throbber
Ownership of knowledge — the role of patents in
`pharmaceutical R&D
`Carlos Maria Correa1
`
`Abstract Both the public and the private sectors contribute to research and development (R&D) in pharmaceuticals. The public sector
`originates many of the discoveries of new drugs. The private sector, which focuses on development, is heavily reliant on patents.
`Though patents are presumed to reward genuine inventions, lax rules on patentability and shortcomings in procedures permit
`protection to be obtained on a myriad of minor developments. These patents, though weak and possibly invalid in many cases, are
`used to restrain competition and delay the entry of generic competition. Developing countries should design and implement their
`patent laws so as to prevent strategic patenting and promote competition and access to medicines.
`
`Keywords Patents/legislation; Pharmaceutical preparations; Research; Diffusion of innovation; Drug industry (source: MeSH, NLM).
`Mots clés Brevet/législation; Preparations pharmaceutiques; Recherche; Diffusion des innovations; Industrie pharmaceutique (source:
`MeSH, INSERM).
`Palabras clave Patentes/legislacién; Preparaciones farmacéuticas; Investigacion; Difusién de innovacion; Industria farmacéutica
`(fuente: DeCS, BIREME).
`
`csn 4.,» can-pp dug, 2MB ausSri Tuba sobigsvi Just safari tagger olwl étlfiYl old}; Ca» carafe :Kc’iaéll outfit
`Guy-u 5:75 are
`
`Bulletin of the World Health Organization 2004;82:784-790.
`
`Voir page 786 Ie résume’ en frangais. En la pégina 786 figura un resumen en espafiol.
`
`.786 H.» QM,“ ”new “is 3”“ a“.
`
`Although governments are responsible for a significant portion
`ofglobal spending on research and development (R&D), since
`the 19805 a steep decline in the share of government firnds for
`R&D is a trend common to all major industrialized countries
`and many other Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
`Development (OECD) countries. In the largest OECD coun-
`tries (with the exception ofItaly), the private sector performed
`between 62% and 70% of total national R&D (1).
`Private and public sources also coexist in pharmaceutical
`R&D. The division oflabour in pharmaceutical R&D between
`the two sectors is related, at least in principle, to the nature of
`the knowledge that is fostered (2). In most cases, the discovery
`of important new drugs is made by public institutions, which
`later license their development and exploitation to private
`firms. Some 70% ofdrugs with therapeutic gain mre produced
`with government involvement (3). Basic research that led to the
`discovery ofpotential “drug leads” has almost always been pub-
`licly funded at universities, in-house government facilities, or
`research institutes in Europe, North America, and Japan. Since
`the beginning ofthe 20th century, publicly funded research has
`led to major drug lead discoveries in, for example, tuberculosis,
`other infectious diseases and cancer. More recently, publicly
`funded research has led to the discovery of antiretrovirals for
`the treatment of human immunodeficiency virus/acquired
`
`immunodeficiency syndrome (HIV/AIDS). Publicly funded
`genome research has also produced many drug leads (4). In the
`United States, the federally funded biomedical research sup-
`ported by the National Institutes ofHealth (NIH) plays a vital
`role in new drug development, feeding into the R&D activities
`of the private pharmaceutical industry that operates under
`patent protection (2). In addition to this direct and important
`contribution, governments ofmany developed countries grant
`tax credits and other incentives for R&D (1).
`However, private industry invests the largest part of
`global funds for pharmaceutical R&D. Unlike the public sec—
`tor, industry’s research agenda is dominated by profit—making
`objectives. Most of industry’s resources are concentrated on
`applied R&D, though funds are also devoted to basic research.
`In 1999, for instance, 24.5% of R&D spending was on basic
`research in the United Kingdom, 36% in the United States, and
`18.4% in Canada (5).
`Given the objectives and nature of industry’s activities,
`they rely heavily on the acquisition and enforcement ofpatents
`worldwide. A common belief is that patents are normally ac—
`quired to protect new drugs, and thereby recover the substantial
`R&D investments made for increasing the range of available
`therapies; but the number of patents annually obtained to
`protect genuinely new pharmaceutical products is very small
`
`‘ Director, Centre of Interdisciplinary Studies of Industrial and Economic Law, University of Buenos Aires, Av. Figueroa Alcorta 2263, lst floor, 1425 Buenos Aires,
`Argentina (email: ceidie@derecho.uha.ar).
`Ref. No. 03-010801
`(Submitted 18 December 2003 7 Final revised version received: 23 June 2004 7 Accepted: 24 lune 2004)
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 1 of 7
`
`Mylan V. Sanofi - IPR2018-01676
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 1 of 7
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01676
`
`

`

`Carlos Maria Correa
`
`Special Theme — Bridging the Know-Do Gap in Global Health
`Patents in pharmaceutical R&D
`
`and declining, whereas thousands of patents are applied for
`or granted concerning pharmaceutical—related inventions. The
`number of patents acquired in relation to “upstream” inven-
`tions, that is, scientific discoveries rather than specific technical
`solutions, is increasing. This kind of patenting detracts from
`public domain knowledge that could be used “downstream” by
`many researchers to explore multiple inventive opportunities;
`it deprives society of the benefits that the widespread use and
`dissemination of basic scientific ideas could generate (2). The
`problems raised by this form of privatization of science have
`been explored by an extensive literature (6, 7). Patents, on the
`other hand, are ordinarily acquired for a myriad offollow-on,
`merely incremental, or minor developments.
`
`Innovation in pharmaceuticals
`Innovation in pharmaceuticals relies increasingly on the knowl-
`edge gleaned from preceding innovations and on generally
`available techniques (8, 9). As in other sectors, innovation “has
`shifted away from models based on absolute novelty and first
`improvement towards a model in which innovation is no lon—
`ger driven by technological breakthroughs but by the routine
`exploitation of existing technologies” (10). Innovation in this
`sector follows, therefore, an essentially “cumulative” model of
`innovation, as opposed to the “discrete” model, where the pros—
`pects ofvariations and improvements of inventions are substan—
`tially bounded.
`Many of the new chemin entities of pharmaceutical
`use do not entail a genuine therapeutic progress; they are “me
`too” drugs, developed as a result of the great deal of emula—
`tion of successful drugs undertaken by rival companies (11).
`Pharmaceutical innovation also includes a large number of
`improvements or minor changes to existing drugs, and the
`identification of new uses of known products. Incremental in-
`novation is often motivated by the objective of attending the
`commercial benefits derived from existing products, particu-
`larly when original patents expire and new patents may be used
`to prolong market exclusivity.
`According to a report ofthe National Institute for Health
`Care Management (NIHCM) in the United States, from 1989
`to 2000 the United States Food and Drug Administration
`(FDA) approved 1035 new drug applications. Ofthese, a third
`(35%) were products with new active ingredients, or new mo—
`lecular entities (NMEs). The other 65% used active ingredients
`that were already available in a marketed product. Over half
`(54%) were incrementally modified drugs, or new versions of
`medicines whose active ingredients were already available in an
`approved product. The rest (11%) contained the same active
`ingredient as identical marketed products (12).
`Priority NMEs, the most innovative type of new drugs,
`were rare in the 12-year period 1989—2000: just 153 (15%) of
`all new drug approvals were medicines that used new active in-
`gredients and provided significant clinical improvement. Drugs
`providing moderate innovation comprised another 28% of
`approvals. The other 57% ofapprovals were for drugs showing
`only modest innovation, at best: 46% made some modification
`to an older product containing the same active ingredient,
`while the remaining 1 1% were identical to marketed products.
`As a result, the NIHCM reports, priority NMEs — the most
`innovative drugs — contributed little to the increase in new
`products, and most growth came from products that did not
`provide significant clinical improvement, especially modified
`versions of older drugs (12).
`
`Patenting cumulative innovations
`The cumulative nature of innovation has important repercus—
`sions on the patent system. Though theoretically conceived to
`reward inventions marked by considerable originality, the patent
`system is plagued with grants covering incremental, minor — in
`some cases trivial — developments. They are not the product
`of inventive efforts, but rather the outcome of “taking a speedy
`path down a trail that was obvious to many” (8, p. 128). In
`2001, the United States Patent and Trademark Office granted
`over 171 000 patents, almost twice the number granted ten
`years earlier. This increase cannot simply be attributed to an
`increase in RSCD productivity, but to the flexibility of the
`patent system to permit the protection offollow-on and other
`developments (13, pp. 1933—4).
`Moreover, there is increasing evidence about poor pat-
`ent quality. (A poor—quality patent is one that is likely to be
`invalid or contains claims that are likely to be overly broad
`(14).) “Non-obviousness” or “inventive step” (one of the key
`patentability requirements) is assessed against a standard that
`many follow—on and routine innovations do not find difficult
`to meet, based on the fiction ofwhat “a person with ordinary
`skill in the art” would have been able to derive from prior art.
`Weaknesses in patent procedures, in addition, favour the grant-
`ing of patents over trivial or minor developments (14’, 15),
`despite the significant resources invested in developed countries
`to fund patent offices (16).
`Large firms have rapidly learned how to exploit lax
`patentability standards and the shortcomings in the patent
`examination process. They apply different strategies to use
`patents offensively as means to encumber or block potential
`competitors. Thus, “hankering” strategies aim at mining every
`step in a manufacturing process with parents claiming minor
`modifications; “findng’ refers to a situation where a series of
`patents blocks certain lines or directions ofR&D; “rm-rounding”
`takes place “when an important central patent can be fenced
`in or surrounded by other patents, which are individually less
`important but collectively block the effective commercial use of
`the central patent, even after its expiration” (17); and Wading”
`is based on the acquisition of many parents on minor or incre-
`mental variations on technology developed by another com—
`pany (18, 19). For other anti-competitive practices, see (20).
`As noted by the NIHCM, “drug manufacturers patent a
`wide range ofinventions connected with incremental modifica—
`tions of their products, including minor features such as inert
`ingredients and the form, color, and scoring oftablets. In many
`cases, these patents discourage generic companies from trying
`to develop a competitive product” (12). Moreover, backed by
`substantial budgets for patent acquisition and litigation, phar-
`maceutical companies have been able to delay substantially the
`entry ofgeneric competition by “evergreening” many of their
`patents (21—23). According to United States lawmaker Waxman
`(one of the authors of the United States Drug Price Competi—
`tion and Patent Restoration Act of 1984, commonly known
`as the “Waxman—Hatch Act”) brand-name companies “have
`used creative lawyering to try and extend the period of their
`monopolies long past the time intended by Congress” (24’).
`Poor-quality patents acquired to encumber or delay ge-
`neric competition are generally aggressively used against com—
`petitors. They are likely to be invalidated totally or partially,
`however, ifsubject to a more serious scrutiny by judicial courts
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 2 of 7
`
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01676
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 2 of 7
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01676
`
`

`

`Special Theme — Bridging the Know—Do Gap in Global Health
`Patents in pharmaceutical R&D
`
`Carlos Marla Correa
`
`than the examination made at the patent office, as shown in a
`study by the United States Federal Trade Commission on drug
`entry and patent expiration (25).
`
`Conclusions
`
`Patents have become a key factor in the RSCD process in phar-
`maceuticals. Although, in certain contexts, they provide the
`incentives to develop new pharmaceutical products from which
`society may benefit, by their very nature they limit the diffusion
`of the innovations that they are intended to promote. When
`the innovation process is cumulative, strong protection for the
`first—generation producer limits the scope ofsecond—generation
`producers, and slows down follow—on innovation.
`Patents often establish barriers to entry that are unjusti—
`fied in terms of the technical contribution effectively made.
`Low standards ofpatentability have allowed a significant expan-
`
`sion of patent coverage. Strategic patenting diverts resources
`into litigation and restrains legitimate competition. While this
`is taking place in both developed and developing countries
`alike, it is particularly worrying in the latter since competition
`laws are in many cases non-existent or poorly implemented,
`and domestic firms are generally too small to bear the costs and
`risks of litigation. Developing countries have struggled in the
`past few years to confirm their rights to use the flexibilities
`allowed by the Agreement on Trade—related Aspects ofIntellec—
`tual Property Rights (TRIPS), particularly in relation to parallel
`imports and compulsory licences.fl Without abandoning these
`efforts, they should pay more attention to the way in which
`patents are examined and granted, in order to avoid abuses
`and the negative eEects on access to medicines that patents on
`noninventive developments entail. I
`
`Conflicts of interest: none declared.
`
`Résumé
`
`Propriété intellectuelle - Le role des brevets dans la R & D en pharmacie
`Le secteur privé, comme le secteur publique, contribuent aux
`progrés mineurs. Ces brevets, quoique faibles et éventuellement
`activités de recherche et développement (R & D) dans Ie domaine
`invalides dans de nombreux cas, sont utilisés pour restreindre Ia
`pharmaceutique. Le secteur public est a I'origine de la découverte
`concurrence et retarder l'entrée en compétition des génériques.
`d'un grand nombre de nouveaux médicaments. Le secteur privé, qui
`|| convient que les pays en développement concoivent et mettent
`en oeuvre leur Iégislation sur les brevets de maniere a prévenir Ia
`axe ses efforts sur la développement, dépend fortement des brevets.
`Bien que ceux—ci soient supposés récompenser de véritables
`prise de brevets stratégique et a promouvoir la concurrence et
`I'accés aux médicaments.
`inventions, Ie laxisme des Iois sur la brevetabilité et les défauts de
`procédure permettent d'obtenir la protection d'une multitude de
`
`Resumen
`
`Propiedad de Ios conocimientos - Funcién de las patentes en la I+D farmacéutica
`desarrollos de poca importancia. Estas patentes, aunque poco
`Tanto el sector publico como el sector privado contribuyen a la
`investigacién y el desarrollo (|+D) de preparaciones farmacéuticas.
`consistentes y posiblemente carentes de validez en muchos casos,
`Muchos de los descubrimientos de medicamentos nuevos tienen
`se usan para restringir Ia competencia y retrasar la introduccién de
`lugar en el sector publico. El sector privado, que se centra en el
`medicamentos genéricos. Los paises en desarrollo deben disefiar
`desarrollo, depende en gran medida de las patentes. Aunque se
`y aplicar sus Ieyes en la materia de manera que prevengan las
`supone que éstas recompensan auténticas invenciones, Ia laxitud
`patentes estratégicas y promuevan la competencia y el acceso a
`Ios medicamentos.
`de las normas acerca de la patentabilidad y Ios tallos de Ios
`procedimientos permiten obtener proteccién para innumerables
`
`unable-r
`2413.01 alrmlt July—j cf. ,3 {up-‘11 out). ”a :deu this»:
`
`93 WW :45 nil-JD Otto“ “3‘ My .egu: Elem 1:353
`J,» «A; Jew ”a; “and rw u? 3‘: :cu‘JLil g» Arm
`agar
`JLU-J‘ &;
`.5945 L;_: J.) _3....0L'ii cal, saga igyill
`f.- ow Ci rill-styl ourfi C" Gigi! Law-r Lair}; L.” aids!
`.39 Q's—”'4 up}; ft“ .235) 35.31,le .rLAl
`tsl’ detail
`‘
`.igpi‘i
`
`flail Judas}! ML”; :MI
`grwr ”is; af. g dad—1:
`imp 1,3:
`;5“*“‘il M93“ J. 41,qu $1; full {Ml oi girth
`old); L519 5115 l'le-l‘el Jag-.5 ”glad! fiuwlffi [SS—ill guard—i
`.
`..
`l
`I
`.
`1
`_.‘
`r‘
`._.=
`r'_
`‘l..
`__
`quire»! 3E Ulilfiul cam 3i Huey-Ml J ”A (fig-1:1 .ilfa-Xl‘
`”as MrJl:
`tour/d! Em ail-cl] Eager
`fie Aclfill or '3';
`target—r
`guise ,tg tiff-‘9‘ ow L»); gr aged-u 5dr obi“; gray)“
`
`‘ See World Health Assembly Resolution WHA56.27 (2003) which recommends Member States "to use to the full the flexibilities" contained in the TRIPS Agreement.
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 3 of 7
`
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01676
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 3 of 7
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01676
`
`

`

`Carlos Maria Correa
`
`Special Theme — Bridging the Know-Do Gap in Global Health
`Patents in pharmaceutical R&D
`
`References
`1 . National Science Board. Science and engineering indicators 2002. Arlington
`(VA): National Science Foundation; 2002.
`2. Macroeconomics and health: investing in health for economic development.
`Report of the Commission on Macroeconomics and Health. Geneva: World
`Health Organization; 2001.Available from: htpp:llwww.who.int
`3. United Nations Development Programme. Human development report. New
`York: Oxford University Press; 1999.
`4. Fatal imbalance. The crisis in research and development for drugs for
`neglected diseases Geneva: Médecins Sans Frontiéres; 2001.
`5. A comparison ofpharmaceutical research and development spending in
`Canada and selected countries. Ottawa: Patented Medicine Prices Review
`Board; 2002.
`6. Barton JH. Research-tool patents: issues for health in the developing world.
`Bulletin of the World Health Organization 2002;80:121-5.
`7. Eisenberg RS. Bargaining over the transfer of proprietary research tools: is
`this market failing or emerging? In: Dreyfuss R, Zimmerman D, First H,
`editors. Expanding the boundaries ofintellectual property. Oxford: Oxford
`University Press; 2001.
`8. Merges R, Nelson R. 0n limiting or encouraging rivalry in technical progress:
`the effect of patent-scope decisions. In: Nelson R, editor. The sources of
`economic growth. Cambridge and London: Harvard University Press; 1996.
`9. Long C. Patents and cumulative innovation. Washington University Journal
`of Law and Policy 2000;2:22946.
`10. Foray D. Production and distribution of knowledge in the new systems of
`innovation: the role of intellectual property rights. Science, Technology
`Industry Review 1992;16:1 19—52.
`11. Casadio Tarabusi C, Vickery G. Globalization in the pharmaceutical industry.
`International Journal of Health Services 1998; 1 :67—105.
`12. National Institute for Health Care Management. Changing patterns of
`pharmaceutical innovation. Washington (DC): NIHCM Foundation; 2002.
`Available from: http://www.nihcm.org
`
`13. Barton J. Reforming the patent system. Science 2000;287:193341.
`14. To promote innovation: the proper balance of competition and patent law
`and policy. Washington (DC): Federal Trade Commission; 2003.Avai|able
`from: htpp:llwww.ftc.gov
`15. Keeping science open: the effects of intellectual property policy on the
`conduct ofscience. London: The Royal Society; 2003. Policy document 02/03.
`16. Intellectual property: information on the US Patent and Trademark Office's
`past and future operations. Washington (DC): General Accounting Office;
`2002. Report to Congressional Requesters.
`17. Granstrand O. The economics and management of intellectual property.
`Towards intellectual capitalism. Northampton: Edward Elgar; 1996.
`18. Sankaran SK. Patent flooding in the United States and Japan. The Journal of
`Law and Technology 2000; 1 :393-428.
`19. Glasgow LJ. Stretching the limits of intellectual property rights: has the
`pharmaceutical industry gone too far? The journal of Law and Technology
`2001;2:227-58.
`20. Sampath PG. Designing national regimes that promote public health
`objectives Maastricht: UNUlINTECH; 2003.1NTECH Discussion Paper.
`21 . Drug patents under the spotlight sharing practical knowledge about
`pharmaceutical patents Geneva: Médecins Sans Frontiéres; 2003.
`22. Correa C. Trends in drug patenting. Buenos Aires: Corregidor; 2001.
`23. Hutchins M. Extending the monopoly: how ”secondary" patents can be
`used to delay or prevent generic competition upon expiry of the basic
`product patent. Journal of Generic Medicine 2003;1:57-71 .
`24. Seltzer J. Changes to aid generic drugmakers afoot in Congress Reuters, 30
`October 2003.
`25. Generic drug entry prior to patent expiration. Washington: Federal Trade
`Commission; 2002. Available from: htpp:llwww.ftc.gov
`
`Round Table Discussion
`
`Pharmaceutical R&D needs new financial
`
`paradigms
`John H. Barton1
`
`I endorse Professor Correa’s sound recommendations on patent
`law. The patent system is at its most successful when it covers a
`significant discrete product or process. It is at its least successful
`when it covers something much broader or much narrower.
`Patents on broad scientific principles are generally bad, because
`in the words of the United States Supreme Court, they “may
`confer power to block offwhole areas ofscientific development,
`without compensating benefit to the public” (I). At the other
`end of the continuum, patents on very minor improvements
`create a monopoly out ofproportion to the technological benefit
`of the improvement. Moreover, such parents may impose exten-
`sive and costly legal negotiations on those who wish to have the
`freedom to launch a new product. Thus, national patent oflices
`should apply appropriate doctrines ofutility or ofthe scope of
`patentable subject matter to avoid the problem of overly broad
`patents, and appropriate doctrines of inventive step to avoid
`the problem of overly incremental patents.
`I want to emphasize that the patent law provisions that
`Correa describes are only part of a much larger body of issues
`
`affecting the balance between drug development incentives and
`drug access. In the United States, the 1984 Waxman—Hatch
`Act explicitly extends a drug’s regulatory monopoly (with some
`very technical provisions that have been used to obtain longer
`exclusivity than was probably intended by Congress and have
`recently been revised). Relevant to middle—income countries
`with the ability to build a generic industry, the TRIPS Agree-
`ment and some other trade agreements restrict the right to use
`an original applicant’s clinical trial data to obtain approval for
`a generic product. Far more important, however, is the issue of
`cost. For the poor and those in poorer nations, access to drugs
`at even generic prices is inadequate, as shown by the estimate of
`WHO’s 3 by 5 initiative to make antiretroviral drugs available
`to 3 million people by 2005: at present only one person out
`of 15 people needing antiretrovirals in the developing world
`is actually receiving them. Solving the legal problems does not
`solve the more diflicult financial problems.
`Finally, the industry is facing an additional problem that
`Correa does not raise: the number of genuinely new pharma—
`ceutical products being approved is falling even as the level of
`research investment by the pharmaceutical industry is growing
`rapidly. The reasons are not clear. One may be a decline in
`basic scientific opportunities, at least for the kinds of disease
`that are of most economic interest to the industry. Others may
`include higher costs ofclinical trials or higher effective regula-
`tory standards. Encouragingly, the area where the number of
`new products is increasing is that in which products derive from
`biotechnology. This overall declining pay—OE ofresearch is very
`
`‘ Emeritus Professor, Stanford Law School, Crown Quad 237, Stanford University, Stanford, CA 94305-8610, USA (email: jbarton@stanford.edu).
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 4 of 7
`
`Mylan V. Sanofi - IPR2018-01676
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 4 of 7
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01676
`
`

`

`Special Theme — Bridging the Know—Do Gap in Global Health
`Round Table Discussion
`
`important, and the industry may have to find new research para—
`digms. This is a concern for the world as awhole. In addition, if
`the industryis to develop products especially for the developing
`world, it will need new financial paradigms as well. I
`
`Conflicts of interest: none declared.
`
`1. Brenner v. Manson, 383 US 519. United States Federal Supreme Court, 1966.
`
`Patents do not strangle innovation, but
`their quality must be improved
`AmirAttaran1
`
`everyone: competitors who must spend heavily to overturn
`wrongly granted patents; consumers who pay a premium while
`those patents remain in force; and even companies and their
`shareholders, as happened when an invalid Prozac patent was
`finally overturned, wiping US$ 35 billion offEli Lilly’s market
`capitalization (I).
`Ironically, among the least affected are the low— and
`rniddle—income countries. This is simply because the parenting
`of medicines there is rare — no more than a few percentage
`points for the WHO Model List ofEssmtial Medicine: (2). If
`Professor Correa is truly correct in the opinion that most new
`medicines “did not provide significant clinical improvement”,
`then even a major push to patent all new medicines in develop-
`ing countries would only modestly affect public health. There
`will always be a minority of cases where patents cause trouble
`— or maybe even harm — but as the hierarchy ofconcerns for
`developing countries goes, patents should not top the list. I
`
`Conflicts of interest: none declared.
`
`1. Maiello M. Prozac hangover. Forbes 10 May 2004.
`2. Attaran A. How do patents and economic policies affect access to essential
`medicines in developing countries? Health Affairs 2004;23:155-66.
`
`There is no doubt that the patenting of inventions — any
`inventions, not just medicines — is rising unprecedentedly.
`As Professor Correa writes, the resulting thicket of patents
`could “deprive society of the benefits [of]
`widespread use
`and dissemination of basic scientific ideas”.
`Possibilities and facts are not the same thing, however, and
`there is surprisingly little empirical data to show that the patent
`thicket is subtracting from the rate of innovation or society’s
`benefit from it. Maybe that is happening without anyone notic—
`ing, but the available evidence suggests otherwise.
`Correa cites extensively from the NIHCM analysis of
`new medicines, 1989—2000. As he correctly points out, only
`15% of the medicines approved in that period contained new
`active ingredients and were exceptionally medically useful.
`Fully 65% of medicines contained active ingredients that had
`Professor Correa alleges that “lax rules on patentability and
`been commercialized earlier, and 54% were “incrementally
`shortcomings in procedures” encourage non—inventive or
`modified drugs” that bear great resemblance to already existing
`medicines.
`“minor, incremental” drug developments and “strategic” pat—
`enting activities. He thus suggests that parents should not be
`But how do these statistics prove that innovation is being
`granted on medicines that “do not entail a genuine therapeutic
`strangled to death? In fact they prove just the opposite: that in—
`progress”. This is to misread the nature and value of pharma—
`novation is alive and well. Ifan inventor’s rational expectation
`ceutical innovation — as in all scientific sectors, the process is
`is that, more likely than not, the difference between the new
`one of evolution and reflects the principle that “Nature does
`medicine and those before it will not constitute a great leap,
`not make jumps”.a Correa’s policy prescription, based on an
`but only an “incremental” improvement, and the inventor still
`inaccurate diagnosis of the problem and a seriously flawed key
`ploughs money and time into its research and development,
`study, would lead to contradictory and anti—innovation results
`then innovation cerminly does not seem strangled. Actually, it
`for critically needed therapeutic innovation in major global
`seems irrepressible.
`disease threats.
`This is not to say that Correa’s hypothesis about patent
`Correa notes that public sector research provides irnpor—
`thickets harming pharmaceutical innovation is necessarily
`rant building blocks for private research and development, and
`wrong. Obviously, the more patents, the more inventors must
`that pharmaceutical companies invest “the largest part ofglobal
`spend on patent management, licensing and litigation. At some
`funds for pharmaceutical RécD”. In modern drug develop-
`point, the mounting costs must dissuade inventors with shal-
`ment, equipped with an armamentarium of scientific and
`low pockets more than those with deep ones, so that research
`technical skills, the private sector manages the discovery and
`and development accretes in major pharmaceutical companies,
`development processes in a competitive market that presents
`ahead of small biotechnology firms. The extent to which that
`high risks of failure. The United States National Institutes of
`accretion is happening, and if it leads to a net decrease in in-
`novation, is under-researched and not clearly known.
`Health (NIH) reported in 2001 that of the 47 prescription
`Correa is correct that the quality ofpatent mtarnination is
`drugs for which sales exceeded US$ 500 million per year, the
`scandalous. Even in Europe or North America, many dubious
`NIH had contributed to the discovery or development of only
`four (1).
`patents are issued. The resulting lack of legal certainty harms
`
`
`Pharmaceutical innovation is evolutionary
`and incentive-driven
`
`Harvey E. Bale2 81 Boris Azais3
`
`‘ Professor, Institute of Population Health and Faculty of Law, University of Ottawa, Canada. Address for correspondence: Royal Institute of International Affairs,
`Chatham House, 10 St James's Square, London SW1Y 4LE, England (email: aattaran@riia.org).
`2 Director General, International Federation of Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Associations (IFPMA), 30 rue de St Jean, PO Box 758, 1211 Geneva 18, Switzerland
`(email: h.bale@ifpma.org). Correspondence may be sent to either author.
`3 IFPMA Fellow from Merck & Co. Inc., International Federation of Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Associations (email: b.azais@ifpma.org).
`‘ See Geoffrey Fishburn. ’Natura non facitsaltum’in Charles Darwin andAlfred Marshall. Available from: http://www.qut.edu.a ularlehumanlethics/ieps/absfish.htm
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 5 of 7
`
`Mylan V. Sanofi - IPR2018-01676
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 5 of 7
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01676
`
`

`

`Special Theme — Bridging the Know-Do Gap in Global Health
`Round Table Discussion
`
`Incremental innovation responds to the needs ofbroader
`conditions of safety, eHicacy, selectivity, and utility — which
`translate into significantly better health outcomes (2). Indeed,
`50% ofthe drugs on the WHO Essential Drugs List are com—
`pounds introduced subsequent to the first in a therapeutic class,
`and 25% are approved (after additional clinical research) for
`therapeutic uses other than the initially approved indications,
`exemplifying that the future utility of medicines cannot be
`determined at the time of drug approval (3).
`Correa does not cite a single example of minor, incre-
`mental innovation undeserving of intellectual property in—
`centives. His critique of pharmaceutical innovation rests on
`a study by the National Institute for Health Care Management
`(NIHCM), an affiliate of the United States private health in-
`surance industry, which has serious gaps in its methodology.
`For example, the NIHCM excluded all FDA approvals of
`vaccines and other biological products from its calculations:
`as a result, over 130 vaccines and biotechnology products are
`simply omitted.a Further, the NIHCM analysis is based on the
`FDA’s priority review process, assuming that it translates into
`innovative products (versus those going through the standard
`review). Priority review is merely a managerial tool, which the
`FDA points out is “based on information available at the time
`application is filed [and] not intended to predict a drug’s ul—
`timate value” (4). The value of new medicines emerges most
`clearly once they have been introduced into medical practice.
`Finally, Correa’s proposal leads to the untenable situa—
`tion that improvements on existing therapies would not be
`patentable. Breakthrough innovations (patentable) would thus
`face immediate generic copies of similar but more advanced
`compounds (not patentable). Facing non-patentability or im-
`mediate generic copying, what ince

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket