throbber
ORIGINAL RESEARCH ARTICLE
`
`Pharrnacoeconomics 2002; 20 Suppl. 3: 11-29
`l 170-7690/02/00J3-00l l/$25.00/0
`
`© A dis International Limited. All rights reserved.
`
`Returns on Research and Development
`for 1990s New Drug Introductions
`Henry Grabowski,1 John Vernon 1 and Joseph A. DiMasi2
`1 Department of Economics, Duke University, Durham, North Carolina, USA
`2 Tufts Center for the Study of Drug Development, Tufts University, Boston, USA
`
`Abstract
`
`Background: Previously published research by the authors found that returns on
`research and development (R&D) for drugs introduced into the US mar(cid:173)
`ket in the 1970s and 1980s were highly skewed and that the top decile of
`new drugs accounted for close to half the overall market value. In the 1990s,
`however, the R&D environment for new medicines underwent a number of
`changes including the following: the rapid growth of managed-care or(cid:173)
`ganisations; indications that R&D costs were rising at a rate faster than that of
`overall inflation; new market strategies of major firms aimed at simultaneous
`launches across world markets; and the increased attention focused on the
`pharmaceutical industry in the political arena.
`Objective: The aim of this study was to examine the worldwide returns on R&D
`for drugs introduced into the US market in the first half of the 1990s, given that
`there have been significant changes to the R&D environment for new medicines
`over the past decade or so.
`Results: Analysis of new drugs entering the market from 1990 to 1994 resulted
`in findings similar to those of the earlier research - pharmaceutical R&D is
`characterised by a highly skewed distribution of returns and a mean industry
`internal rate of return modestly in excess of the cost of capital.
`Conclusions: Although the distribution of returns on R&D for new drugs con(cid:173)
`tinues to be highly skewed, the analysis reveals that a number of dynamic forces
`are currently at work in the industry. In particular, R&D costs as well as new drug
`introductions, sales and contribution margins increased significantly compared
`with their 1980s values.
`
`Competition in the research-based pharma(cid:173)
`ceutical industry centres on the introduction of new
`drug therapies. In this paper, we examine the re(cid:173)
`turns on research and development (R&D) for new
`drug entities introduced into the US market in
`the first half of the 1990s. This research work
`builds directly on earlier analyses of returns on
`R&D for the 1970s and 1980s introductions per(cid:173)
`formed by Grabowski and Vernon_[l,21
`
`Our prior analyses indicate that this industry has
`exhibited very skewed distributions of returns. In
`this regard, several significant new classes of drug
`therapies have been introduced since the late
`1970s. Early movers in these classes have obtained
`the highest returns on R&D. We found that the top
`decile of new drugs accounted for close to half of the
`overall market value associated with all the new drug
`introductions in our 1970s and 1980s' samples.
`
`Return to Report
`
`Sanofi Exhibit 2209.001
`Mylan v. Sanofi
`IPR2018-01675
`
`

`

`16
`
`Grabowski et al.
`
`latter sub-sample of drugs accounts for a very
`small share of overall sales for the full sample.
`
`Life-Cycle Sales Profiles
`
`Since data were available for the years 1990 to
`2000, 7 to 11 years of worldwide sales values for
`the NCEs in our sample were provided, depending
`on their date of introduction into the US market.
`The next task was to estimate future sales over the
`complete market life of these products. Twenty
`years was chosen as the expected market life. This
`is the same assumption that we utilised for 1980s
`new drug introductions. We believe this to be a
`reasonable time horizon for an IRR analysis. Any
`sales remaining after 20 years of market life are
`likely to be very small, given the sales erosion ex(cid:173)
`perienced by most products from generic competi(cid:173)
`tion and product obsolescence. Furthermore, these
`sales will also be severely discounted by the cost
`of capital in an IRR analysis.
`We utilised a two-step procedure to project fu(cid:173)
`ture sales values. These steps involve forecasting
`sales to the point of US patent expiry and then pro(cid:173)
`jecting sales in the post-patent period. The two(cid:173)
`step approach is illustrated in figure 1 for one of
`the products in our sample. This product was intro(cid:173)
`duced into the US market in 1992. There are 9
`
`800
`
`00
`Q) 700
`:::,
`gi
`0
`0
`0
`8
`<f) 500
`
`600
`
`" ~ .E 400
`
`(f)
`:::J
`y; 300
`·" <f)
`Q) 200
`cl
`<f)
`" ro
`Q)
`2
`
`100
`
`Projected values
`(dashed lines)
`
`··••-
`
`' I!_
`
`• -. ., • • .....
`
`Patent expiry
`
`0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1011121314151617181920
`Sales year
`
`Fig. 1. Actual and projected worldwide sales values for a rep(cid:173)
`resentative sample product.
`
`© Adis International Limited. All rights reserved.
`
`years of sales information and its US patent expires
`in year 12. By year 9, this product was in the mature
`portion of its product life cycle. By using a refer(cid:173)
`ence life-cycle curve, the product was projected to
`have relatively stable sales (in constant dollar
`terms) until year 12. A significant decline is then
`projected in the period after US patent expiry be(cid:173)
`cause of the entry of generic competitors and re(cid:173)
`lated economic factors.
`The estimated sales decline after patent expiry
`is based on the experience of major commercial
`products coming off patent in the 1994 to 1997
`period. In particular, we examined worldwide sales
`losses for a sample of NCEs for a 4-year period
`following their US patent expiry. The average per(cid:173)
`centage declines observed were 31, 28, 20 and
`20%, respectively. We utilised these percentages
`to project sales in the first 4 years after patent ex(cid:173)
`piry and, thereafter, a 20% decline until the prod(cid:173)
`uct's market life is completed in year 20. In our
`prior work, we found that generic competition is
`focused on products with significant sales at the
`time of US patent expiry. Consequently, for the
`drugs concentrated in the bottom four deciles of
`our sample (with worldwide sales of less than
`$US40 million in year 10 of their market life), we
`assume that the probability of generic competition
`is very low. For these drugs we assume that sales
`losses in the mature phase of cycle will proceed at
`a more moderately declining rate based on the ref(cid:173)
`erence curve used for the pre-patent expiry period.
`We should note that the percentage declines in
`sales from generic competition in the US market
`observed in prior studies are much greater than the
`worldwide losses in sales for major commercial
`products observed here.l16l Hence, the decline in
`worldwide sales in the post-patent period is amel(cid:173)
`iorated by the lower incidence of generic competi(cid:173)
`tion and sales losses outside the US. This may
`change by the time this cohort actually reaches
`patent expiry during the current decade, because
`reference pricing and generic competition are on
`the rise in many European countries.l17l
`Figure 2 provides a plot of the sales life-cycle
`profile (in $US, 2000 values) for the top two dee-
`
`Pharmacoeconomics 2002; 20 Suppl. 3
`Return to Report
`
`Sanofi Exhibit 2209.002
`Mylan v. Sanofi
`IPR2018-01675
`
`

`

`R&D Returns for 1990s New Drug Introductions
`
`17
`
`3000 □ 1st Decile
`.i. 2nd Decile
`0 Mean
`■ Median
`
`00
`Q) 2500
`:::,
`cl
`>
`0
`0
`0
`8
`
`2000
`
`<f) " ~ 1500
`.E
`
`(f)
`
`:::J 1000
`y;
`·" <f)
`
`Q)
`cl
`(f)
`
`500
`
`0
`
`1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 0 11 12 13 14 1 5 16 17 18 19 20
`Sales year
`
`Fig. 2. Worldwide sales profiles of 1990 to 1994 new drug in(cid:173)
`troductions.
`
`iles as well as the mean and median drug com(cid:173)
`pounds in our 1990 to 1994 sample. The sales
`curves illustrate the highly skewed distribution of
`sales in pharmaceuticals that was observed for
`early cohorts. The peak sales of the top decile com(cid:173)
`pounds are several times the peak sales of the
`second decile compounds. The mean sales curve
`is also significantly above the median.
`Figure 3 provides a plot of mean worldwide
`sales for the 1990s sample compared with that for
`the 1980s cohort (in $US, 2000 values). Mean
`sales have increased significantly in real terms,
`with peak sales increasing from $US345 million
`for the 1980s cohort to $US458 million for the
`1990s cohort. There is also the suggestion that
`sales curves have become somewhat steeper in the
`ascending sales growth stages of the life cycle,
`with a longer plateau before generic competition
`and product obsolescence take hold.
`Figure 4 shows a corresponding plot of the
`mean worldwide sales for the top decile com(cid:173)
`pounds in the 1990 to 1994 and 1980 to 1984 pe(cid:173)
`riods. This is instructive, given that the prospective
`returns for top decile compounds are primary driv(cid:173)
`ers of R&D investment activities in pharmaceuti(cid:173)
`cals . For the 1990s cohort, the top decile com(cid:173)
`pounds reached peak sales of more than $US2.5
`
`© Adis International Limited. All rights reserved.
`
`billion. This may be compared with peak sales of
`near $US 1.8 billion for the 1980s cohort. The peak
`sales for the 1990s cohort also occur later than for
`the 1980s cohort.
`
`Pre-Tax Contributions and Other
`Economic Parameters
`
`The next step in the analysis was to obtain rev(cid:173)
`enues net of production and distribution costs ( of(cid:173)
`ten categorised in the economic literature as
`'quasi-rents'). For this purpose, we analysed pre(cid:173)
`tax contribution margins in pharmaceuticals dur(cid:173)
`ing the 1990s. As in prior work, we utilised data
`derived from the income statements of the pharma(cid:173)
`ceutical divisions of a number of major multina(cid:173)
`tional drug companies to obtain representative
`values on contribution margins over timeP.2l
`Our analysis of the data on these firms indicated
`that average contribution margins gradually in(cid:173)
`creased from 42% in the early part of the 1980s to
`approximately 45% at the end of the decade. On
`the basis of these data, we constructed a linear con(cid:173)
`tribution margin schedule over time. In particular,
`the contribution margin is 42% in the first year of
`the product life and grows by increments of 0.3%
`
`500
`
`□ 1990-1994
`
`Q)
`
`00
`.:! 400
`~
`0
`0
`0
`8
`
`300
`
`<f) " ~ .E
`
`(f)
`:::J
`y;
`
`·" <f)
`
`Q)
`cl
`<f)
`" ro
`
`Q)
`~
`
`200
`
`100
`
`0
`
`1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
`Sales year
`
`Fig. 3. Comparison of mean worldwide sales curves for new
`drug introductions in the 1990 to 1994 and 1980 to 1984
`samples.
`
`Pharmacoeconomics 2002; 20 Suppl. 3
`Return to Report
`
`Sanofi Exhibit 2209.003
`Mylan v. Sanofi
`IPR2018-01675
`
`

`

`18
`
`Grabowski et al.
`
`3000
`
`□ 1990-1994
`O 1980-1984
`
`2500
`
`00
`Q)
`:::,
`cl
`>
`0
`2000
`0
`0
`~
`
`<f) " ~ .E
`
`(f)
`:::J
`y;
`
`·" <f)
`
`Q)
`cl
`(f)
`
`1500
`
`1000
`
`500
`
`1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 0 11 12 13 14 1 5 16 17 18 19 20
`Sales year
`
`Fig. 4. Comparison of mean worldwide sales curves for top
`decile drugs in the 1990 to 1994 and 1980 to 1984 samples.
`
`per year. We also assume that contribution margins
`will continue to rise at this same rate during the
`current decade. Hence, over the full 20-year life
`cycle, target contribution margins are expected to
`rise from 42 % in year one, to 48% by year 20, with
`a mean contribution margin of 45% over the full
`life cycle.
`While we constrained margins to average 45%
`over the life cycle, we also recognise, as in our
`earlier analyses, that promotion and marketing ex(cid:173)
`penditures are concentrated in the launch phases of
`the life cycle. In our prior analysis, we developed
`the following allocation rule based on a regression
`analysis of promotional and marketing outlays:
`promotion and marketing is equal to sales in year
`1, declines to 50% in year 2, and falls to 25% in
`year 3. We retained this assumed pattern on mar(cid:173)
`keting outlays in the present analysis. Interviews
`with industry participants indicated that the initial
`post-launch years continue to be the primary focus
`of marketing and promotion activities.
`An analysis performed by Rosenthal et aU18l
`indicates that the drug industry's marketing ex(cid:173)
`penses to sales ratios have remained relatively
`stable around 14% in the 1996 to 2000 period. How(cid:173)
`ever, there were some important compositional
`
`© Adis International Limited. All rights reserved.
`
`shifts over this period. The direct-to-consumer ad(cid:173)
`vertising to sales ratio increased from 1.2 % to 2.2 %
`between 1996 and 2000, at the expense of physi(cid:173)
`cian detailing and hospital medical journal adver(cid:173)
`tising.[lSJ
`For the current analysis, we did make one rela(cid:173)
`tively minor change in the allocation and timing of
`marketing expenditures related to launch. In par(cid:173)
`ticular, we estimated pre-marketing launch expen(cid:173)
`ditures in the order of 5 and 10% of first year sales
`in the 2 years immediately prior to launch. These
`marketing expenditures are for activities such as
`pre-launch meetings and symposiums, pricing and
`focus group studies, and sales force training. Our
`assumptions concerning the size and timing of
`these expenditures were guided by a recent survey
`report on pre-launch marketing expenditures by in(cid:173)
`dustry consultants as well as interviews with some
`of the participating companies.l19l
`As indicated above, our model is structured so
`that margins average 45% over the full product life
`cycle. Given the assumed pattern of launch expen(cid:173)
`ditures, contribution margins for each product
`are below representative industry values in the
`first 3 years of marketing. However, as a product
`matures, both promotional and administrative
`costs decline in relative terms, and contribution
`margins increase over average industry values in
`the later years of the life cycle.
`The model is also structured to provide for cap(cid:173)
`ital expenditures on plant and equipment (P&E).
`As in our model for the 1980s cohort, we assumed
`overall capital expenditures for P&E to be equal to
`40% of tenth year sales . Half of these outlays are
`assumed to occur in the first 2 years before market(cid:173)
`ing and the other half during the initial 10 years of
`the product's market life. These assumptions imply
`an average capital investment to sales ratio of 3.3%
`over the full product life cycle. This is generally
`consistent with data from pharmaceutical industry
`income statements.
`In particular, we checked the reasonableness of
`our assumptions by comparing this implied 3.3%
`capital investment to sales ratio with the corre(cid:173)
`sponding ratios observed on industry income state-
`
`Pharmacoeconomics 2002; 20 Suppl. 3
`Return to Report
`
`Sanofi Exhibit 2209.004
`Mylan v. Sanofi
`IPR2018-01675
`
`

`

`R&D Returns for 1990s New Drug Introductions
`
`19
`
`ments during the 1990s. We found that the drug
`industry capital investment to sales ratio averaged
`about 7.0% during the 1990s. However, the latter
`value includes investment for R&D as well as
`production, marketing and administrative facil(cid:173)
`ities. In our model, provisions for capital invest(cid:173)
`ment in R&D facilities are included in the cost
`estimates provided by DiMasi et aU5l Accord(cid:173)
`ingly, we asked some industry members involved
`with strategic planning for information on what
`percentage of their P&E expenditures was devoted
`to R&D, versus other firm activities. We obtained
`a range of 40 to 50% of total capital expenditures
`devoted to R&D. Given this range, the capital in(cid:173)
`vestments to sales ratio for non-R&D activities
`implied by our model is consistent with the ob(cid:173)
`served data from company income statements.
`For working capital, it was assumed that ac(cid:173)
`counts receivables are equal to 2 months of annual
`sales and inventories are 5 months of sales (valued
`at manufacturing cost). These are also based on
`the analysis of balance sheet data of major phar(cid:173)
`maceutical firms. Working capital is recovered at
`the end of the final year of product life.
`
`Effective Tax Rates
`
`Our analysis of returns is conducted on an af(cid:173)
`ter-tax basis. In our prior studies of returns, we
`computed average effective tax rates based on
`analysis of income statement data from eight major
`pharmaceutical firms. The average effective rate
`was 35% for the 1970s cohort and 33% for the
`1980s cohort. A comparable analysis for the 1990s
`cohort yielded an effective tax rate of 30%. This is
`the rate used in our baseline case. The difference
`between the nominal corporate tax rate (34%) and
`the average effective tax rate of 30% reflects var(cid:173)
`ious credits and deferrals such as the R&D tax
`credit and manufacturing tax credits for plants in
`Puerto Rico.l2l
`After-tax cash flows are also influenced by the
`tax treatment of depreciation. In our analysis, cash
`flow in each year is equal to after-tax profits, plus
`depreciation charges. Accelerated depreciation, as
`specified in the US tax code, results in tax deferrals
`
`© Adis International Limited. All rights reserved.
`
`and positive cash flow in the early years of a prod(cid:173)
`uct's market life. This reverses in the latter years
`of a product's life.
`
`Summary of Economic Values
`
`Table II provides a summary of the key eco(cid:173)
`nomic inputs to IRR and NPV analysis for the 1990
`to 1994 NCEs cohort compared with the corre(cid:173)
`sponding values for the 1980 to 1984 cohort. R&D
`investment levels have roughly doubled in real
`terms, in both uncapitalised as well as capitalised
`dollar terms. On the revenue side of the equation,
`sales-life curves have shifted upward significantly.
`This is reflected in higher peak sales for the 1990
`to 1994 cohorts ($US458 million compared with
`$US345 million for 1980 to 1984 NCEs ). While
`sales have not grown at the same rate as R&D
`costs, contribution margins have increased in the
`1990s, implying higher operational profits from a
`given level of sales. How all these factors balance
`out from a returns-on-investment standpoint is a
`major issue addressed in the analysis that follows.
`The industry's cost of capital, effective tax rate,
`and capital investment-to-sales ratio have changed
`only marginally for the current cohort compared
`with the 1980s sample.
`Table II suggests that R&D investment expen(cid:173)
`ditures are growing over time relative to sales rev(cid:173)
`enues and the other activities of pharmaceutical
`
`Table II. Key economic values for internal rate of return analysis
`for the 1990 to 1994 versus 1980 to 1984 new chemical entities
`(NCEs)
`
`1990 to 1994
`
`1980 to 1984
`
`$US416 mil
`$US480 mil
`$US458 mil
`45%
`11%
`30%
`3.3%
`
`$US196 mil
`$US251 mil
`$US345 mil
`40%
`10.5%
`33%
`3.4%
`
`Economic parameter
`Average R&D costs•
`pre-tax uncapitalised
`after tax capitalised
`Peak sales for mean NCE•
`Contribution marginb
`Cost of capital
`Effective tax rate
`Capital-to-investment sales
`ratio
`a R&D costs and sales are all expressed in 2000 values.
`b Average contribution margins over the full product life cycle;
`launch costs are concentrated in early phases of life cycle,
`so margins are lower in initial years and higher in later years.
`mil = millions; R&D = research and development.
`
`Pharmacoeconomics 2002; 20 Suppl. 3
`Return to Report
`
`Sanofi Exhibit 2209.005
`Mylan v. Sanofi
`IPR2018-01675
`
`

`

`20
`
`200
`
`150
`
`Grabowski et al.
`
`Market introduction
`
`100
`
`00
`Q)
`:::,
`cl
`>
`0
`0
`0
`~ 50
`
`<f) " ~ .E
`
`(f)
`:::J
`y;
`
`0
`
`-50
`
`-11-10-9 -8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
`Year
`
`Fig. 5. Cash flows over the product life cycle: baseline case.
`
`firms. This issue is discussed further in 'Drug In(cid:173)
`novation and Industry Evolution Since 1970'. This
`increase in industry research intensity can be inter(cid:173)
`preted both as a response to increasing profit op(cid:173)
`portunities from new drug research as well as an
`equilibrating factor bringing returns in line with
`the industry cost of capital. This makes the ques(cid:173)
`tion of industry returns on new drug introduction
`in the 1990s a particularly interesting question to
`analyse at the present time.
`
`Empirical Results
`
`The Baseline Case
`
`Using the data and assumptions described
`above, we constructed the pattern of cash flows
`for the mean of our sample of 118 NCEs shown
`in figure 5. The R&D phase lasts for 12 years and
`results in a stream of negative cash flows. The first
`years of marketing, years 1 and 2, are also charac(cid:173)
`terised by negative cash flows. This is because of
`heavy promotion and advertising expenditures
`during the product launch period. Cash flows rise
`to a peak in year 12 and then begin to decline. The
`decline becomes steeper as patent expiry and ge(cid:173)
`neric competition begin.
`
`© Adis International Limited. All rights reserved.
`
`The baseline case results are shown in the first
`row of table III. The IRR is 11.5% and can be com(cid:173)
`pared with our real cost-of-capital estimate of 11 %.
`Hence, the industry mean performance is positive
`but only by a small amount. The present value of
`net revenues at the date of marketing is $US525
`million and can be compared with the present value
`of R&D costs at the same point in time, or $US480
`million. This leads to an NPV of $US45 million.
`The results for the baseline case for the 1990 to
`1994 NCEs are roughly the same as for our earlier
`1980 to 1984 sample. In the 1980 to 1984 baseline
`case, the IRR was 11.1 % compared with a cost of
`capital ofl0.5%. The 1990 to 1994 IRR is similarly
`about a half percentage point above the cost-of(cid:173)
`capital estimate.
`
`Sensitivity Analysis
`
`Given the uncertainty surrounding many of the
`key parameters that affect the IRR and NPV, we
`have performed a sensitivity analysis for a number
`of the parameters. These results are reported in
`table III.
`An important parameter is the contribution mar(cid:173)
`gin. As discussed earlier, we examined data for a
`number of firms during the 1990s and found that
`
`Pharmacoeconomics 2002; 20 Suppl. 3
`Return to Report
`
`Sanofi Exhibit 2209.006
`Mylan v. Sanofi
`IPR2018-01675
`
`

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket