throbber
Ownership of knowledge — therole of patentsin
`pharmaceutical R&D
`Carlos Maria Correa!
`
`Abstract Both the public and the private sectors contribute to research and development(R&D)in pharmaceuticals. The public sector
`originates many of the discoveries of new drugs. The private sector, which focuses on development, is heavily reliant on patents.
`Though patents are presumed to reward genuine inventions, lax rules on patentability and shortcomings in procedures permit
`protection to be obtained on a myriad of minor developments. These patents, though weak and possibly invalid in many cases, are
`used to restrain competition and delay the entry of generic competition. Developing countries should design and implementtheir
`patent lawsso as to preventstrategic patenting and promote competition and access to medicines.
`
`KeywordsPatents/legislation; Pharmaceutical preparations; Research; Diffusion of innovation; Drug industry (source: MeSH, NLM).
`Motsclés Brevet/législation; Préparations pharmaceutiques; Recherche;Diffusion des innovations; Industrie pharmaceutique (source:
`MeSH, INSERM).
`Palabras clave Patentes/legislacién; Preparaciones farmacéuticas; Investigacion; Difusion de innovacidn; Industria farmacéutica
`(fuente: DeCS, BIREME).
`SS RN OE32$8) indy shady Bydoles COLIlard Opel Hsp) oleral teLEN) lly ae olyAo heblll CLI
`eaSS gli
`
`Bulletin of the World Health Organization 2004;82:784-790.
`
`Voir page 786le résumé en francais. En la pagina 786 figura un resumen en espafiol.
`
`786 todue § dyply jasdli do ON ow
`
`immunodeficiency syndrome (HIV/AIDS). Publicly funded
`Although governments are responsible fora significant portion
`genomeresearchhas also produced manydrugleads (4). In the
`ofglobal spending onresearch and development (R&D), since
`United States, the federally funded biomedical research sup-
`the 1980sa steep decline in the share of governmentfunds for
`ported by the National Institutes ofHealth (NIH)playsavital
`R&Dis a trend commontoall major industrialized countries
`and many other Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
`role in new drug development,feeding into the R&Dactivities
`of the private pharmaceutical industry that operates under
`Development (OECD)countries. In the largest OECD coun-
`tries (with the exception ofItaly), the private sector performed.
`patentprotection (2). In addition to this direct and important
`between 62% and 70% oftotal national R&D (1).
`contribution, governments ofmany developed countries grant
`tax credits and other incentives for R&cD (J).
`Private and public sources also coexist in pharmaceutical
`R&D.Thedivision oflabour in pharmaceutical R&D between
`However, private industry invests the largest part of
`the two sectorsis related,at least in principle, to the nature of
`global funds for pharmaceutical R&cD. Unlike the public sec-
`the knowledge thatis fostered (2). In mostcases, the discovery
`tor, industry's research agenda is dominated by profit-making
`of important new drugs is made by public institutions, which
`objectives. Most of industry's resources are concentrated on
`later license their development and exploitation to private
`applied R8cD,though funds are also devoted to basic research.
`firms. Some 70% ofdrugs with therapeutic gain were produced
`In 1999,for instance, 24.5% of R&D spending was on basic
`with governmentinvolvement(3). Basic research thatled to the
`research in the United Kingdom, 36% in the United States, and
`18.4% in Canada (5).
`discovery ofpotential “drug leads” has almost always been pub-
`licly funded at universities, in-house governmentfacilities, or
`Given the objectives and nature of industry's activities,
`research institutes in Europe, North America, and Japan. Since
`they rely heavily on the acquisition and enforcementofpatents
`the beginning ofthe 20th century, publicly funded research has
`worldwide. A commonbelief is that patents are normally ac-
`led to major drug lead discoveries in, for example, tuberculosis,
`quired to protect mew drugs, and thereby recover the substantial
`other infectious diseases and cancer. Morerecently, publicly
`R&Dinvestments made for increasing the range of available
`funded research has led to the discovery of antiretrovirals for
`therapies; but the number of patents annually obtained to
`the treatment of human immunodeficiency virus/acquired.
`protect genuinely new pharmaceutical products is very small
`
`" Director, Centre of Interdisciplinary Studies of Industrial and Economic Law, University of BuenosAires, Av. Figueroa Alcorta 2263, 1st floor, 1425 BuenosAires,
`Argentina (email: ceidie@derecho.uba.ar).
`Ref. No. 03-010801
`(Submitted: 18 December 2003 — Final revised version received: 23 June 2004 — Accepted: 24 June 2004)
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 1 of 7
`Mylanv. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 1 of 7
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`
`

`

`Carlos Maria Correa
`
`Special Theme — Bridging the Know—Do Gapin Global Health
`Patents in pharmaceutical R&D
`
`Patenting cumulative innovations
`and declining, whereas thousands of patents are applied for
`or granted concerning pharmaceutical-related inventions. The
`The cumulative nature of innovation has importantrepercus-
`numberofpatents acquired in relation to “upstream” inven-
`sions on the patent system. Though theoretically conceived to
`tions, thatis, scientific discoveries rather than specific technical
`reward inventions marked by considerable originality, the patent
`solutions, is increasing. This kind of patenting detracts from
`system is plagued with grants covering incremental, minor — in
`public domain knowledge that could be used “downstream” by
`somecases trivial — developments. They are not the product
`manyresearchersto explore multiple inventive opportunities;
`ofinventive efforts, but rather the outcomeof “taking a speedy
`it deprives society of the benefits that the widespread use and
`path downatrail that was obvious to many”(8, p. 128). In
`dissemination ofbasic scientific ideas could generate (2). The
`2001, the United States Patent and Trademark Office granted
`problemsraised by this form of privatization of science have
`over 171 000 patents, almost twice the number granted ten
`been explored by an extensiveliterature (6, 7). Patents, on the
`years earlier, This increase cannot simply be attributed to an
`other hand,are ordinarily acquired for a myriad offollow-on,
`increase in R&D productivity, but to the flexibility of the
`merely incremental, or minor developments.
`patent system to permit the protection offollow-on and other
`developments(13, pp. 1933-4).
`Moreover, there is increasing evidence about poor pat-
`ent quality. (A poor-quality patentis one thatis likely to be
`invalid or contains claims thatare likely to be overly broad
`(14).) “Non-obviousness” or “inventive step” (one of the key
`patentability requirements) is assessed against a standard that
`many follow-on and routine innovations donotfind difficult
`to meet, based on thefiction ofwhat“a person with ordinary
`skill in the art” would have been able to derive from priorart.
`Weaknesses in patent procedures, in addition, favour the grant-
`ing of patents over trivial or minor developments (14, 15),
`despite the significant resources invested in developed countries
`to fund patentoffices (6).
`Large firms have rapidly learned how to exploit lax
`patentability standards and the shortcomings in the patent
`examination process. They apply different strategies to use
`patents offensively as means to encumberor block potential
`competitors. Thus, “blanketing”strategies aim at mining every
`step in a manufacturing process with patents claiming minor
`modifications; “fencing” refers to a situation where a series of
`patents blocks certain lines or directions ofR&cD; “surrounding”
`takes place “when an important central patent can be fenced
`in or surrounded by otherpatents, which are individually less
`importantbutcollectively block the effective commercial use of
`the central patent, even after its expiration” (17); and “flooding”
`is based on the acquisition of many patents on minoror incre-
`mental variations on technology developed by another com-
`pany (18, 19). For other anti-competitive practices, see (20).
`As noted by the NIHCM,“drug manufacturers patent a
`widerange ofinventions connected with incremental modifica-
`tions of their products, including minorfeatures such as inert
`ingredients and the form,color, and scoring oftablets. In many
`cases, these patents discourage generic companies from trying
`to develop a competitive product” (12). Moreover, backed by
`substantial budgets for patent acquisition andlitigation, phar-
`maceutical companies have been able to delay substantially the
`entry ofgeneric competition by “evergreening” manyoftheir
`patents (2/—23). According to United States lawmaker Waxman
`(oneof the authorsof the United States Drug Price Competi-
`tion and Patent Restoration Act of 1984, commonly known
`as the “Waxman—Hatch Act”) brand-name companies “have
`used creative lawyering to try and extendthe period oftheir
`monopolies long past the time intended by Congress” (24).
`Poor-quality patents acquired to encumberordelay ge-
`neric competition are generally aggressively used against com-
`petitors. They arelikely to be invalidated totally or partially,
`however,ifsubject to a moreserious scrutiny by judicial courts
`
`Innovation in pharmaceuticals
`Innovation in pharmaceuticals relies increasingly on the knowl-
`edge gleaned from preceding innovations and on generally
`available techniques (8, 9). As in other sectors, innovation “has
`shifted away from models based on absolute novelty andfirst
`improvement towards a model in which innovation is no lon-
`ger driven by technological breakthroughs but by the routine
`exploitation ofexisting technologies” (70). Innovationin this
`sector follows, therefore, an essentially “cumulative” model of
`innovation, as opposed to the “discrete” model, where the pros-
`pects ofvariations and improvements ofinventions are substan-
`tially bounded.
`Manyof the new chemical entities of pharmaceutical
`use do notentail a genuine therapeutic progress; they are “me
`too” drugs, developed as a result of the great deal of emula-
`tion of successful drugs undertaken byrival companies (J 2).
`Pharmaceutical innovation also includes a large number of
`improvements or minor changes to existing drugs, and the
`identification of new uses of known products. Incremental in-
`novation is often motivated by the objective of extending the
`commercial benefits derived from existing products, particu-
`larly when original patents expire and new patents maybe used
`to prolong market exclusivity.
`Accordingto a report ofthe National Institute for Health
`Care Management (NIHCM) in the UnitedStates, from 1989
`to 2000 the United States Food and Drug Administration
`(FDA)approved 1035 new drugapplications. Ofthese, a third
`(35%)were products with new active ingredients, or new mo-
`lecular entities (NMEs). The other 65% used active ingredients
`that were already available in a marketed product. Overhalf
`(54%) were incrementally modified drugs, or new versions of
`medicines whose active ingredients were already available in an
`approved product. The rest (11%) contained the sameactive
`ingredient as identical marketed products (12).
`Priority NMEs, the most innovative type of new drugs,
`wererare in the 12-year period 1989—2000:just 153 (15%) of
`all new drug approvals were medicines that used new active in-
`gredients and provided significantclinical improvement. Drugs
`providing moderate innovation comprised another 28% of
`approvals. The other 57% ofapprovals were for drugs showing
`only modest innovation,at best: 46% made some modification
`to an older product containing the same active ingredient,
`while the remaining 11% wereidentical to marketed products.
`Asa result, the NIHCMreports, priority NMEs — the most
`innovative drugs — contributedlittle to the increase in new
`products, and most growth came from products that did not
`provide significantclinical improvement, especially modified
`versions ofolder drugs (12).
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 2 of 7
`Mylanv. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 2 of 7
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`
`

`

`Special Theme — Bridging the Know—DoGapin Global Health
`Patents in pharmaceutical R&D
`
`Carlos Marfa Correa
`
`than the examination made at the patent office, as shown ina
`study by the United States Federal Trade Commission on drug
`entry and patent expiration (25).
`
`Conclusions
`
`Patents have becomea key factor in the R&¢Dprocess in phar-
`maceuticals. Although, in certain contexts, they provide the
`incentives to develop new pharmaceutical products from which
`society may benefit, by their very nature they limit the diffusion
`of the innovations that they are intended to promote. When
`the innovation process is cumulative, strong protection for the
`first-generation producerlimits the scope ofsecond-generation
`producers, and slows down follow-on innovation.
`Patents often establish barriers to entry that are unjusti-
`fied in terms of the technical contribution effectively made.
`Lowstandards ofpatentability have allowed a significant expan-
`
`sion of patent coverage. Strategic patenting diverts resources
`intolitigation and restrains legitimate competition. While this
`is taking place in both developed and developing countries
`alike, it is particularly worryingin the latter since competition
`laws are in many cases non-existent or poorly implemented,
`and domestic firms are generally too small to bear the costs and
`risks oflitigation. Developing countries have struggled in the
`past few yeats to confirm their rights to use the flexibilities
`allowed by the Agreementon Trade-related Aspects ofIntellec-
`tual Property Rights (TRIPS), particularly in relation to parallel
`imports and compulsory licences.” Without abandoning these
`efforts, they should pay more attention to the way in which
`patents are examined and granted, in order to avoid abuses
`and the negative effects on access to medicines that patents on
`noninventive developments entail. I
`
`Conflicts of interest: none declared.
`
`Résumé
`
`Propriété intellectuelle - Le réle des brevets dans la R & D en pharmacie
`Le secteur privé, comme le secteur publique, contribuent aux
`progrés mineurs. Ces brevets, quoique faibles et éventuellement
`activités de recherche et développement (R & D) dansle domaine
`invalides dans de nombreux cas, sont utilisés pour restreindre la
`pharmaceutique, Le secteur public est a l'origine de la découverte
`concurrence et retarder I'entrée en compétition des génériques.
`d'un grand nombre de nouveaux médicaments. Le secteurprivé, qui
`ll convient que les pays en développement concoivent et mettent
`axesesefforts sur le développement, dépend fortementdesbrevets.
`en ceuvreleur législation sur les brevets de maniére a prévenirla
`Bien que ceux-ci soient supposés récompenser de véritables
`prise de brevets stratégique et a promouvoir la concurrence et
`I'accés aux médicaments.
`inventions,le laxisme deslois sur la brevetabilité et les défauts de
`procédure permettent d’obtenir la protection d'une multitude de
`
`Resumen
`
`Propiedad de los conocimientos- Funcién de las patentes en la 1+D farmacéutica
`desarrollos de poca importancia. Estas patentes, aunque poco
`Tanto el sector pUblico comoel sector privado contribuyen a la
`investigaciony el desarrollo (I+-D) de preparaciones farmacéuticas.
`consistentes y posiblemente carentes de validez en muchoscasos,
`Muchosdelos descubrimientos de medicamentos nuevostienen
`se usan para restringir la competencia y retrasarla introduccién de
`lugar en el sector publico. El sector privado, que se centra en el
`medicamentos genéricos. Los paises en desarrollo deben disefiar
`desarrollo, depende en gran medida de las patentes. Aunque se
`y aplicar sus leyes en la materia de manera que prevengan las
`supone que éstas recompensanauténticasinvenciones,la laxitud
`patentes estratégicas y promuevan la competencia y el acceso a
`los medicamentos,
`de las
`_normas acerca de la patentabilidad y los fallos de los
`procedimientos permiten obtener proteccién para innumerables
`
`ars
`ANpAStpoemyay Segt BogeeStelyy99 1Bylall Soka!
`Spel pay Se Selly old! lela) waLL soll
`3 beseDe pe Jel cielSh ode Gime or obJy Alas ale
`dye wll, ill oA pedal peltetend WY wey opt deel
`¢laa ul, Beeb! 3 oe tall Send ela Naa Lal 5hyal
`al) Glali le ee a cfg AeSLA Gale at! yo)
`ley le Nn S lalacel dead cygel de aalacal Sy coll ¢ elt
`lelVY lel dl aa YE ead of oe pdb ogeM
`a wollos es cele’ ely oe. Adler) Golk! Lguilgs Aady altel
`le Spall Goky allah pialy gonad ulate cell
`gpa eo ghy cote Sl pee, aleESA pb dela of YI teat!
`:
`449M
`whe gl pley obl, bbs Sl abdh acadl Obes colle!
`
`4 See World Health Assembly Resolution WHA56.27 (2003) which recommends MemberStates “to useto thefull theflexibilities” contained in the TRIPS Agreement.
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 3 of 7
`Mylanv. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 3 of 7
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`
`

`

`Carlos Maria Correa
`
`Special Theme — Bridging the Know—Do Gapin Global Health
`Patents in pharmaceutical R&D
`
`13. Barton J. Reforming the patent system. Science 2000;287:1933-4.
`14. To promote innovation: the proper balance of competition and patent law
`and policy. Washington (DC): Federal Trade Commission; 2003.Available
`from: htpp:/Awww.ftc.gov
`15. Keeping science open:the effects ofintellectual property policy on the
`conduct ofscience, London: The Royal Society; 2003.Policy document 02/03.
`16. Intellectual property: information on the US Patent and Trademark Office’s
`past and future operations. Washington (DC): General Accounting Office;
`2002. Report to Congressional Requesters.
`17. Granstrand 0. The economics and managementofintellectual property.
`Towards intellectual capitalism. Northampton: Edward Elgar; 1996.
`18. Sankaran SK,Patent flooding in the United States and Japan. The Journal of
`LawandTechnology 2000; 1:393-428.
`19. Glasgow L. Stretching the limitsof intellectual propertyrights: has the
`pharmaceutical industry gone too far? The Journal of Law and Technology
`2001;2:227-58.
`20. Sampath PG. Designing national regimes that promote public health
`objectives, Maastricht: UNU/INTECH; 2003. INTECH Discussion Paper.
`2
`. Drug patents underthe spotlight sharing practical knowledge about
`pharmaceutical patents. Geneva: Médecins Sans Frontiéres; 2003.
`22. Correa C. frends in drug patenting. BuenosAires: Corregidor; 2001.
`23. Hutchins M. Extending the monopoly: how “secondary” patents can be
`used to delay or prevent generic competition upon expiry of the basic
`product patent. Journal of Generic Medicine 2003;1:57-71.
`24, Seltzer J. Changes to aid generic drugmakers afootin Congress. Reuters, 30
`October 2003.
`25. Generic drug entry prior to patent expiration. Washington: FederalTrade
`Commission; 2002. Available from: htpp://www.ftc.gov
`
`References
`. National Science Board. Science and engineering indicators 2002. Arlington
`(VA): National Science Foundation; 2002.
`. Macroeconomics and health: investing in health for economic development.
`Report of the Commission on Macroeconomics and Health. Geneva: World
`Health Organization; 2001. Available from: htpp:/Awww.who.int
`. United Nations Development Programme. Human developmentreport. New
`York: Oxford University Press; 1999,
`. Fatal imbalance. Thecrisis in research and developmentfordrugs for
`neglected diseases, Geneva: Médecins Sans Fronti@res; 2001.
`. A comparison ofpharmaceutical research and developmentspending in
`Canada and selected countries. Ottawa: Patented Medicine Prices Review
`Board; 2002.
`. Barton JH. Research-toolpatents:issues for health in the developing world.
`Bulletin of the World Health Organization 2002;80:121-5.
`. Eisenberg RS. Bargaining overthe transfer of proprietary research tools:is
`this marketfailing or emerging? In: Dreyfuss R, ZimmermanD,First H,
`editors. Expanding the boundariesofintellectual property. Oxford: Oxford
`University Press; 2001.
`. MergesR, Nelson R. Onlimiting or encouragingrivalry in technical progress:
`the effect of patent-scope decisions.In: Nelson R, editor. The sources of
`economic growth. Cambridge and London: Harvard University Press; 1996.
`. Long C. Patents and cumulative innovation. Washington University Journal
`of Law andPolicy 2000;2:229-46.
`10. Foray D. Production and distribution of knowledgein the new systemsof
`innovation:the role ofintellectual property rights. Science, Technology
`Industry Review 1992;16:119-52.
`11. Casadio Tarabusi C, Vickery G. Globalization in the pharmaceutical industry.
`International Journal of Health Services 1998;1:67-105.
`12. NationalInstitute for Health Care Management. Changing patterns of
`pharmaceutical innovation. Washington (DC): NIHCM Foundation; 2002.
`Available from: http:/Awww.nihcm.org
`
`oo
`
`wo
`
`nN
`
`w > w
`
`i a ~
`
`RoundTable Discussion
`
`Pharmaceutical R&D needs new financial
`paradigms
`John H. Barton’
`
`I endorse Professor Cortea’s sound recommendations on patent
`law. The patent system is at its most successful whenit covers a
`significantdiscrete product or process. It is at its least successful
`when it covers something much broader or much narrower.
`Patents on broad scientific principles are generally bad, because
`in the words of the United States Supreme Court, they “may
`confer power to block offwhole areas ofscientific development,
`without compensating benefit to the public”(1). At the other
`end of the continuum,patents on very minor improvements
`create a monopolyoutofproportion to the technological benefit
`of the improvement. Moreover, such patents may impose exten-
`sive and costly legal negotiations on those whowish to have the
`freedom to launch a new product. Thus, national patentoffices
`should apply appropriate doctrines ofutility or ofthe scope of
`patentable subject matter to avoid the problem ofoverly broad.
`patents, and appropriate doctrines of inventive step to avoid
`the problem ofoverly incremental patents.
`I want to emphasize that the patent law provisions that
`Correa describes are only part of a much larger body ofissues
`
`affecting the balance between drug developmentincentives and
`drug access. In the United States, the 1984 Waxman-—Hatch
`Act explicitly extends a drug’s regulatory monopoly (with some
`very technical provisions that have been used to obtain longer
`exclusivity than was probably intended by Congress and have
`recently been revised). Relevant to middle-income countries
`with the ability to build a generic industry, the TRIPS Agree-
`mentand some othertrade agreementsrestrict the right to use
`an original applicant's clinical trial data to obtain approval for
`a generic product. Far more important, however,is the issue of
`cost. For the poor and those in poorer nations, access to drugs
`at even generic prices is inadequate, as shown by the estimate of
`WHO's 3 by5 initiative to make antiretroviral drugs available
`to 3 million people by 2005: at present only one person out
`of 15 people needing antiretrovirals in the developing world
`is actually receiving them. Solving thelegal problemsdoes not
`solve the more difficult financial problems.
`Finally, the industry is facing an additional problem that
`Correa does notraise: the numberof genuinely new pharma-
`ceutical products being approvedisfalling even as the level of
`research investment by the pharmaceutical industry is growing
`rapidly. The reasons are not clear. One may be a decline in
`basic scientific opportunities, at least for the kinds of disease
`that are of most economicinterest to the industry. Others may
`include highercosts ofclinical trials or higher effective regula-
`tory standards. Encouragingly, the area where the number of
`new products is increasing is that in which products derive from
`biotechnology. This overall declining pay-off ofresearch is very
`
`1 Emeritus Professor, Stanford Law School, Crown Quad 237, Stanford University, Stanford, CA 94305-8610, USA (email: jbarton@stanford.edu).
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 4 of 7
`Mylanv. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 4 of 7
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`
`

`

`Special Theme — Bridging the Know—DoGapin Global Health
`RoundTable Discussion
`
`important, and the industry may have to find new research para-
`digms. This is a concernfor the world as a whole. In addition,if
`the industry is to develop products especially for the developing
`world,it will need new financial paradigmsas well.
`
`Conflicts of interest: none declared.
`
`1. Brenner v. Manson, 383 US 519. United States Federal Supreme Court, 1966.
`
`Patents do not strangle innovation, but
`their quality must be improved
`Amir Attaran'
`
`everyone: competitors who must spend heavily to overturn
`wrongly granted patents; consumers who pay a premium while
`those patents remain in force; and even companies and their
`shareholders, as happened whenan invalid Prozac patent was
`finally overturned, wiping US$ 35billion offEli Lilly's market
`capitalization (7).
`Ironically, among the least affected are the low- and
`middle-income countries. This is simply because the patenting
`of medicines there is rare — no more than a few percentage
`points for the WHO Model List ofEssential Medicines (2). If
`Professor Correais truly correct in the opinion that most new
`medicines “did not provide significantclinical improvement”,
`then even a majorpush co patentall new medicines in develop-
`ing countries would only modestly affect public health. There
`will always be a minority of cases where patents cause trouble
`— or maybe even harm — but as the hierarchy ofconcernsfor
`developing countries goes, patents should nottop thelist.
`
`Conflicts of interest: none declared.
`
`1. Maiello M. Prozac hangover. Forbes 10 May 2004.
`2. Attaran A. How do patents and economic policies affect access to essential
`Medicinesin developing countries? Health Affairs 2004;23: 155-66.
`
`Pharmaceutical innovation is evolutionary
`andincentive-driven
`Harvey E. Bale? & Boris Azais?
`
`There is no doubt that the patenting of inventions — any
`inventions, not just medicines — is rising unprecedentedly.
`As Professor Correa writes, the resulting thicket of patents
`could “deprive society of the benefits [of] ... widespread use
`and dissemination of basic scientific ideas”.
`Possibilities and facts are not the samething, however, and
`there is surprisingly little empirical data to show that the patent
`thicket is subtracting from the rate of innovation or society's
`benefit from it. Maybe thatis happening without anyonenotic-
`ing, but the available evidence suggests otherwise.
`Correacites extensively from the NIHCManalysis of
`new medicines, 1989-2000.As he correctly points out, only
`15% of the medicines approvedin that period contained new
`active ingredients and were exceptionally medically useful.
`Fully 65% of medicines contained active ingredients that had
`Professor Correa alleges that “lax rules on patentability and
`been commercialized earlier, and 54% were “incrementally
`shortcomings in procedures” encourage non-inventive or
`modified drugs” that bear great resemblanceto already existing
`medicines.
`“minor, incremental” drug developments and “strategic” pat-
`enting activities. He thus suggests that patents should not be
`Buthow dothesestatistics prove that innovationis being
`granted on medicinesthat “do notentail a genuine therapeutic
`strangled to death?In fact they provejust the opposite: that in-
`progress”. This is to misread the nature and value of pharma-
`novationis alive and well. Ifan inventor’s rational expectation
`ceutical innovation — as inall scientific sectors, the processis
`is that, morelikely than not, the difference between the new
`one ofevolution andreflects the principle that “Nature does
`medicine andthosebefore it will not constitute a great leap,
`not make jumps”.” Correa’s policy prescription, based on an
`butonly an “incremental” improvement, and the inventorstill
`inaccurate diagnosis of the problem anda seriously flawed key
`ploughs money andtime intoits research and development,
`study, would lead to contradictory and anti-innovationresults
`then innovation certainly does not seem strangled. Actually, it
`for critically needed therapeutic innovation in major global
`seems irrepressible.
`disease threats.
`This is not to say that Correa'’s hypothesis about patent
`Correa notes that public sector research provides impor-
`thickets harming pharmaceutical innovation is necessarily
`tant building blocks for private research and development, and
`wrong. Obviously, the more patents, the more inventors must
`that pharmaceutical companies invest “the largest part ofglobal
`spend on patent management,licensing andlitigation. At some
`funds for pharmaceutical R&D”. In modern drug develop-
`point, the mounting costs must dissuade inventors with shal-
`ment, equipped with an armamentarium ofscientific and
`low pockets more than those with deep ones, so that research
`technical skills, the private sector manages the discovery and
`and developmentaccretes in major pharmaceutical companies,
`developmentprocesses in a competitive market that presents
`ahead of small biotechnology firms. The extent to which that
`high risks of failure. The United States National Institutes of
`accretion is happening, andif it leads to a net decreasein in-
`Health (NIH) reported in 2001 that of the 47 prescription
`novation,is under-researched and notclearly known.
`drugs for which sales exceeded US$ 500 million per year, the
`Correa is correct that the quality ofpatent examinationis
`NIH had contributed to the discovery or developmentof only
`scandalous. Even in Europe or North America, many dubious
`four (7).
`patents are issued. The resulting lack of legal certainty harms
`
`
`1 Professor, Institute of Population Health and Faculty of Law, University of Ottawa, Canada. Address for correspondence:RoyalInstitute of InternationalAffairs,
`Chatham House, 10 St James's Square, London SW1Y 4LE, England (email: aattaran@riia.org).
`2 Director General, International Federation of Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Associations (IFPMA), 30 rue de St Jean, PO Box 758, 1211 Geneva 18, Switzerland
`(email: h.bale@ifpma.org). Correspondence maybesentto either author.
`3 IFPMAFellow from Merck & Co.Inc., International Federation of Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Associations (email: b.azais@ifpma.org).
`4 See Geoffrey Fishburn. ‘Natura non facit saltum’ in Charles Darwin andAlfred Marshall. Available from: http://www.qut.edu.au/arts/human/ethics/ieps/absfish.htm
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 5 of 7
`Mylanv. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`
`Mylan Ex.1071 - Page 5 of 7
`Mylan v. Sanofi - IPR2018-01675
`
`

`

`Special Theme — Bridging the Know—Do Gapin Global Health
`RoundTable Discussion
`
`Problems with patent examination in the
`developing world
`Christopher Garrison’
`
`Professor Correa illustrates clearly some of the concerns as-
`sociated with contemporary R&D models and the patterns of
`patenting activity in developed countries that support them.
`Hedraws the proper conclusion that developing countries need
`to pay moreattention to their patent examination and granting
`procedures if they are to avoid similar problems.
`To develop this theme further, two steps must be con-
`sidered. Firstly, developing countries must decide upon or
`review their rules on patentability, bearing in mind the degree
`of flexibility still available under the TRIPS Agreement;least
`developed countries need neither grant nor enforce patents for
`pharmaceutical products until 2016 (1). Ifa developing country
`wished to minimize the numberofpharmaceutical patents that
`it must grant,it could adopt morerestrictive (butstill perfectly
`legitimate) interpretationsofits TRIPSobligations than those
`adopted by Europe, Japan or the United States, and might thus
`avoid someofthe problematic patents cited by Correa. Secondly,
`to make this work, developing countries must put in place a
`robust system to ensure that the rules they have chosen are
`observed.This is nota trivial task.
`To examinerigorously a patent application requires a high
`degree of expertise: for example, the European Patent Office
`employs some 2500 trilingual patent examiners, many with
`postgraduate qualifications. A few developing country patent
`offices do haveeffective examination capabilities, ifnot on such
`a scale, but they are the exception rather than therule (2).
`Patentoffices in many developing countriesrely to a great
`extent on the work ofthe European,Japanese and UnitedStates
`Patent Offices. Through the Substantive Patent LawTreaty nego-
`tiations hosted by the World Intellectual Property Organization,
`these three Patent Offices are pushingfora further international
`harmonization ofcertain fundamental patentabilityrequirements,
`largely alongthelines oftheir ownrules (3). Although adopting
`further harmonized international rules may mean that developing
`countries have to devote fewer resources to patent examination,
`by the sametoken they will furtherlose the policy freedom avail-
`able under TRIPSto chooserules better suited to their needs. A
`regional approach might

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket