throbber
‘THINKING
`ECONOMICALLY
`ABOUT
`COMMERCIAL
`UCCESS
`
`By R. DEFOREST MCDUFF,
`RYAN C. ANDREWS, AND MATT D. BRUNDAGE
`
`conomic experts frequently evaluate commercial success as a secondary consideration
`of the obviousnessof a patented invention.' While other common economicinquiries
`are often based on widely recognized methodologies (e.g., the Panduit factors for lost
`profits, the Georgia-Pacific factors for reasonableroyalties), experts often base analysis of com-
`mercial success on a layperson’s notion of“success,” without appreciation ofits purpose. For
`example, an expert may conclude that a productis a commercial success because sales andprofits
`are “large” or “substantial.” appealing to preconceived notions of success in other contexts (“sales
`of $100 million a year? .
`.
`. sounds like a success to me!”).
`We should be wary of such simplistic approaches to evaluating commercial success,
`which oftenfail to ask a fundamental economic question: success compared to what? Just
`as one individual’s success in life may differ from another’s, commercial success for one
`product in a particular context may differ from commercial success for another product in
`another context. Improperanalysis of commercial success can be particularly problematic in
`pharmaceuticals, for example, which often require billions ofdollars in sales for economic
`incentives to have existed for others to bring the product to market sooner. Evaluations of
`commercial success without proper context(or, for some experts, without any contextatall)
`are unhelpful to the role of commercial success in patent litigation.
`Recent case law hasclarified the purpose of commercial success and whatit is intended to
`demonstrate. For example, the Federal Circuit stated in Merck v. Teva that commercial suc-
`cessis relevant “because the law presumes an idea would successfully have been brought to
`market sooner, in response to market forces, had the idea been obvious to persons skilled in
`the art.’ This makes sense, from an economic perspective, because other parties would have
`economic incentives to commercialize obvious inventions if there were economic incentives
`to do so, However, based on our experience evaluating dozens of expert reports on com-
`mercial success, all too often experts fail to provide relevant context and/ortie any alleged
`success back to the fundamental purpose outlined by the courts.
`This article summarizes challenges and shortcomings with common approachesto evalu-
`ating commercial success, and offers guidance for providing appropriate economic analysis.
`We draw upon numerous expert evaluations of commercial success, with a focus in phar-
`maceuticals and electronics, to provide practical insights on commercial success for both
`plaintiffs and defendants,
`
`Mylan Ex.1084
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`March/April 2017 @ LANDSLIDE
`
`37
`
`Mylan Ex.1084
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`
`

`

`Overly Simplistic Analysis of Commercial Success
`Overly simplistic evaluations of commercial success frequently
`fail to provide sufficient information and analysis to conclude
`that economicincentives existed to bring the product to mar-
`ket sooner. Such analysis often simply tabulates sales, profits,
`and market shares, followed by some grand conclusion on
`whetherthose constitute commercial success. Very little is said
`for whethersales are sufficient to compensate for the economic
`costs needed to develop the product and bringit to market.
`Experts often fail to compare sales and profits from the product
`in question to other comparable products in the industry, even
`though millions of dollars in one market might be successful in
`one industry and an utter failure in another.
`In our experience, this kind of analysis is too often set
`forth as alleged evidence of commercial success. This overly
`simplistic approach to evaluating commercial success often
`misses the economic purpose of commercial success in
`informing on obviousness. Analyses rooted in a layperson’s
`notion of success are not necessarily unscientific or false—
`rather, they simply fail to connect with the purpose ofthe
`commercial success established by the courts.
`Overtime, courts have clarified the purpose of commer-
`cial success in evaluating a patent’s obviousness. Dating
`back to Smith v. Goodyear Dental (1876), the Supreme Court
`grappled with how to determine whether a new product was
`a legitimately novel invention.* The Court indicated what
`might be learned from one product displacing others previ-
`ously used for the same purpose, establishing the relevance
`of a product’s market performance, but provided noclear
`economic standard for what kind of displacement would be
`informative. The Supreme Courtlater identified commer-
`cial success as a secondary consideration for nonobviousness
`in Grahamy. John Deere (1966),° a role that was strength-
`ened upon establishment ofthe Federal Circuit in 1982.° One
`scholar suggested that commercial success was transformed
`“from a tiebreaker to a virtual trump card.” Most recently,
`the Federal Circuit stated in Merck v. Teva (2005) (citing to
`Graham v. John Deere) that “[c]ommercial success is relevant
`because the law presumes an idea would successfully have
`been brought to market sooner, in response to market forces,
`had the idea been obviousto personsskilled in the art."
`Merely reporting sales or market shares in a vacuum misses
`the point of a commercial success analysis as explained by the
`courts. Net sales or market sharesin isolation tell us very litle
`about whether market forces would have existed for other compa-
`nies to have responded by bringing the product to market sooner.
`As one author noted: “For commercial success to be persuasive,
`a patentee must do more than showsales or market share data for
`her patented product. (Although, under some oldercases, this was
`enough).”” Rather, commercial success should inform on whether
`
`sales and profits provide objective evidence on whether material
`economicincentives (i.e., “market forces’) would have incen-
`tivized others to bring the product to market, had the invention
`been obvious. Other economists and scholars agree that thisis. in
`essence, the fundamental purpose of commercial success analy-
`sis."” Said another way, ideas are brought to market whenthere is
`a profit opportunity, not merely when sales or market shares are
`“high” or“substantial” in some abstract sense.
`
`Economic Analysis of Commercial Success
`A better approach to evaluating commercial success focuses
`on factors that are economically relevant for its purpose. While
`each analysis will be unique and specific to the facts of the par-
`ticular case, some principles can provide guidance to improve
`putting forth or rebutting evidence of commercial success. This
`section elaborates on several such factors: (1) comparisons to
`relevant benchmarks, (2) comparisons to commercialization
`costs, (3) evaluation of market shares, and (4) evaluation ofthe
`inferential limitations of any alleged commercial success.
`
`Comparisons to Relevant Benchmarks
`One useful measure in evaluating commercial success is a
`comparisonof sales to relevant benchmarks in the industry—
`for example: average productsales, sales of competitors, and
`projections of potential sales. This provides guidance on what
`level of sales or revenues in the field are typical, sought, and
`expected, and would yield an economic profit for a particular
`industry at a particular pointin time.
`In the pharmaceutical industry, for example, economiclit-
`erature provides context on the range ofdrug sales by drug type
`(e.g., cardiovascular, neurologic, etc.) and time period. For drugs
`launched from 1990 to 1994, anesthetic drugs earned $556 mil-
`lion over the productlife cycle, on average, compared to more
`than $2 billion for anti-infective drugs and more than $3billion
`for cardiovascular drugs.'' Economic research examining drugs
`by decile (i.e., Ist decile from 90th percentile to 99th percentile,
`2nd decile from 80th percentile to 89th percentile) often pro-
`vides additional context for where a drug fits into the broader
`industry.'* Notably, research indicates that only the top three
`deciles of drugs tend to be economically profitable, and that an
`average drug tendsto yield close to break-even or even negative
`profits.All else equal, it is unlikely that a drug with sales below
`an average drug would be a commercial success."
`All too often, experts assert that sales are “high” in some
`abstract sense (even withlittle or no profit), without evaluat-
`ing what sales might have been expected or what sales have
`been earned by competitor products. By adding comparisons
`to the types of benchmarksdescribedherein, sales can be
`evaluated in proper context and better inform whether mate-
`rial economic incentives for development existed.
`
`R. DeForest McDuff, PhD,is a partner at Insight Economics; he is an expert in applied business economics and provides expert witness testimony on
`intellectual property and other areas. Ryan C.Andrewsis a former senior associate at Intensity; he has extensive experience evaluating lost profits,
`reasonable royalties, commercial success, and otherareas. He is currently pursuing his MBA atThe Wharton Schoolat the University of Pennsylvania.
`Matt D. Brundageis an analystat Intensity; his experience includes economic research and analysis for commercial success, reasonable royalties, and
`other economic damages.They may be reached,respectively, at deforest@insighteconomics.com, ryanandr@wharton.upenn.edu, and matt.brundage@
`ff BXHGRppspective
`intensity.com.The opinions expressed are those of the author(s) and may notreflect the viewsof their employersgi
`affiliates.This article is for general information purposes andis not intended to be and should notbe taken aslegal advice.
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`
`38
`
`LANDSLIDE ™ March/April 2017
`
`Mylan Ex.1084
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`
`

`

`Comparisons to Commercialization Costs
`Another useful but often overlooked measure in evaluating
`commercial success is a comparison to commercialization
`costs for a product. Properly evaluated, including economic
`costs associated with actual expenditures, costs of capital,
`risk, and uncertainties, comparisons to commercialization
`costs can provide information for whether sales andprofits
`are sufficient to generate an economic return on investment—
`in other words, a material economic incentive for others to
`bring the product to market. For example, some economists
`argue that “commercial success couldin principle be defined
`by a single criterion: Does the patented invention earn a
`positive net return (risk-adjusted) on invested capital after
`accounting forall relevant costs associated with developing
`and commercializing the patent as well as anyalternatives
`available to the patent holder?”!° Techniques suchas net pres-
`ent value analysis can be helpful for comparing sales over
`time with costs associated with commercialization.
`In the pharmaceutical industry, a numberof authors have
`determinedthat the cost of bringing a new pharmaceutical
`product to market exceeds $1 billion (and more than $2 bil-
`lion based on estimates for more recent products).'° These
`costs include out-of-pocket expenses of development and
`clinical trials, the cost of capital over time, and the risk
`of nonapproval (in which case all expenditures would be
`wasted), all of which are expected and considered when eval-
`uating products in the pharmaceutical industry.'’ If a drug
`product does not earn revenues and profits that sufficiently
`compensate pharmaceutical companies forsignificant eco-
`nomic costs in bringing a product to market, that product will
`tend not to be a commercial success,all else being equal."
`Despite the economic foundation and connection to material
`economic incentives, experts frequently fail to take into account
`the costs of development and commercialization whenevaluat-
`ing commercial success.’ By adding comparisonsto potential
`costs of commercialization describedherein, sales and profits
`can be evaluatedrelative to the expense and investment required
`to bring the product to market, providing further evidence on
`material economic incentives for commercialization.
`
`Evaluation of Market Shares
`Market shares are a factor frequently considered by experts in
`evaluating commercial success, because they provide implicit
`comparisons to competitor products. However, the interpre-
`tation of market shares can be difficult. For example, experts
`are often pressed at deposition to define what market share
`would provide a global cutoff for a commercially success-
`ful product(e.g., “Is it 5 percent? 10 percent? 25 percent? 50
`percent?”), The answer, because of how market shares are
`defined, is often: it depends.
`For example, a 5 percent share of one market might be com-
`mercially successful, whereas a 20 percent share of another
`market might not be. The former market might be significant
`and commercialization costs may be low, whereas the second
`market might be smaller and commercialization costs may be
`high. As another example, a product may have a very high rev-
`enue share but a very low quantity share due tofactors like
`patent protection of competitors (e.g., branded versus generic
`
`pharmaceuticals). Trying to define an absolute cutoff for what
`market share, in the abstract, denotes a commercial successis
`a futile exercise.” Experts often disagree about market defi-
`nition—i.e., which products define competition and which do
`not—yet the marketdefinition and market share are interre-
`lated. It is the overall context, rather than a particular market
`share per se, that defines whether market shares are interpreted
`as persuasive evidence of commercial success.
`Unlike the other economic factors described thus far, market
`shares are less directly connected to whether material economic
`incentives existed to bring the product to market sooner. Yet they
`can, at times, provide insight on the market opportunity for an
`invention and, in that sense, may informon incentivesto bring a
`product to market sooner whenotherinformationis less concrete.
`
`Economic Relevance of Commercial Success
`Finally, a thoughtful analysis of commercial success may
`consider whetherany alleged success,if it exists, is relevant
`for evaluating the existence of material economic incentives
`to bring a product to market sooner. There are circumstances
`
`where evensales and profits that might artes be sufficient
`commercial opportunity) might not be informative on obvi-
`
`to generate economicinterest in the product (e.g., a potential
`
`ousness at the time of the invention because ofotherfactors.
`For example, the presence of blocking patents or regu-
`latory exclusivity often limits the economic relevance of
`commercial success. Inthis case, incentives for development
`may only exist for the party with that exclusivity and not
`for the market more generally. In Merck v. Teva, the plaintiff
`argued that Fosamax, the patented product in question, was
`commercially successful.?! The Federal Circuit agreed, but
`found that Merck’s earlier patent (a so-called “blocking pat-
`ent” that blocked others from commercializing a Fosamax
`product) limited the economic relevance of commercial suc-
`cess because otherparties in the market could be blocked
`frombringing the product to market.*’ The court stated:
`“Because market entry by others was precluded on those
`bases, the inference of non-obviousness .. . from evidence of
`commercial success, is weak.”
`As another example, there may be contemporaneousevi-
`dence aroundthe time of the invention that showsa lack of
`commercial interest, even if the product later turns out to be
`commercially successful. In such a situation, sales and profits
`may provide limited evidence on whether material economic
`incentives existed to bring the product to market sooner,
`above and beyond the contemporaneous evidence already
`demonstrating this directly.
`In summary, experts can often benefit from asking whether
`commercial success, even ifit exists, is relevant in evaluating
`the existence of material economic incentives aroundthe time
`of the invention and, in turn, in evaluating obviousness of a
`particular patent at issue.
`
`Conclusion
`While the purpose of commercial success has been established
`for some time, too often we see basic principles being misap-
`plied, misunderstood, or not ackmyAytaer Bx] BB4ating
`“success” in a vacuum, without prea SOTS9benchmarks
`Mylanv. Sanofi - IPR2018-
`March/April 2017 ™@ LANDSLIDE
`
`39
`
`Mylan Ex.1084
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`
`

`

`for comparison, can result in a flawed and misguided analysis.
`There is, of course, no single set of factors that are disposi-
`tive on commercial success in every situation, but providing
`additional context relating to the purpose of commercial suc-
`cess (1.e., whether sales and profits demonstrate material
`economic incentives existed to have brought the product to
`market sooner) appears to be a step in the right direction. Suc-
`cess, both in business andin life, requires an understanding and
`appreciation for what is meant to be achieved. m
`
`Endnotes
`
`1. Commercial success is one of several secondary consider-
`ations intended to inform on whethera particular technologyis
`obvious—i.e., whetherit differs enough frompriorart in order to
`qualify as a patentable invention—whichare often evaluated when
`defendants challenge a patent’s validity in patent litigation. Because
`obviousness is the most commonbasis forfinding that a pat-
`ent is invalid, commercial success can play an important role. For
`discussion and references, see AndrewBlair-Stanek, Profits as Com-
`mercial Success, 117 YALEL.J. 642, 646 (2008); and RebeccaS.
`Eisenberg, Obvious to Whom? Evaluating Inventions fromthe Per-
`spective of PHOSITA, 19 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 885, 885 (2004).
`2. Merck & Co. v. Teva Pharm. USA, Inc., 395 F.3d 1364, 1376
`(Fed. Cir. 2005).
`3. Smith v. Goodyear Dental Vulcanite Co., 93 U.S. 486, 495 (1876).
`4, Id. at 495-96,cited in Blair-Stanek, supra note 1, at 647,
`5. Graham y. John Deere Co., 383 U.S. 1, 17-18 (1966) (“Such
`secondary considerations as commercial success, long felt but
`unsolved needs, failure of others, etc., might be utilized to give light
`to the circumstances surrounding the origin of the subject matter
`soughtto be patented. As indicia of obviousness or nonobviousness,
`these inquiries may have relevancy.”).
`6, Blair-Stanek, supra note |, at 647-48; see Graham, 383 U.S, at 11.
`7. Robert P. Merges, Commercial Success and Patent Standards:
`EconomicPerspectives on Innovation, 76 CAL. L. REV, 803, 827 (1988).
`8. Merck & Co. v. Teva Pharm. USA,Inc., 395 F.3d 1364, 1376
`(Fed. Cir. 2005).
`9. Merges, supra note 7, at 823.
`10. Jesse David & Marion B. Stewart, Commercial Success: Eco-
`
`nomic Principles Applied to Patent Litigation, in ECONOMIC APPROACHES
`TO INTELLECTUAL PRopPERTY: PoLicy, LITIGATION, AND MANAGEMENT
`
`196-99 (Gregory K. Leonard & LaurenJ. Stiroh eds., 2005) (“A patented
`invention should be considered a commercial successifit can be shown
`
`to have earned, or can reasonably be expected to earn, a positive net return
`oninvested capital after accounting forall relevant costs associated with
`development and commercialization .
`.
`. °°); Blair-Stanek, supranote |, at
`649 (“The potential for commercial success presumably provides incen-
`tives for others to try to perfect the invention, and the failure of others to
`do so suggests nonobviousness. Put most simply, the classical theory-
`based argument goes,‘if an invention is both obvious and lucrative, why
`wasn’t it thought ofearlier?’”’); Rahul Guhaetal., The Economics of
`Commercial Success in Pharmaceutical Patent Litigation, | LANDSLIDE,
`no. 5, May/June 2009, at 8 (“From an economic perspective, commercial
`success supports a conclusion of nonobviousness becauseit suggests that
`an economicincentive existed to produce the invention.”).
`1. Joseph DiMasiet al., R&D Costs and Returns by Therapeutic
`Category, 38 DruG INFo. J. 211, 219 (2004).
`
`12. Henry Grabowskietal., Retns on Research and Develop-
`ment for 1990s New Drug Introductions, 20 PHARMACOECONOMICS
`11, 17, 22 (Supp. 3 2002).
`13. Id. at 17, 23; Ernst R. Berndt et al., Decline in Economic
`Returns from New Drugs Raises Questions about Sustaining Innova-
`tions, 34 HEALTH AFF. 245, 245, 252 (2015).
`14. Skeptics might question why so many unprofitable drugs are
`brought to market. Reasons mayvary, of course, but one impactful
`factoris the uncertain processofclinical trials and FDA approval
`occurring over many years. Once a company incurs sunk costs of
`developmentand clinicaltrials, it may be worthwhile to proceed to
`the market, even if the product never recoupsall of those sunk costs.
`15. David & Stewart, supra note 10, at 196.
`16. For sources and discussion, see Joseph DiMasietal., Jnnova-
`tion in the Pharmaceutical Industry: New Estimates ofR&D Costs,
`47 J. HEALTH Econ. 20 (2016). For a variety of other sources and ref-
`erences over time, see JORGE MESTRE-FERRANDIZ ET AL., OFFICE OF
`
`HEALTH Econ., THE R&D Cost oF A NEW MEDICINE I-86 (2012);
`Joseph A. DiMasi & Henry G. Grabowski, R&D Costs and Returnsto
`New Drug Development: A Reviewof the Evidence, in THE OXFORD
`HANDBOOK OF THE ECONOMICS OF THE BIOPHARMACEUTICAL INDUS-
`
`TRY 29 (Patricia M. Danzon & Sean Nicholson eds., 2010); Joseph A.
`DiMasi et al., The Price ofInnovation: NewEstimates of Drug Devel-
`opment Costs, 22 J. HEALTH Econ. 151, 151 (2003); Joseph A.
`DiMasi & Henry G. Grabowski, The Cost of Biopharmaceutical
`R&D;Is Biotech Different?, 28 MANAGERIAL & DECISION Econ, 469,
`477 (2007); and Grabowski et al., supra note 12.
`17. See MESTRE-FERRANDIZ ETAL., supra note 16; DiMasiet al.,
`Innovation in the Pharmaceutical Industry, supra note 16; DiMasietal.,
`The Price ofInnevation, supra note 16; Grabowski et al., supra note 12.
`18. Interestingly, some authors have argued that pharmaceuti-
`cal products may be commercially successful even whenthey do
`not generate a positive return on investment, because there maystill
`be some therapeutic value associated with their use. See, e.g., Guha
`et al., supra note 10, at 11-12 n.10 (“[A] lack ofpositive return on
`capital investment should not necessarily undermine a conclusion of
`commercial success. A few ‘blockbuster’ drugs generate the major-
`ity ofprofits for the drug companies. That means the majority of
`smaller drugs may not be profitable in the sense of recouping all the
`costs of their discovery and development, evenif they have proven
`therapeutic value.”). However, products may be therapeutically
`valuable or desirable without being commercially successful and
`sufficient to provide incentives to bring products to market sooner.
`19. While the costs of commercialization are often not available
`
`in historical records, either due to the passage of time or non-
`specific attribution ofcosts to a particular product, we have had
`success linking the facts and circumstancesof a particular product
`to peer-reviewed published literature on commercialization costs,
`accounting for time oflaunch, therapeutic category, and the actual
`duration of clinical costs.
`
`20. See, e.g., David & Stewart, supra note 10, at 196 (“However,
`undercertain circumstances, rapid sales growth and gains in market
`share will not necessarilyreflect a profitable underlying invention.”).
`21. Merck & Co. v. Teva Pharm. USA, Inc., 395 F.3d 1364, 1376
`(Fed. Cir. 2005).
`22, Id. at 1376-77.
`23. Id. at 1377.
`
`Mylan Ex.1084
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`
`40
`
`LANDSLIDE ® March/April 2017
`
`Mylan Ex.1084
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`
`

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket