throbber
INDEX: A Platform for Determining how People Value the
`Quality of their Internet Access
`INDEX Project Report #98-010P
`
`Bj¨orn Rupp
`
`Richard J. Edell
`
`Harish Chand
`
`Pravin P. Varaiya
`
`May 1998
`
`© 1998 IEEE. All rights reserved. Do not redistribute this document
`electronically. This document may be found on the web at:
`http://www.INDEX.Berkeley.EDU/reports/98-010P
`
`Abstract
`The continuing exponential growth of the Internet and the emergence of new time-critical applications have
`led to the integration of a large number of different services on the Internet. In the process, the question of how
`to efficiently allocate bandwidth as a scarce resource has become a crucial issue for the continued proliferation
`of these new services. Future growth depends on the division of services into quality-differentiated market
`segments and the pricing structure of each segment. Successful growth requires service providers to offer
`combinations of quality and price that match user need. But to do this providers must understand the structure
`of user demand. Such understanding is lacking at present.
`This paper describes a platform designed to obtain a basic understanding of how individuals value Internet
`usage when offered different Quality of Service choices. The Internet Demand Experiment (INDEX) has
`two main objectives: (a) Measurement of user demand for Internet access as a function of Quality of Service
`(QoS), pricing structure, and application; and (b) Demonstration of an end-to-end system that provides ac-
`cess to a diverse group of users at attractive price-quality combinations. The data being collected is expected
`to reveal the correlation between user application and service demand, howdemand varies with user experi-
`ence, and up to what extent users form discrete market segments. This paper gives an overview of both the
`technology employed at INDEX and the goals of the experimental design.
`
`The INDEX Project is supported by the National Science Foundation, Cisco Systems, SBC Communications and the
`California State MICRO Grant program.
`
`1
`
`GUEST TEK EXHIBIT 1007
`Guest Tek v. Nomadix, IPR2019-00211
`
`

`

`In: ProceedingsoftheSixthIEEE/IFIPInternationalWorkshoponQualityofService,Napa,CA,May1998,pp.85-90. c 1998IEEE.1
`
`INDEX: A Platform for Determining how People Value the Quality of their Internet Access
`
`Bj¨orn Rupp Richard Edell Harish Chandy Pravin Varaiya
`
` Department of Electrical Engineering & Computer Sciences yDepartment of Economics
`University of California at Berkeley
`
`Abstract
`
`The continuing exponential growth of the Internet and the emer-
`gence of new time-critical applications have led to the integration
`of a large number of different services on the Internet.
`In the
`process, the question of how to efficiently allocate bandwidth as
`a scarce resource has become a crucial issue for the continued
`proliferation of these new services. Future growth depends on the
`division of services into quality-differentiated market segments
`and the pricing structure of each segment. Successful growth re-
`quires service providers to offer combinations of quality and price
`that match user need. But to do this providers must understand
`the structure of user demand. Such understanding is lacking at
`present.
`This paper describes a platform designed to obtain a basic un-
`derstanding of how individuals value Internet usage when offered
`different Quality of Service choices. The Internet Demand Ex-
`periment (INDEX) has two main objectives: (a) Measurement of
`user demand for Internet access as a function of Quality of Service
`(QoS), pricing structure, and application; and (b) Demonstration
`of an end-to-end system that provides access to a diverse group of
`users at attractive price-quality combinations. The data being col-
`lected is expected to reveal the correlation between user application
`and service demand, how demand varies with user experience, and
`up to what extent users form discrete market segments. This paper
`gives an overview of both the technology employed at INDEX and
`the goals of the experimental design.
`
`1 Motivation
`
`In recent years, the Internet has undergone a dramatic transforma-
`tion from a computer network dominated by traditional, mostly
`text-based applications and a comparatively small, coherent user
`community to a universal platform for ever more users and ser-
`vices. This was not without its consequences. While traditional ap-
`plications like electronic mail or file transfers can react in an elastic
`fashion to deviations in available bandwidth, new time-critical ap-
`plications like Internet telephony and video conferencing cannot,
`thereby causing their employment to be severely limited as soon as
`network congestion leads to high packet delays and packet drops.
`With the explosion of demand for Internet services, higher speed
`access, and new applications, this situation continues to worsen. A
`single “best effort” service quality seems to become increasingly
`inappropriate for a network serving a wide variety of users and
`applications. Currently, users who occasionally need high band-
`width are either forced to lease over-provisioned dedicated lines,
`
`risk the vagaries of the performance of “best effort”-quality shared
`resources, or forego the desired application altogether. When
`demand for Internet access varies among the population (as indi-
`cated by population-projectable data as in [CommerceNet/Nielsen
`1997] ), quality differentiation, along with proper economic in-
`centives, can increase the overall value of the network by making
`available resources when needed for high value applications. The
`division of services into quality-differentiated market segments
`and the design of appropriate pricing structures for each segment
`is crucial for further proliferation of Internet services. Successful
`growth requires service providers to offer combinations of quality
`and price that match user need. But to do this providers must
`understand the structure of user demand. While there have been
`many pricing proposals in recent literature (for a short overview of
`different approaches, see [Shenker et al. 1996]), such understand-
`ing of user demand is lacking at present.
`
`INDEX — the Internet Demand Experiment — is a real-world
`market trial seeking to provide this information and measure how
`individuals value Internet usage when they are offered different
`Quality of Service choices.
`INDEX has two main objectives:
`(a) Measurement of user demand for Internet access as a function
`of quality of service (QoS), pricing structure, and application; and
`(b) Demonstration of an end-to-end system that provides access to
`a diverse group of users at attractive price-quality combinations.
`The experiment will provide Internet access over ISDN lines to a
`group of about 150 users from the Berkeley campus community
`for a two-year period. Users select network services from a menu
`of QoS-price offerings and pay for their usage.
`It is important
`to stress that while the subjects’ basic Internet access (in partic-
`ular, the ISDN line and access equipment) is greatly subsidized,
`each choice on these QoS menus has a real economic cost which
`the subjects pay out of their own pockets. This is necessary in
`order to achieve incentive compatibility, i.e. given the incentive
`schedule as represented by their active menu, users pick the option
`that corresponds to their true valuation of the network resources in
`question. The menu changes in certain intervals in order to mea-
`sure demand for a wide range of combinations of QoS, price and
`user characteristics. The data being collected is expected to reveal
`the correlation between user application and service demand, how
`demand varies with user experience, and up to what extent users
`form discrete market segments. The data will also allow to test
`hypotheses about the structure of the market for variable-quality
`ATM services. In addition, the experiment demonstrates a single
`system that offers variable service quality-price combinations that
`meet the needs of a diverse user population, an automated billing
`system that also gives the user control over service selection, and
`
`

`

`a remotely operated network monitoring and management system.
`This paper gives an overview of the INDEX Project’s scope and
`describes both the technology employed and the goals, timing and
`structural details of the experimental design.
`
`2 Experimental Setup
`
`2.1 INDEX Access Network Provision
`
`The INDEX access network provides IP service over dedicated,
`128kbps ISDN lines in order to establish a predictable and stable
`QoS between the subjects’ homes and the INDEX Project Net-
`work Operations Center1. For this purpose, INDEX loans a pre-
`configured Cisco 762 ISDN router to each subject participating in
`the experiment and installs an ISDN phone line at their home. The
`128kbps basic rate interface lines coming from the subjects’ homes
`are then multiplexed over ISDN primary rate lines at the Pacific
`Bell central office before they reach the INDEX Project Network
`Operations Center. In contrast to common industry practice, the
`overall available bandwidth is not reduced in the multiplexing
`process and the whole network is heavily overprovisioned to make
`sure that none of the subjects experience deteriorations of their
`selected quality level due to potential bottlenecks at the INDEX
`access network.
`
`1
`
`Cisco
`762s
`
`2
`
`2
`
`ISDN BRI
`
`PSTN
`
`2
`
`Cisco
`7513
`
`Cisco
`7507
`
`3
`
`3
`
`BGW
`(Intel PCs)
`
`3
`
`4
`
`Cat 5000
`Switched
`Ethernet
`
`1
`
`IP
`
`2
`
`IP
`
`PPP
`
`ISDN PRIs
`
`4
`
`IP
`
`3
`
`IP
`
`PPP
`UDP
`
`4
`
`Cisco 7200
`(DCNS maintains)
`
`4
`
`Supervisor
`(also WWW
`& DBMS)
`
`4
`
`Offline
`Analysis
`
`NMAS
`
`Campus
`Network
`&
`Internet
`
`Figure 1: INDEX Network – Transport Layer
`
`At the INDEX NOC, all connections are through either a Cisco
`7507 or 7513 Internet router. These routers distribute all user traffic
`over a set of Billing Gateways specifically designed to meter usage
`and selectively adjust the service quality of individual connections.
`The user may select a service quality from the currently active
`menu of choices at any time. Connections are aggregated by
`user so that the quality for this bundle can then be controlled
`accordingly. All outbound packets are forwarded to a Cisco 7200
`router that is directly connected to the UC Berkeley 100Mbps
`FDDI backbone.
`
`1It should be noted that although the current experimental setup is oriented
`towards providing service over ISDN lines, the INDEX network architecture is
`flexible enough to allow us to expand the experiment to demonstrate ADSL or
`CATV access using cable modems at a later stage.
`
`2.2 User Interaction, Accounting and Billing
`
`INDEX uses a locally developed system for user interaction and
`metering individual subject usage. The user interacts with this sys-
`tem by means of the “Control Center”, a Java application running
`on the user’s computer. For the subjects, this is the central appli-
`cation enabling them to select different Qualities of Service and
`control their usage of network resources. Apart from functions for
`login and authentication, it consists of a small window informing
`the user about the current experiment, the price schedule currently
`in effect and the actual choices. The subjects can choose a service
`quality by the click of a button and change their Quality of Service
`even during the active session. The Control Center also provides
`usage feedback by displaying a summary of charges for either the
`current session, the current day or the current month.
`
`Figure 2: INDEX User Interface (“Control Center”)
`
`The Control Center application communicates user choices and
`selected quality levels as control data going through a Billing Gate-
`way to a “supervisor” process. This supervisor process then orders
`the Billing Gateway to treat this user’s connections according to
`the selected quality level. The Billing Gateway in turn meters the
`traffic and reports back to the supervisor process.
`User traffic is monitored and recorded at a fairly detailed level
`for both billing purposes and subsequent offline analysis. The
`database contains records for each TCP connection. Apart from an
`anonymized user ID, time stamp, selected QoS/price information
`and a variety of TCP control data types, they include information
`about connection length, the amount of inbound and outbound
`traffic for the connection, source and destination IP addresses,
`port numbers, and other data describing the type of user activity.
`It is important to collect data at this level of detail in order to not
`only record at what time users change their QoS choices, but also
`to infer what parameters influence these decisions and what the
`reasons for these changes are. Such detailed records are able to
`reveal, for instance, what applications are running at the time of
`a QoS change and what types of hosts and network services are
`involved.
`
`

`

`2.3 Network QoS Emulation
`
`After a subject has chosen a desired quality level, the QoS must
`be adjusted (i.e. degraded) accordingly. As the current Internet
`infrastructure does not permit controlling QoS, the INDEX Billing
`Gateways do not only control and measure network usage, but
`they are also capable of selectively degrading the performance
`of certain TCP connections (e.g., all connections on behalf of
`a given subject). User quality choices map to entry points of
`an internal “emulated network” composed of different elements
`including leaky bucket, random router and packet delay or packet
`drop. This behavior can be altered quickly in response to subject
`choices or experimentally controlled random processes.
`While it would be desirable to give users complete control over
`end-to-end performance of their connections, this is unfortunately
`impossible while the single-quality “best effort” paradigm still
`prevails. As a consequence, the quality offered by INDEX cannot
`exceed the baseline undegraded QoS. However, much of our sub-
`ject pool is accustomed to a congested, 14.4kbps modem pool for
`accessing the campus network. In addition, many of the services
`that our subjects seek to access are in fact campus services for
`which there are little other sources of degradation. Therefore, we
`believe that INDEX is adequately capable of controlling the QoS
`delivered to the subjects.
`
`3 Experimental Design
`
`3.1 Purpose and Objectives
`
`INDEX seeks to answer the question of how people value the
`quality of their Internet access. There are three basic aspects to
`this question. The first and most fundamental is what dimensions
`of QoS truly matter for overall end user’s perception of service
`quality. While there are indeed many dimensions of QoS that can
`or could be varied on the supply side, little is known about along
`which dimensions users feel performance to be most significantly
`affected by these parameters and up to what extent they are will-
`ing to sacrifice certain service characteristics in order to improve
`others. Although these internal valuations are very likely to be
`heavily dependent on the type of application the user is running,
`empirical data capable of accurately verifying and quantifying
`these hypotheses is still missing at present. One important goal of
`the experimental design therefore is to identify the key parameters
`for user’s perceptions of QoS and to quantify the correlation be-
`tween application type and service demand. This information will
`substantially aid network service providers in future decisions on
`which aspects of QoS to optimize and when and where to expand
`the network in order to provide service options that satisfy users’
`needs.
`The second task is to measure the economic value which indi-
`vidual users place on different resource levels for each of the QoS
`dimensions identified. The results from these investigations should
`support decisions on what kind of pricing structure to choose and
`what economic incentives the price structure should provide. For
`example, congestion-based prices require users and network ad-
`ministrators to know the value lost due to congestion. The degree
`to which congestion needs to be discouraged or the markup charged
`
`to priority service depends on the degradation of user value due
`to user contention.
`If the perceived network degradation from
`congestion is substantial, then congestion-related pricing (such as
`time-of-day, traffic-based, or priority-based charges) can rational-
`ize the allocation of network resources and increase the value of
`the network.
`Apart from gaining a better understanding of how to quan-
`tify valuation of different dimensions of QoS, survey data (i.a.
`[CommerceNet/Nielsen 1997, Kehoe/Pitkow/Morton 1997] ) also
`suggests that demand for Internet access varies among the popu-
`lation. The data also indicates that there is a correlation between
`user experience and intensity of network usage. If users are indeed
`considerably heterogeneous in their consumption of network re-
`sources, information about the exact nature of the price elasticity
`of demand will help to differentiate types and levels of service
`through pricing. Therefore, INDEX also includes experiments
`involving nonlinear tariffs to determine up to what extent users
`form discrete market segments. Such multi-part tariffs involve
`price discrimination in the sense that different bundles of homo-
`geneous output are sold at different prices. If substantial variation
`exists among users, and if users are sufficiently sophisticated in
`their decisions, then self-selecting tariffs differentiated on the ba-
`sis of quantity and quality may segment the market on the basis of
`willingness to pay.
`
`3.2 Subject Population
`
`INDEX will recruit about 150 subjects affiliated with the Univer-
`sity of California at Berkeley (students, faculty, staff). Participa-
`tion in the Project is highly attractive for this group of experimental
`subjects because the campus modem pools are highly congested
`while there exists at the same time a lack of other options offering
`service similar to INDEX. The availability of this subject pool of-
`fers several advantages: Firstly, it provides the required geograph-
`ically concentrated pool of diverse users for such an experiment.
`It also allows for a better QoS control than otherwise possible,
`ensures continued participation and reduces costs of setting up the
`experiment.
`The recruiting process involves several steps: The project ad-
`vertises by electronic means such as posting to newsgroups as
`well as traditional means of Berkeley newspaper advertisements
`and articles. The advertisements direct interested people to the
`INDEX WWW server to learn more about the project. Potential
`subjects who wish to participate are required to complete an on-
`line screening survey. The INDEX screening survey collects basic
`contact information, residence location and nature of university
`affiliation to verify eligibility and aid in ISDN service planning.
`Prospective subjects must reasonably expect that their affiliation
`with UC Berkeley will continue for at least two years. We also
`plan to facilitate participation from individuals affiliated with UC
`San Francisco in the near future. After prospective subjects have
`completed the screening survey, they are invited to complete an
`extensive demographic survey. At this stage, taking the survey
`is optional, however completing it is required for all participating
`subjects before they take part in the experiment. After evaluating
`the screening survey results, we invite selected persons to par-
`ticipate.
`If they agree, they receive their access equipment and
`
`

`

`ISP
`
`•
`
`••••••••
`
`CO
`
`•••••••••••••
`
`Subscriber
`Loops (N)
`
`Access
`Ports (M)
`
`ISP Link
`
`Circuit Switched
`(A bps per circuit)
`
`Packet Switched
`(B bps total)
`
`Figure 3: Traditional ISP Resource Model
`
`dimension of resources within the traditional ISP resource model
`(as depicted in Figure 3) affect end user valuation. The second set
`of experiments, experiments five through nine, examine users’ re-
`sponse to alternative price structures. In the majority of these later
`experiments, users will compare alternative pricing schemes with
`a flat rate scheme. The following sections describe the individual
`sub-experiments in detail.
`
`can begin using their INDEX-provided Internet access after the
`ISDN line has been installed at their home and they have signed
`an informed consent form.
`Subjects are recruited with the goal of obtaining a suitable
`variation in, e.g., field of study, expected computer usage, travel
`distance to campus, and demographic characteristics. Neverthe-
`less, it is evident that the sample, like any other, remains biased. In
`order to overcome this sampling bias and be able to extrapolate the
`results, significant sample-specific characteristics influencing the
`results will be identified and analyzed to determine the exact struc-
`ture of the INDEX Project’s demographic base. Before receiving
`INDEX provided Internet access, each subject has to complete
`a detailed demographic survey. Many of its questions are taken
`from a representative, population-projectable study conducted by
`Nielsen Media Research [CommerceNet/Nielsen 1997] in early
`1997. Apart from general demographical data (i.e. income, age,
`gender, household characteristics etc.), the INDEX Demographic
`Survey asks subjects about their recent Internet usage, computer
`sophistication and related data. By comparing the responses to the
`INDEX Demographic Survey with the Nielsen data, it is possible
`to extrapolate findings from the INDEX Project to the general U.S.
`population2.
`
`3.3 Revealed Preference Experiments
`
`3.3.1 Network Resource Valuation Experiments
`
`To achieve the objectives outlined above and investigate the effects
`of alternative price and QoS combinations, a series of experiments
`will be conducted. These experiments infer preferences from data
`based on actual choices for which the subjects have to make eco-
`nomic decisions immediately affecting them – therefore providing
`reliable incentives to accurately represent their preferences. The
`experiments are preceded by a free trial period of several weeks.
`This serves as a “control” for later INDEX experiments and al-
`lows the subjects to gain familiarity with their new Internet access,
`the billing interface and experimental procedures. After the trial
`period is over, users begin paying for their usage. Depending on
`the experimental setting, the fee structure will change either every
`Monday on a weekly basis or daily at 4 a.m. Pacific Standard Time.
`Higher qualities of service will incur a higher fee, but the level and
`ratios depend on the specific sub-experiment and will also change
`over the course of each experiment. Whereas nonexperimental
`studies are forced to rely on cross-sectional variation in prices and
`demand to infer the price elasticity, varying the prices during the
`individual sub-experiments allows for measuring the demand re-
`sponse for each participant. Fairly detailed data will be collected
`on the characteristics of the subjects’ usage. As described in sec-
`tion 2.2, each time the subject uses the ISDN connection, data will
`be collected on the time and length of the session, the speed of the
`connection, the price in effect, and the amount of data transferred
`and applications used during the session.
`The experiments can be partitioned into two groups. The first
`group, representing the first four experiments, examines how the
`
`2We also plan to expand the experiment to conduct general population exper-
`iments and test CATV and ADSL access in the future. This is dependent upon
`cooperative arrangements with CATV and ADSL service providers which have not
`yet been negotiated. These future experiments will be based on a different ISP
`Resource Model and are not described in this paper.
`
`(1) – Variable Bandwidth. Do individuals value connection speed
`sufficiently to pay higher prices for high speed connections? How
`does the elasticity of demand depend on application and demo-
`graphics? Does demand exhibit habit formation? This experiment
`will address these questions and examine how users value the
`speed of their connection to the Internet cloud. It isolates the last
`link in Figure 3 and permits the accurate measurement of the price
`elasticity of demand for connection speed to the Internet cloud.
`Design Details. QoS dimension controlled: Bandwidth (six connec-
`tion speeds A f8 16 32 64 96 128 kbpsg). Duration: 6 weeks. Price
`structure: Five weeks with weekly price changes, one week with daily
`price changes – strictly increasing prices within certain limits.
`(2) – Variable Asymmetric Bandwidth. Since the early days
`of the 1200/75 bps modems, the question of whether individualend
`users value bandwidth for incoming traffic more than for outgoing
`traffic has been discussed intensely. With the advent of ADSL
`and CATV proposals that feature different fixed data rates for
`incoming and outgoing traffic, this issue warrants further research.
`Do individuals value the speed of their connection from the Internet
`cloud differently than the connection speed to the Internet cloud?
`If yes, what ratios of incoming vs. outgoing bandwidth are deemed
`appropriate? Up to what extent do these ratios depend on the type
`of application run by the user? This experiment seeks to answer
`these questions.
`Design Details. QoS dimension controlled: Bandwidth (six connec-
`tion speeds for both incoming and outgoing traffic). Duration: 6 weeks.
`Price structure: Five weeks with weekly price changes, one week with
`daily price changes – prices from the first experiment will be cut in half
`and applied separately towards each direction of all data flows.
`(3) – Access Reliability. Congestion in dialup access to the
`network is a significant problem in many networks. The expected
`waiting time for a free line can be significant. As a result, once
`
`

`

`connected, users are typically reluctant to relinquish their connec-
`tion even during idle periods for fear of inability to reconnect in
`a prompt manner. By presenting subjects with a choice of three
`different simulated modem pools, this experiment will examine
`the value which users attach to network access and the value of
`waiting time. Each of these simulated modem pools is associated
`with a different, predetermined level of congestion and average
`waiting time. The experiment will thus provide data on whether
`individuals value network access sufficiently to pay higher prices
`for less contention for free circuits and whether they relinquish
`lines more often when they can reconnect.
`Design Details. QoS dimensions controlled: Expected waiting time
`for a connection, bandwidth. Duration: 4 weeks. Price structure: Fixed
`fee based on choice of average modem pool congestion changes daily,
`per-minute charge based on connection speed will not change during the
`duration of the experiment.
`(4) – Priority Service. Another potential source of contention
`from other users is for shared bandwidth (labeled B in Figure 3)
`such as in trunk lines or Internet cable access. While the last ex-
`periment addressed the issue of access reliability, this experiment
`will measure the value which users place on service reliability and
`effective bandwidth by measuring their willingness to pay for dif-
`ferent service priorities. The level of effective bandwidth which
`subjects obtain will be a function of the chosen priority class and
`the level of congestion in the network. The interfering traffic will
`be simulated. The findings from this experiment are expected
`to yield insights into the possible future role for multiple service
`classes that take into account the load status of the network nodes.
`Design Details. QoS dimensions controlled: Effective bandwidth,
`dependent on varying amounts of simulated interfering traffic. Duration:
`6 weeks. Price structure: Different prices for different priority classes.
`
`3.3.2 Alternative Pricing Structures Experiments
`
`(5) – Demand under Traffic-Based Charges. To the extent that
`service degradation occurs due to network traffic, prices should
`reflect the level of traffic which the user generates. However,
`charges based solely on connection time do not provide the proper
`economic incentives and result in a negative externality and in-
`creased congestion. While many researchers have suggested that
`users should be charged on the basis of their traffic, little is known
`about whether users will adequately understand the basis for such
`prices, whether usage will be sensitive to such prices, and whether
`users could benefit from usage based prices due to a reduction in
`network congestion: How price sensitive is the amount of user
`generated traffic? What are the optimal usage charges for band-
`width on demand? How much learning about traffic generation
`occurs? Does the price elasticity change over time?
`Design Details. Segmentation Approach: Volume. Duration: 8 weeks.
`Price structure: Per-byte charges which change once per week. Prices
`will be calibrated so that total charges would be approximately the same as
`under per minute charges in the absence of behavioral effects. Of primary
`interest is whether usage decreases in comparison to the first experiment,
`and whether usage decreases more when per byte charges are higher.
`(6) – Tariff Self-Selection. Would individuals voluntarily
`choose tariffs based on bytes rather than minutes? Are these
`choices of self-selecting tariffs rational? Is usage sufficiently pre-
`
`dictable? In this experiment, subjects will be presented with a
`choice of six different connection speeds and three different tariff
`structures. The tariff structures will be different combinations of
`per minute charges and per byte charges. Users will be offered the
`choice of being charged exclusively on the basis of either minutes
`or bytes, as well as the choice of having half of the charges being
`determined by each.
`Design Details. Segmentation Approach: Self-Selection. Duration:
`10 weeks. Price structure: Users will be asked to select which tariff
`structure they wish to be billed under for the course of the week. The
`prices contained in the tariff structure will remain in effect for two weeks
`at a time.
`(7) – Time-of-Use Charges and Peak Shifting. Network use
`displays regular temporal patterns. In order to avoid building extra
`capacity to meet peak usage, price incentives may be provided in an
`effort to shift some demand from peak to non-peak periods. Since
`there is likely to be a significant amount of variation in tastes
`and time constraints, significant welfare gains might be possible.
`For example, if a sizable segment of the user population could be
`induced to shift usage to nonpeak hours, the value of the resources
`to those unable to shift their usage may increase substantially.
`Design Details. Segmentation Approach: Time-of-day. Duration: 8
`weeks. Price structure: Price incentives will be provided to shift some
`demand from peak to non-peak periods. Suitable peak periods will be
`identified from data collected during the earlier experiments.
`(8) – Demand under Flat Rate Pricing. This experiment
`will vary the level of the flat fee charged to users for unlimited
`usage in order to examine the total value which users place on
`access at different connection speeds. The relationship of this
`value to various observable characteristics will also be examined.
`By obtaining this measure of user heterogeneity in the total value
`of usage, the design of optimal tariffs will be helped greatly.
`Design Details. Segmentation Approach: Total value of access at
`defined connection speeds. Duration: 12 weeks. Price structure: Flat
`price will differ by connection speed and change on a weekly basis. Unlike
`the first experiment where each connection speed could be reselected as
`desired, only the speed(s) for which the flat fee has been paid will be
`allowed. Thus, if an individual discovers in midweek that a higher speed
`is needed, the individual would have to pay the new higher fixed fee.
`(9) – Two-Part Tariff Design. This experiment will com-
`bine some of the different features of the previous experiments.
`Whereas experiment 6 examined the selection of tariffs which
`varied according to the basis for usage sensitive fees (per-minute
`charges versus per-byte charges), this experiment will vary only
`the relative contributions of the fixed and variable charges. This
`will allow examination of how users respond to declining block
`tariffs and also provide some insight into whether individuals have
`preferences over tariff structures themselves due to such effects
`as risk aversion or mental accounting costs. Combined with data
`from the other experiments, this will allow for the design of price
`structures which track consumer demand curves more closely than
`do either fixed fees or uniform prices.
`Design Details. Segmentation Approach: Self-Selection. Duration:
`10 weeks. Price structure: Individuals will face a menu of tariff choices
`which will vary according to the level of the fixed weekly fee and the
`usage sensitive fee and

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket