throbber
Are Physicians "Easy Marks"? Quantifying the Effects of Detailing and Sampling on New
`Prescriptions
`Author(s): Natalie Mizik and Robert Jacobson
`Source: Management Science, Vol. 50, No. 12 (Dec., 2004), pp. 1704-1715
`Published by: INFORMS
`Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/30048061
`Accessed: 30-04-2019 22:35 UTC
`
`JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
`range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
`facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
`
`Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
`https://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`INFORMS is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Management
`Science
`
`This content downloaded from 208.85.77.1 on Tue, 30 Apr 2019 22:35:27 UTC
`All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`Opiant Exhibit 2171
`Nalox-1 Pharmaceuticals, LLC v. Opiant Pharmaceuticals, Inc.
`IPR2019-00694
`Page 1
`
`

`

` MANAGEMENT SCIENCE
` Vol. 50, No. 12, December 2004, pp. 1704-1715
` ISSN 0025-1909 1 EISSN 1526-5501 104150121 1704
`
` infimeR
` DOI 10.1287/mnsc.1040.0281
` f 2004 INFORMS
`
` Are Physicians "Easy Marks"? Quantifying the
` Effects of Detailing and Sampling on
` New Prescriptions
`
` Natalie Mizik
` Graduate School of Business, Columbia University, 3022 Broadway, New York, New York 10027-6902, nm2079@columbia.edu
` Robert Jacobson
` Department of Marketing, School of Business, University of Washington, Seattle, Washington 98195-3200,
` yusho@u.washington.edu
`
` Much public attention and considerable controversy surround pharmaceutical marketing practices and their
` impact on physicians. However, views on the matter have largely been shaped by anecdotal evidence or
` results from analyses with insufficient controls. Making use of a dynamic fixed-effects distributed lag regres-
` sion model, we empirically assess the role that two central components of pharmaceutical marketing practices
` (namely, detailing and sampling) have on physician prescribing behavior. Key differentiating features of our
` model include its ability to (i) capture persistence in the prescribing process and decompose it into own-growth
` and competitive-stealing effects, (ii) estimate an unrestricted decay structure of the promotional effects over
` time, and (iii) control for physician-specific effects that, if not taken into account, induce biased coefficient esti-
` mates of detailing and sampling effects. Based on pooled time series cross-sectional data involving three drugs,
` 24 monthly observations, and 74,075 individual physicians (more than 2 million observations in total), we find
` that detailing and free drug samples have positive and statistically significant effects on the number of new
` prescriptions issued by a physician. However, we find that the magnitudes of the effects are modest.
`
` Key words: pharmaceutical marketing; salesforce effectiveness
` History: Accepted by Linda Green, public sector applications; received March 8, 2004. This paper was with the
` authors 1 month for 1 revision.
`
` Introduction
` industry's promotional tactics lead to an increase in
` appropriate versus inappropriate use of drugs in a
` As the cost of prescription drugs continues to escalate,
` cost-effective manner.
` increased public attention is being focused on the
` Concern that pharmaceutical marketing practices
` marketing practices of the pharmaceutical firms as
` have exacerbated increases in public health costs has
` one source of the problem. Direct-to-physician activ-
` prompted government actions at the federal and state
` ities account for the bulk of U.S. pharmaceutical
` levels. For example, in 2002 the federal government
` firm promotional spending. IMS Health (2003) esti-
` issued a warning to the drug industry to curtail some
` mates that over $5.8 billion was spent in 2002 on
` of their marketing practices (Washington Post 2002).
` detailing, i.e., pharmaceutical sales representatives
` H.R. 2356, which calls for ongoing annual funding of
` (PSRs) visiting physicians to promote their firm's
` $75 million to conduct comparative cost-effectiveness
` drugs. In addition, the retail value of the free drug
` drug studies, was introduced in Congress in June
` samples distributed during these visits is estimated
` at $11.5 billion.
` 2003. A primary intent of this legislation is to pro-
` vide objective scientific evidence to "reduce doctors'
` A detailing visit typically lasts two to five minutes
` reliance on marketing information from the pharma-
` during which time a PSR discusses one to three of
` ceutical industry" (Pear 2003). Given the fact that one
` the company's drugs. Information (and, at times, mis-
` of every five dollars spent on pharmaceutical drugs in
` information) about a drug's composition, therapeutic
` value, proper dosage, and potential side effects is
` the United States is paid for by a state program, state
` governments have also taken steps to counter PSR
` communicated (Zigler et al. 1995). Often, PSRs will
` influence. Most notably, several states have under-
` also dispense samples and possibly offer small gifts
` taken counterdetailing initiatives (Gold 2001). State
` to the physician. At issue is whether these interac-
` employees visit physicians in hopes of persuading
` tions with PSRs compromise physician integrity and
` them to switch from prescribing branded drugs to
` affect their prescribing behavior. More precisely, the
` key public policy issue is the extent to which the
` prescribing lower-cost generic drugs.
`
` 1704
`
`This content downloaded from 208.85.77.1 on Tue, 30 Apr 2019 22:35:27 UTC
`All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`Opiant Exhibit 2171
`Nalox-1 Pharmaceuticals, LLC v. Opiant Pharmaceuticals, Inc.
`IPR2019-00694
`Page 2
`
`

`

` Mizik and Jacobson: Quantifying the Effects of Detailing and Sampling on New Prescriptions
` Management Science 50(12), pp. 1704-1715, v 2004 INFORMS 1705
`
` bias if left uncontrolled, we assess the effect of detail-
` Prescription drug expenditures are projected to
` remain the fastest-growing sector of health care
` ing and sampling on physician prescribing behavior.
` The large number of observations in the database (it
` expenditures. They are expected to account for 14.5%
` involves a total of more than 2 million observations)
` of $3.1 trillion health care expenditures by 2012
` (compared with approximately 10% in 2001). With
` allows us to accurately pinpoint the impact that inter-
` actions with PSRs have on the number of new pre-
` recent legislation providing a Medicare drug benefit
` scriptions issued by physicians.
` expected to cost the federal government $534 billion
` We find that, although detailing and free drug sam-
` over the next decade, it is no wonder that the impact
` ples have a positive and statistically significant asso-
` of pharmaceutical industry marketing practices is of
` ciation with the number of new prescriptions issued
` keen interest to policymakers, the business commu-
` by a physician, the magnitudes of the effects are mod-
` nity, and the general public.
` est. As such, our results challenge the two domi-
` Two competing views have dominated discussion
` nant views and support the contention that, rather
` on the matter. The prevailing view contends that
` than being easy marks, physicians are tough sells.
` PSRs significantly influence physicians' prescribing
` This realization is important because the public policy
` behavior and that this influence has negative effect
` debate continues over how best to address the high
` on patients' welfare, in that PSRs encourage physi-
` cost of prescription drugs.
` cians to prescribe more expensive branded drugs.
` Many public policy organizations and consumer
` advocacy groups adhere to this view (see, for exam-
` PSR Influence on Physicians
` ple, www.nofreelunch.org). The prominent alternative
` Most discussions of PSRs have focused on the factors
` view argues that PSRs do influence physicians' pre-
` facilitating their influence. Unquestionably, PSRs pro-
` scribing behavior, but that this influence is positive
` vide physicians with information about new drugs,
` in that PSRs provide physicians with valuable infor-
` new indications, dosages, and interactions for existing
` mation. As a result, physicians are better informed
` medicines. Azoulay (2002) finds evidence that detail-
` and make better choices for their patients. Pharma-
` ing diffuses product information. Avorn et al. (1982)
` ceutical companies and industry groups advocate this
` report that 20% of surveyed physicians view informa-
` second view.
` tion provided by PSRs as "very important" in influ-
` Despite the substantial resources that pharmaceu-
` encing their prescribing behavior. Furthermore, PSRs
` tical companies invest in promoting their products
` are trained in persuading physicians. Detailing takes
` and the controversy associated with pharmaceutical
` the form of presenting facts and, as has been doc-
` marketing practices, surprisingly little is known about
` umented (Zigler et al. 1995), misrepresenting facts
` the magnitude of the impact that PSR visits and free
` about the drug in an effective manner. Finally, mere
` drug samples have on physician prescribing behavior.
` exposure or salience effects might lead to a temporary
` Narayanan et al. (2003) report a pharmaceutical exec-
` increase in prescribing following a PSR visit. Numer-
` utive as stating, "No one is really sure if sending the
` ous studies have reported high physician responsive-
` legions of reps to doctors' offices really works. Every-
` ness to PSR activity attributed it to PSR persuasive-
` one is afraid to stop it, because they don't know what
` ness (Avorn et al. 1982, Powers 1998).
` difference it's making" (p. 4).
` Less attention has been paid to the factors limiting
` In point of fact, much of the evidence on PSR
` PSR effectiveness. The key consideration here is that
` effectiveness is anecdotal. The empirical studies
` PSRs are not the only or even the primary source
` investigating the issue have been subject to data or
` of information about drugs for physicians. Scientific
` methodological limitations that restricted their ability
` papers, advice from colleagues, and a physician's own
` to control for potential biases and have come to
` training and experience also influence prescribing
` contradictory conclusions regarding even the central
` practices. Indeed, most physicians view these other
` issues: the effects of detailing on prescriptions (e.g.,
` influences as far more important than that of PSRs
` Parsons and Abeele 1981 versus Gonul et al. 2001),
` (Peay and Peay 1990).
` of detailing on price elasticity (e.g., Rizzo 1999 versus
` PSR influence is limited by the fact that many
` Gonul et al. 2001), and even of price on sales (e.g.,
` physicians have skeptical or negative attitudes toward
` Rizzo 1999 versus Gonul et al. 2001).
` PSRs (Lichstein et al. 1992, McKinley et al. 1990).
` We have obtained access to a unique database
` Attribution theory suggests that with low source
` that allows us to undertake econometric analysis
` credibility, which is determined by factors such as
` that overcomes a number of fundamental limitations
` a source's trustworthiness and expertise (Dholakia
` existing in past research. In particular, making use
` and Sternthal 1977), arguments in a message will
` of a dynamic fixed-effects distributed lag model that
` be discounted (Eagley and Chaiken 1975). Physicians
` accounts for physician-specific effects likely to induce
` recognize that PSRs are neither experts nor com-
`
`This content downloaded from 208.85.77.1 on Tue, 30 Apr 2019 22:35:27 UTC
`All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`Opiant Exhibit 2171
`Nalox-1 Pharmaceuticals, LLC v. Opiant Pharmaceuticals, Inc.
`IPR2019-00694
`Page 3
`
`

`

` Mizik and Jacobson: Quantifying the Effects of Detailing and Sampling on New Prescriptions
` 1706 Management Science 50(12), pp. 1704-1715, r2004 INFORMS
`
` estimated main effect of detailing was negative. The
` pletely trustworthy. They realize that information pre-
` most dominant explanatory factor in the model is
` sented is biased toward the promoted drug and is
` sales lagged one period, which would reflect per-
` unlikely to be objective or even accurate (Connelly
` et al. 1990). Thus, physicians will discount informa-
` sistence in behaviors and carryover effects magnify-
` tion received from a PSR.
` ing the influence of detailing. Alternatively, lagged
` Some additional characteristics of physicians would
` sales could be reflective of territory-specific effects
` that are not modeled and, as such, could lead to
` seem to make them particularly tough sells. Friestad
` and Wright's (1994) persuasion knowledge model
` biased estimates. Wotruba (1982), for example, raises
` suggests that targets of persuasion use their knowl-
` this possibility of territory-specific effects to question
` edge about the persuasion agent and can effectively
` the reported effects of detailing.
` Rizzo (1999) uses annual data for the period 1988-
` cope with and even achieve their own goals during a
` persuasion attempt, e.g., obtaining free drug samples
` 1993 and for 46 drugs to estimate a brand-level model
` linking prescriptions for a drug for a given year
` that can be later distributed to patients. Campbell and
` Kirmani's (2000) tests of the persuasion knowledge
` to pharmaceutical company marketing activities. He
` model reveal that busy targets with accessible agent
` finds that price is negatively related to sales and that
` motivation (a profile that would fit most physicians)
` detailing is anticompetitive in that it decreases price
` sensitivity. Detailing is also found to have a direct
` are particularly effective in resisting persuasion.
` When cast within the workings of other sources
` positive effect on sales. Surprisingly, no consideration
` of influence, we would expect the ability of PSRs to
` is given to the dynamic properties of sales. The classic
` influence physician behavior to be relatively small. As
` spurious regression characteristics, i.e., very high R2
` such, we hypothesize a relatively small effect of PSR
` in the presence of substantial unmodeled autocorre-
` activity on physician prescribing behavior.
` lation, appear to be present. As such, questions exist
` about the validity of both the point estimates and
` standard errors reported in the analysis.
` Previous Empirical Research
` Gonul et al. (2001) use data involving 1,785 patient
` The various studies assessing the effect of PSR activ-
` visits to estimate a multinomial logit model assess-
` ity on physician prescribing behavior have generated
` ing factors influencing physician prescribing behav-
` conflicting results. Indeed, on some of the most cen-
` ior. Exactly opposite to the findings of Rizzo (1999),
` tral issues-ranging from the effects of detailing on
` they report that price has a positive effect on prescrip-
` prescriptions, of detailing on price elasticity, and even
` tion probabilities and that detailing increases price
` of price on sales-studies have come to diametrically
` sensitivity. They find positive effects of detailing and
` opposite conclusions. Data and methodological limi-
` sampling, but do not discuss the implications of their
` tations, however, raise concerns about the inferences
` magnitudes. These magnitudes, calculated based on
` drawn from these analyses.
` descriptive statistics, imply elasticities that are sur-
` A few quasi-experimental studies of the issue orig-
` prisingly large.' The elasticity estimates for the seven
` inate in the medical community. These studies com-
` drugs studied, evaluated at the mean level of detail-
` pare physicians who did not see PSRs or were visited
` ing and sampling, average 41% for detailing and 48%
` less frequently by PSRs to physicians who saw PSRs
` for sampling. Particularly for samples, which have a
` or were visited more frequently by PSRs (Chren and
` negligible marginal cost, their estimated coefficients
` Landefeld 1994, Powers 1998). The limitation of these
` imply enormous returns to enhanced PSR activity. In
` studies is that they are not randomized: PSRs do
` point of fact, these substantial effects could arise, not
` not determine which physicians to visit on a random
` from the influence of PSR activity, but rather as an
` basis. Rather, PSRs tend to see physicians who are
` outgrowth of a joint correlation with an omitted factor
` more likely to utilize the drug or who prescribe in
` from the model, e.g., larger practices prescribe more
` higher volume. This consideration invalidates these
` and receive more free samples.
` attempts to assess the effect of PSRs independent of
` A concern, which Gonul et al. (2001) explicitly
` controls accounting for motivation influencing PSR
` acknowledge, is over the role of physician-specific
` behavior.
` effects that can induce a bias in the estimated coeffi-
` The ability to potentially control for other influ-
` cients. They state (p. 84),
` ences is an advantage of regression-based analysis.
` Past research has made use of different regression
` techniques to assess PSR influence. Unfortunately,
` it has been inadequate in controlling for physician-
` specific effects. Parsons and Abeele (1981) use data
` for 24 months and 14 territories to model the number
` 1 The elasticity of prescription probability Pj to covariate Xjk in a
` of prescriptions sold in a given territory for a given
` conditional logit model is calculated as (dPj/Pj)/(aXjk/Xjk) = f3k * Xjk *
` (1- P).
` month as a function of sales calls. Interestingly, the
`
` prescription behavior patterns might be strongly influ-
` enced by factors other than the explanatory vari-
` ables we include in our model. Examples are physi-
`
`This content downloaded from 208.85.77.1 on Tue, 30 Apr 2019 22:35:27 UTC
`All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`Opiant Exhibit 2171
`Nalox-1 Pharmaceuticals, LLC v. Opiant Pharmaceuticals, Inc.
`IPR2019-00694
`Page 4
`
`

`

` Mizik and Jacobson: Quantifying the Effects of Detailing and Sampling on New Prescriptions
` Management Science 50(12), pp. 1704-1715, l2004 INFORMS 1707
`
` to 11 years; annual sales range from under $0.5 billion
` cians' unobservable personal characteristics.... Ignor-
` ing these factors might bias the coefficients of the
` to more than $1 billion; they come from different ther-
` included explanatory variables.
` apeutic areas. Although the effect of detailing can
` vary across drugs, analysis of these three drugs offers
` The extent to which their estimates are biased by
` some generalizable insights, not only because they
` the failure to control for unobservable factors remains
` provide a cross-section of drugs in the marketplace,
` unanswered, but this is one consideration that might
` but because they represent more than 4 million PSR
` account for the large estimated effects.
` interactions with physicians.
`
` 6 6
`
` Empirical Analysis
` Model
` A key benefit of utilizing pooled time series cross-
` We employ the following dynamic fixed-effects dis-
` sectional (panel) data is the ability to test for and
` tributed lag regression model to assess the effect of
` control the effect of unobserved fixed factors. These
` detailing and sampling on new prescriptions:
` unobserved factors, if left uncontrolled, can induce
` Prescribeit
` bias in the coefficient estimates of the explanatory fac-
` tors included in the model. Past research has either
` =- a + E j * Detailsit-j + E yj * Samplesit-j
` not used panel data or not made full use of the ben-
` j=0 j=0
` efits of panel data analysis. We make use of pooled
` 6 6
` time series cross-section observations (24 months of
` + E Aj * Competitort- + E * Prescribeit-
` observations across 74,075 physicians) and panel data
` =O i=1
` statistical methods (i.e., a dynamic fixed-effects dis-
` T 11
` tributed lag regression model) to assess the effect
` + , * Time(r) + i, Ks Specialty(s) * Trendt
` of detailing and sampling on physician prescribing
` +=1 s=1
` behavior.
` + Eit' (1)
` Data
` where Prescribeit, Detailsit, Samplesit, and Competitorit
` are, respectively, the number of new prescriptions
` Access to the data was gained from a U.S. pharmaceu-
` issued, the number of PSR visits, the number of free
` tical manufacturer with the only condition of ensur-
` ing the anonymity of the firm and the drugs in the
` drug samples received, and the number of new pre-
` study. Two different sets of data were merged to form
` scriptions issued for competitive drugs by physician i
` the database. One data set pertains to the number
` at time period t. Time(7) is an indicator function that
` of new prescriptions for the studied drugs and their
` takes on the value 0 prior to the time period r and 1
` competitors issued by physicians during a month.
` from the time period r on, Specialty(s) is an indi-
` cator function that takes on the value 1 when the
` The new prescription measure reflects both new and
` repeat usage, but does not reflect refills accompany-
` specialty area of the physician is s, 0 otherwise (i.e.,
` ing the prescriptions. These data cover a 24-month
` separate dummy variables for each of the 11 spe-
` cialty areas), and Trend is the observation number
` period for three widely prescribed drugs. The second
` data set pertains to detailing and sampling activity
` for a given month and year. Because it includes both
` by PSRs for the same three drugs. The two data sets
` current-term and lagged variables in the model, Equa-
` were merged into one database containing prescrib-
` tion (1) allows for a wide range of possible effects and
` ing and promotional activity information by month
` influences, e.g., serial correlation (current-effects) and
` and physician.
` state-dependent (persisting) dynamic relationships.
` To reduce the possible influence of extreme val-
` A key characteristic of Equation (1) is that it allows
` ues (outliers) that would arise from, for example,
` for a physician-specific effect, i.e., the intercept ai
` data entry errors and the common practice of one
` is allowed to vary by physician. This consideration
` physician signing for all samples that later get dis-
` acknowledges that physician behavior patterns are
` influenced by unobserved or unobservable factors,
` tributed to a group of physicians attending a confer-
` ence, we excluded the top 0.5% of observations for the
` e.g., physician characteristics. To the extent that these
` number of details, samples, and new prescriptions.
` unobserved factors are correlated with detailing and
` We later undertook sensitivity analysis on alternative
` sampling, analysis not controlling for their effects will
` definitions of outliers (e.g., 0%, 1%, 5%) and found
` result in biased estimated effects for the marketing
` results in close correspondence across these alterna-
` phenomena. Although a Hausman (1978) specification
` tive samples.
` test can empirically assess the role played by fixed
` Table 1 presents basic background information and
` effects, we have a priori reason to believe that these
` unobserved factors will in fact be correlated with mar-
` descriptive statistics for the drugs included in our
` study. The drugs differ on a variety of dimensions:
` keting activity. For instance, larger practices will gen-
` erate more prescriptions and will also attract more
` They have been on the market from less than 1 year
`
`This content downloaded from 208.85.77.1 on Tue, 30 Apr 2019 22:35:27 UTC
`All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`Opiant Exhibit 2171
`Nalox-1 Pharmaceuticals, LLC v. Opiant Pharmaceuticals, Inc.
`IPR2019-00694
`Page 5
`
`

`

` Mizik and Jacobson: Quantifying the Effects of Detailing and Sampling on New Prescriptions
` 1708 Management Science 50(12), pp. 1704-1715, w2004 INFORMS
`
` Table 1 Drug Profiles
`
` Drug A Drug B Drug C
`
` Sales range (US$) 0.5 to 1 billion over 1 billion under 0.5 billion
` Time on the market at the 3 years 11 years 6 months
` beginning of the study period
` Estimated number of competitors 12 18 11
` in the respective therapeutic area
` Mean number of details per 1.73 1.98 1.73
` physician per month (1.75) (1.70) (1.44)
` Mean number of free drug samples 4.34 7.79 4.02
` per physician per month (9.76) (13.71) (7.73)
` Mean number of monthly new 13.18 8.82 2.27
` prescriptions per physician (14.81) (10.43) (3.58)
` Average number of refills following 2-3 2-3 2-3
` one new prescription
`
` Recommended duration of therapy 3 months, and as maintenance with 3 months and up to 9 months Not yet established
` periodic patient reexamination
` Cost of therapy relative to other Average Above average Average
` drugs in the therapeutic area
` Mean number of monthly new 42.91 48.80 22.46
` prescriptions per physician in (43.63) (53.73) (19.03)
` the respective therapeutic area
` Therapeutic area is Relatively new Well established Well established
` Specialty area of top prescribers Psychiatry Primary carett Primary careft
` Number of physicians 10,516 55,896 30,005
` Number of data points 252,384 1,341,504 720,120
`
` Note. Standard errors are in parentheses. The sum of the number of physicians in each of the three data sets is greater than the total
` number of physicians in the study (74,075) because some physicians are in the upper 60 prescribing percentile for more than one of
` the drugs in our study.
` ttThe primary care specialty area includes family practice, general practice, internal medicine, and osteopathy.
`
` involve both a direct effect on prescriptions and an
` detailing. As such, a spurious positive correlation, i.e.,
` unrelated to any potential effects of detailing, will
` indirect effect that arises through persistence in physi-
` exist between detailing and prescriptions due to a
` cian behavior. The total effect of detailing and sam-
` pling can be calculated as
` joint correlation with practice size.
` Because the effects of PSR activity are unlikely to
` 6 6 6 6
` be limited to the month when the visit occurred, we
` /Pj/ 1-Bb-[ j and y/ 1-yyj ,
` allow for current and lagged effects for both detailing
` j=O j=l j=0 j=1
` and sampling. The number of observations available
` respectively.
` in our data sample allows us to directly estimate sep-
` We include both lagged own prescriptions and
` arate effects for lagged terms. As such, we do not
` lagged competitors' prescriptions, thus the model
` need to impose a specific decay pattern as a neces-
` separates lagged total demand dynamics into two
` sity for preserving degrees of freedom. We do, how-
` key components: competitive substitution and own
` ever, need to specify the length of time that a PSR
` demand growth. Lagged own prescriptions will have
` visit might influence physician behavior. We select a
` a positive effect on prescriptions. Lagged competitors'
` six-months lag length under the view that the effect
` prescriptions will have a negative impact on prescrip-
` of a visit will dissipate substantially over this period,
` tions because they capture the substitution effects
` but we also test for longer-term lagged effects. Still,
` that physicians make between competing drugs. The
` we expect the effects of detailing to be largest in the
` current competitive prescriptions, however, will cap-
` months directly following the visit. The cumulative
` ture two different phenomena. They will reflect not
` direct effect of detailing and sampling can be obtained
` only substitution effects, but also changes in total
` demand due to market expansion or contraction. In
` simply by summing the coefficients, i.e., E61=0j and
` this regard, current-term competitive effects will act
` as a proxy for two different phenomena with oppo-
` Lagged values for new prescriptions (Prescribeit_)
` capture autocorrelation in the series that arises
` site effects, i.e., negative substitution effects and posi-
` tive market demand effects. As such, the current-term
` through inertia and persistence in physician behavior.
` These autoregressive effects play a key role in that
` coefficient (AO) will depend on the relative magnitude
` they magnify the effects of detailing and sampling.
` of the two conflicting effects and, therefore, the sign
` That is, the total effects of detailing and sampling
` of the effect cannot be postulated a priori.
`
`This content downloaded from 208.85.77.1 on Tue, 30 Apr 2019 22:35:27 UTC
`All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`Opiant Exhibit 2171
`Nalox-1 Pharmaceuticals, LLC v. Opiant Pharmaceuticals, Inc.
`IPR2019-00694
`Page 6
`
`

`

` Mizik and Jacobson: Quantifying the Effects of Detailing and Sampling on New Prescriptions
` Management Science 50(12), pp. 1704-1715, @2004 INFORMS 1709
`
` The other variables in Equation (1) are time-period-
` data for antiulcer drugs.2 We found that, after making
` specific indicators and specialty-specific trends. The
` use of competitive sales as a proxy variable, monthly
` time-period-specific indicators (the coefficients 8,)
` changes in brand detailing exhibited little correlation
` allow for the fact that the number of prescriptions
` (0.01) with monthly changes in competitor detailing.
` Given the absence of correlation at the brand level, the
` can shift across time periods. These intercepts capture
` not only seasonal effects but all brandwide influences
` correlation at the physician level can also be expected
` to be similarly small and, indeed, even smaller. As
` that shift prescribing behavior across all physicians
` (e.g., price changes, changes in the set of alternative
` such, the magnitude of this bias in the estimated effect
` medications available, changes in advertising cam-
` of detailing caused by the exclusion of competitive
` paigns, etc.). That is, the inclusion of the time-specific
` detailing from the analysis can be expected to be min-
` indicator variables will capture all effects common
` imal, or even completely absent.
` across physicians, which would include the diffu-
` We estimate Equation (2) using instrumental vari-
` sion pattern for the drug, research reports in scien-
` able estimation as ordinary least squares will generate
` tific journals, any negative or positive publicity for
` biased estimates of the coefficients for APrescribeit-1
` the brand or its competitors, etc. The 11 specialty-
` and ACompetitorit. By construction, APrescribeit_1 will
` specific trends K, capture influences that shift pre-
` be correlated with the differenced error term qit
` scribing behavior across all physicians in a particular
` and, just as substitution effects cause competitor pre-
` specialty. After we take first differences, the time-
` scriptions to influence own prescriptions, own pre-
` period-specific indicators and the specialty-specific
` scriptions will influence the amount of competitor
` trends are transformed into time-period-specific inter-
` prescriptions. Following Anderson and Hsiao (1982),
` we use lagged values of the levels of the series
` cepts and specialty-specific intercepts.
` To remove the influence of physician specific effects
` (values at time period t - 2 and earlier) to gener-
` (i.e., ai), we take first differences of Equation (1) to
` ate instrumental variable estimates for APrescribeit-1
` obtain
` and ACompetitorit. This procedure generates consis-
` tent (i.e., asymptotically unbiased) estimates of the
` APrescribeit
` parameters and their standard errors.3
` 6 6
` = p fj3 * ADetailsit-j + yei * ASamplesitj
` Results
` j=0 j=O
` For each of the three drugs in our study, we estimated
` 6 6
` the Equation (2) regression model. Table 2 reports
` + E Aj * ACompetitorit-j + ~ * APrescribeit-j
` the estimated coefficients. Figures 1 and 2 graphically
` j=0 j=1
` depict the estimated direct effects of detailing and
` T 11
` + , * ATime(r) + K * Specialty(s) + it. (2)
` sampling, respectively.
` Persistence in Prescribing Behavior. For each of
` Of notable absence from our model, due to lack of
` the three drugs in the study we observe signifi-
` available data, is competitive marketing effort. How-
` cant persistence in physicians' prescribing behavior.
` ever, several considerations suggest that the poten-
` Although the first-order autocorrelation is the most
` tial bias in the estimated effects of firm detailing and
` substantial for all three drugs, significant higher-order
` sampling stemming from this omission will be minor.
` effects are present as well. For Drug A the estimated
` First, the inclusion of competitor sales will capture
` coefficients for months 1 through 6 of 0.357, 0.205,
` some of the effects of competitive marketing activi-
` ties and thus reduce potential omitted variable bias.
` 2 We thank Ernst R. Berndt for granting us access to these data. See
` In essence, the competitor sales variable in the model
` Berndt et al. (2003) for a complete description of the data. Consis-
` will act as a proxy variable (Wickens 1972) for com-
` tent with lack

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket