are the increments in the
`ratio over 010 when there are r‘ producers. Because no reflecrs
`the ratio below which additional ”entry does not lead to
`lower prime, we view ((10 + 23x”) P“ as the long-run
`marginal production cost of drug k (where X” is the mean
`value of )9 for drug 1:). Under this assumption. afluo +
`a, + 27, x”) is a measure of the price-cost margin with i
`generic producers.
`The other relationship required for calculating V condi-
`tional on the Dr, is the relationship between generic revenue
`
`“This criticism dates back a least to Demsetz (I973). For more formal
`analysis. see Blesaahan (I989).
`'° Other- studies have allowed for drug-specific effects by including
`market-specific dummy variables. Either assumption allows calculation of
`the avenge ell'ect of increasing the number of competitors in a market.
`“ Following Frank and Salkever(l997) and Caves et al. (199]). we use
`time s'mce patent expiration and pie-patent branded revenues as instru-
`meras for the number of genetic firms. Because Ive do not leave enough
`instruments to atimale equation (2). our endogeneity tests employ several
`common ftmctioaal forms of the number of competitors.
`
`and market-specific variables. Our estimation of this rela-
`tionship is of the form
`
`J
`
`In (a, 9..) = to + n In (Pat 9..) + 2 1.x...
`1-2
`
`(3)
`
`where Pk. Q” is total monthly generic industry revenue at
`time t in market It. PM (2.. is the branded film’s average
`monthly revenue during the year prior to patent expiration.
`and the XE,- are other variables that might affect generic
`revenue. The XV will include many of the same variables as
`equation (2).
`
`B. The Efl'ccr of Industry Pmfitabiliry an Entry
`
`The model we use to examine entry decisions traits each
`of M timts as homogeneous in regard to their ability to enter
`and produce a generic dmg. We assume that generic rents
`are not sufficient to allow all M potential entrants to prof-
`itably enter any market. but that they are sufficient to allow
`one firm to earn profits in any market. We also make the
`natural assumption that each firm’s profits from producing a
`drug are decreasing in the number of rival producers of the
`dmg. We conceptualize the entry decision as each firm
`choosing independently and simultaneously whether to en-
`ter each market. This reflects the reality that each generic
`producer must
`independently decide whether to enter a
`market. at a point usually 2 to 3 years prior to patent
`expiration. The symmetric (mixed strategy) Nash equilib-
`rium in this case will consist of each firm i choosing to enter
`market It with some probability p“, where that M may
`depend on the expected rents in the market.'2 The symmet-
`ric Nash equilibrium in each market consists of a pk that is
`common to each firm. and that has the property that each
`firm optimally chooses it. given that all of its rivals have
`chosen that same [L‘- The p.) in the Nash equilibrium yields
`zero expected profits.
`the logic being that
`if an entry
`probability generates sufficiently few expected entrants so
`that each entrant expects to earn positive profits. then any
`firm would be better off unilaterally changing its strategy to
`entering with probability l (and entering with probability 0
`if expected profits are negative). Comparing across drugs,
`the equilibrium in will be increasing in the expected rents
`associated with that dnig. so that we expect to see more
`entrants for higher-V. drugs
`One feature of this stylized game is that, because each
`firm‘s decision whether to enter is independent of all other
`firms‘ decisions. the equilibrium distribution of the number
`of entrants will follow a binomial distribution. We use the
`Poisson distribution as an approximation of the binomial to
`
`'1 An alternative equilibrium concept is employed by Berry (I992). who
`assumes that fimts' uttry costs differ. Given variation in entry costs. a
`pure-strategy equilibrium can emerge. in which only low-entry-cost firms
`Clllfl.
`
`

`

`GENERIC DRUG INDUSTRY DYNAMICS
`
`41
`
`This function is defined in terms of the hazard proportion-
`ality parameter as Sh = expo-M t). Then. using equation
`(4) and the binomial formula, we calculate the probability
`that i fimts have ANDAs in market It in period t as
`
`p... = Slim) 62%“ — su)‘ .r'.
`
`(7)
`
`C. The Endogeneity Qfltentr and Identification
`
`Equations (2). (3). and (7) together make up the compo—
`nents of equation (I) and thus allow for the calculation of
`industry rents.
`
`derive the density function of the number of entrants in
`market It as
`
`fin.) = exp( - u.) ui‘lnt! .
`
`(4)
`
`where u, is the equilibrium entry probability. The zero-
`expected-profits condition implies that Eh.“ == E[VI. Be-
`cause Eln.) = MN with the Poisson distribution, this yields
`Elm/Mm. = A; that is. applications costs are equal
`to
`expected rents divided by the expected number of entrants.
`This implies that holding M and A constant. there should be
`a direct relationship between V). and us. There is reeson to
`believe. however. that application costs increased substan-
`tially in I989. when it was discovered that some ANDAs
`had been fraudulently obtained. and that the FDA reacted by
`increasing its scrutiny of applications (Scott Morton. 1996).
`We attempt to capture this in a dummy variable. Sm'ngem.
`that equals l for the period after mid-1989 and Oodterwise.
`Consequently. we estimate the relationship between it; and
`the cost and benefit of applying as
`
`P4 = Vt €XP(¢: + 4’2 Sifi"gemk)
`
`(5)
`
`from a cross section of 3l drugs. This relationship charac-
`terizes how the number of entrants adjusts to changes in the
`costs and benefits of FDA approval. it also provides us with
`a means of estimating the time series of entry within each
`market. because the expected number of producers at each
`point in time depends on the total number of applications. as
`detailed below.
`For any given number of applicants. the pattern of entry
`will depend on the FDA review process. Our second entry
`equation characterizes the timing of entry. conditional on
`the total number of entrants. To reflect the stochastic nature
`(from the applicants' perspective) of the FDA review pro-
`cess, we model the rate of entry as a proportional hazard
`function in which the proportionality parameter is possibly
`affected by rents available and FDA regime. Specifically. we
`posit a probability x of any firm that has not yet been
`approved obtaining an ANDA during month t. We estimate
`the following relationship for M:
`
`In A, = 6. + 62V, + 83 Sm‘ngenn.
`
`(6)
`
`We postulate that )t. may be increasing in Vb because
`firms apply earlier in high-Vt markets and/or have a greater
`incentive to file accurately. Because the value of X may also
`depend on the regulatory environment. equation (6) in-
`cludes Stringenr. our postscandal dummy variable. These
`parameters are estimated from data on the time to entry for
`all entrants in each of 31 generic drugs.
`Combining equations (4) and (6) allows us to calculate
`the time path of expected entry. as a function of rents and
`the FDA regime. Specifically. we use the estimate of M from
`equation (6) to determine the survivorship function, where
`surviving means the applicant has not yet been approved.
`
`VA 3‘ 2 B' ( 2 Danna:
`
`- 2 B’ (2 p... ; p. 9.).
`
`"I
`
`‘
`
`all
`
`n
`
`Pi I —
`In
`
`(1')
`
`However. equation (7). goveming the entry process. also
`depends on the magnitude of the expected available rents
`through equations (5) and (6). Larger expected rents V
`generate larger probabilities of entry. u. shifting the prob-
`abilities p toward more firms at any point in time. which by
`equation (I ’) tends to reduce expected rents V. Because V is
`endogenous. via equation (1'). we develop an iterative
`process to estimate the parameters of equations (5) and (6).
`The mixed—strategy simultaneous-move Nash equilibrium
`suggested above will represent a stable fixed point in the
`mapping of V onto V under certain conditions. Specifically.
`the system of equations consisting of equations (1 ’). (5) and
`(6), along with subsidiary relationships embodied in those
`equations [for example. equation (2) within equation (1')].
`will have a fixed point (W, h“. pf) if equations (2) and (3)
`indicate that per-finn profits are decreasing in the number of
`firms. and equations (5) and (6) indicate that )t and p. are
`such that the expected number of firms at every point in
`time is increasing in V. To see why (V*. A“, pt“) represents
`a fixed point, consider an alternative V. Va > V“. Because
`V' > V", the x and p. based on V” will lead to more firms
`at each point in time if the second stability condition
`holds. Consequently. if the first stability condition holds,
`the V resulting from this it and y. will be less than V‘.
`Hence. V‘s above V" map to lower V‘s. and V5 below V“
`map to higher Vs.
`The actual calculation of the fixed point follows this same
`logic. la the first iteration. we calculate V. using equation
`(1') based on arbitrary values of h and it. along with the
`parameters estimated in equations (2) and (3). We then
`estimate the h and ‘L. using equations (5) and (6) with VI on
`the right-hand side. These are used to calculate fin), the
`density of at, and the pit, according to equations (4) and (7).
`
`

`

`42
`
`THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
`
`We combine the n, and pin from this iteration with the arm
`calculated from equations (2) and (3) to calculate V2. We
`then compare V2 with V. and if the two values are suffi-
`ciently close. we view the process as convergent; that is.
`these values of )t. p, and V are the equilibrium. If the
`predicwd Vis sufficiently different from the initial value. we
`repeat
`the process. using V; as the right-side value in
`reestimating equations (5) and (6). and then calculating V3
`based on the new A and p. and the unchanged pm. In this
`way. we iterate through a series of V; until we obtain
`convergence.
`
`IV. Data
`
`Our primary source for price and quantity data is Generic
`Spectra" from [MS Inc., a proprietary vendor of informa-
`tion to the pharmaceutical industry. The [MS data provide
`information on 31 drugs that went off patent in the late
`1980s and early l9908. and subsequently faced competition
`from generic producers (see table 4). It includes information
`on monthly price and quantity for the patent holder and
`generic entrants for 3 years subsequent to patent expiration
`and 3 years prior to patent expiration (for the patent holder).
`These data include prices derived from two distinct sources:
`product shipments and price surveys. For both sources the
`data are provided separately for each strength (for example.
`50 mg) and form (for example. oral solid) of the drug.
`The shipment-based data on revenues and quantities are
`derived primarily from shipments by distributors (who pur-
`chase from manufacturers) to pharmacies and other dispens-
`ers. A small proportion, perhaps 5%. of sales are made
`directly by manufacturers. The sales by distributors are
`captured by 1M5 directly monitoring the shipments of a
`high percentage of distributors (98% of all such shipments
`are contained in their sample). This is combined with
`estimates of direct sales of manufacturers. which are esti-
`mated from a sample of invoices. Our measure of price per
`kilogram is the average revenue for a particular strength and
`form derived by dividing total generic revenue by the
`number of kilograms of genetic product. We calculate this
`price sepmately for all genetic sales. and for sales by the
`first generic entrant"
`The second set of prices in Generic Spectra is obtained
`from a sample of pharmacies. It includes data on average
`transaction prices paid by pharmacies. Awording to [M5,
`the measured acquisition price would reflect all relevant
`discounts, with the exception of year-end quantity discounts
`provided by some manufacturers. We calculate acquisition
`prices for both the

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket