throbber
Volume l3 - Number I °2EIIU
`VALUE IN HEALTH
`
`Good Research Practices for Measuring Drug Costs in
`Cost Effectiveness Analyses: Issues and Recommendations:
`The ISPOR Drug Cost Task Force Report—Part I
`
`JoeIVV. Hay, PhD,' Jim Smeeding, RPh, MBA,2 NormanV. Carroll, RPh, PhD,J Michael Drummond,PhD,“
`Louis P. Garrison, PhD,5 Edward C. Mansley, PhD,‘S C. Daniel Mullins, PhD,7 Jack M. Mycka. 85,3
`Brian Seal, PhD, RPh, MBA,” Lizheng Shi, PhD, MS“)
`’Department of Clinical Pharmacy. Pharmaceutical Economics 8: Policy. University of Southern California. Los Angeles.CA.USA:1JestaRx
`Group, Dallas.TX, USA; 3School of Pharmacy,Virginia Commonwealth University, Richmond,VA, USA; ‘Centre for Health Economics.
`University onork,York, UK; 5Pharmaceutical Outcomes Research & Poiicy Program, Department of Pharmacy. University of Washington,
`Seattle.WA, USA; ‘Merck & Co.. Inc.. North Wales, PA, USA; 7Pharmaceutics! Health Services Research, University of Maryland School of
`Pharmacy, Baltimore. MD. USA: ”MME LLC. Montclair. NJ. USA; ’Sanofi-Aventis Pharmaceuticals. Bridgewater’. NJ. USA; '“Department of Health
`Systems ManagemenLTuIane University School of Public Health and Tropical Medicine, New Orleans. LA, USA
`
`ABSTRACT
`
`Obiectives: The assignment of prices or costs to pharmaceuticals can be
`Good Research Practices—«Use of Drug Costs for Cost Effectiveness
`Analysis (DCTF) subgroups met to develop core assumptions and an
`crucial to results and conclusions that are derived from pharmacoeco-
`outline before preparing six draft reports. They solicited comments on the
`nomic cost efiectivencss anaiyses (CEAs). Although numerous pharmaco-
`economic practice guidelines are available in the literature and have been
`outline and drafts from a core group of 174 external reviewers and more
`promulgated in many countries, these guidelines are either vague or silent
`broadly from the membership of JSPOR at two iSPOR meetings and via
`the ISPOR web site.
`I
`about how drug costs should be established or measured. This is particu-
`Results: Drug cost measurements should be fully transparent and reflect
`larly problematic in phatmaeocconomic studies performed from the “soci-
`etal” perspective, because typically the measured cost of a brand name
`the net payment most relevant to the user’s perspective. The Task Force
`pharmaceutical is not a true economic cost but also includes transfer
`recommends that for CEAs of brand name drugs performed from a soci-
`ctal perspective, either '1} CEA analysts use a cost that more accurately
`payments from some members of society (patients and third parry payers)
`to other members of society (pharmaceutical manufacturer stockholders)
`reflects true societal drug costs ($3., 20-60% of average sales price), or
`in large part as a reward for biomedical innovation. Moreover, there are
`when that is too unrealistic to be meaningful for decision-makers, 2) refer
`numerous and complex institutional factors that influence how drug costs
`to their analyses as from a ”limited societal perspective." CEAs performed
`from :1 payer perspective should use drug, prices actualiy paid by the
`should be measured from other CEA perspectives, both internationally
`and within the domestic US context. The objective of this report is to
`relevant payer net of ail rebates, copays, or other adjustments. When such
`price adiusrmcnts are confidential, the analyst slanuid apply a typical or
`provide guidance and recommendations on how drug costs should be
`average discount that preserves this confidentiality.
`measured for CEAs performed from a number of key analytic perspectives.
`Methods: ISPOR Tasit Force on Good Research Pr:1cticcs~——Use of Drug
`Conclusions: Drug transaction prices not only ration current use of mcdi-
`Costs for Cost Effectiveness Analysis (Drug Cost Task Force lDCTFl) was
`Cation but also ration future biomedical research and development. CEA
`appointed with the advice and consent of the ISPOR Board of Directors.
`researchers should tailor the appropriate measure of drug costs to the
`Members were experienced developers or users of CEA modcis, worked in
`analytic perspective, maintain clarity and transparency on drug cost mea-
`academia,
`industry, and as advisors to governments, and came from
`surcment, and report the sensitivity of CEA resuits to reasonable drug cost
`measurement alternatives.
`scvcrai countries, Because how drug costs should be measured for CEAs
`Keywords: cost effectiveness analysis, drug costs, drug research and devel-
`depend on the perspectives, five Task Force subgroups were create-(i to
`deveIOp drug cost standards from the societal, managed care, US govern-
`opment, healtlrcare market segmentation, healthvcare reimbursement,
`payer perspective.
`‘ menr, industry, and international perspective. The ISPOR Task Force on
`
`Background to the Task Force
`The ISPOR Task Force on Good Research ProcticcswUse of Drug
`Costs for Cost Effectiveness Analysis (DCTF) was recommended
`by the ISPOR Health Science Policy Council on December 13,
`2004 and approved by the ISPOR Board of Directors on May 15,
`2005.}0131 Hay and jim Smceding were appointed as Task Force
`leaders by the ISPOR Board. The core members ofthe Task Force
`who became the leaders of the Task Force subgroups were chosen
`
`Address correspondence to: joel W. Hay, Department of Clinical Phar-
`macy, Pharmaceutical Economics Sc Policy, University of Southern Cali-
`fornia, Cl-ll’ii 140}, 1540 E. Alcoznr Street, Los :‘tngclcs, CA 90089-9004,
`USA, Email jhay@usc.cdu
`10.1 I I if].1.5244733300930661}:
`
`based on the key cost effectiveness analysis (CEA) modeling
`perspectives and their experience as developers or users of CEA
`models for that particular perspective. These individuais were
`recognized as scientific leaders in the field, who worked with that
`perspective in academia, industry, and as advisers to governments,
`and who came from a variety of countries and health—care settings.
`Because how drug costs shouid be measured for CEAs depend on
`the perspectives,
`five Task Force subgroups were created to
`develop drug cost standards from the societal, managed care, US
`government, industry, and international perspective. Therefore,
`this ‘l‘nsk Force Report is given in six parts, Part I:
`issues and
`recommendations; Part
`II: a societal perspective; Part
`III: a
`managed care perspective; Part IV: US government perspective;
`i’art V: industry perspective; and Part VI: international perspee
`rive. The Task i-‘orce Report reflects the authors’ own experiences
`
`© 2009, International Society for Pharmacoeconomics and Outcomes Research (ISPOR)
`
`|U9SJDISIIUIE 3—7
`
`Page 1 of 5
`
`2.106
`
`DEPOSITION
`EXHIBIT
`
`Biogen Exhibit 2206
`Mylan v. Biogen
`IPR 2018-01403
`
`Page 1 of 5
`
`Biogen Exhibit 2206
`Mylan v. Biogen
`IPR 2018-01403
`
`

`

`Hay er of.
`
`companies would quickly discontinue pharmaceutical RSCD. But
`patent protection creates clear political, economic and social
`tensions, because certain drugs could be provided to some
`patients and/or payers at a price that would cover the marginal
`costs of production, but are not high enough to generate optimal
`profits to the innovative manufacrurer. As has been the case of
`AIDS drugs in Africa, patients get sick and die without access to
`existing medications partly to pretect
`the patent monopoly
`reward system to ensure pharmaceuticai innovation for future
`generations.
`It is often in the interest of both the pharmaceutical manu-
`facturer and its consumers to aliow price discrimination among
`different market segments. That is, the pharmaceutical manufac-
`turer, particularly when holding patents on brand name drugs,
`can often make more profits and also make their products more
`accessible to more market segments by charging different prices
`to different consumers, based on the consumers’ different
`demand eiasticities (willingness~to-pay). This strategy is most
`effective when such price discrimination is confidential or parallel
`imports are restricted, because this minimizes the potential for
`supply leakage between market segments.
`Drug price discrimination is most obvious in comparing
`prices for the same brand name pharmaceuticals in different
`countries (e.g., the price of as hypertension drug in Canada, the
`United States, Mexico, and China}. Although many health-care
`providers can price discriminate across market segments,
`this
`strategy is often challenged politically, because consumers in the
`richer (higher priced) market segments usually resent having to
`pay more for the same pills as consumers in the poorer (lower
`priced} market segments. Unlike hospital or physician services,
`pharmaceuticals are generaiiy available as tangible and tradablc
`products, and when drug price discrepancies become too large
`between different market segments (or countries) there will be
`substantiai arbitrage through legal,
`illegal, or _ grey market
`rte-importation activities.
`Measurement of drug costs depends firstiy on the perspective
`of the analyst. Depending on the country or region, the drug cost
`burden is ultimately shared in varying degrees between govern-
`ment or other third party payers and patients. There are drug
`supply chain intermediaries (e.g., wholesalers, retailers, etc.) who
`receive payments for maintaining inventories, product distribu-
`tion, and dispensing. There can also be demand-side intermedi-
`aries (e.g., pharmaceutical benefits managers, group purchasing
`organizations, etc.) who receive payments for negotiating price
`discounts or rebates and managing drug product lists and for—
`mularies. At with step of these demand and suppiy chains, drug
`acquisition costs may vary in complex and nontransparent ways.
`Given this background, drug valuation (costing) for economic
`evaluation is complicated. The complexity is compounded when
`one considers that each economic evaluation is carried out from
`a specific perSpective (e.g., hospital, government payer [in a large
`or small country], managed care organization, patient, societal,
`etc.) and the various perspectives reflect tangibly different objec-
`tives, impacts, allocation priorities, market power, and demand
`elasticities. At the societal perSpective levei, particularly in coun-
`tries with large domestic innovative pharmaceutical
`industry,
`there is a ciear tension between encouraging pharmaceutical
`innovation with brand name drug prices that are substantially
`higher than marginal drug production costs and encouraging
`less-expensive medications to reduce health-care costs.
`For managed care organizations, or for smaller countries
`without domestic innovative pharmaceutical industries, there is
`little direct incentive to encourage pharmaceutical innovation,
`because such innovation disproportionateiy benefits other con-
`sumers, payers, or countries. In these organizations, it is prefer-
`
`4 d
`
`eveloping drug costs for use in CEA models and publications, but
`is not intended as a comprehensive review of the literature.
`The Task Force held its first meeting at
`the lSPOR 10th
`Annual International Meeting in Washington DC in 2005 and
`held open forums and/or group leader breakfast meetings at the
`ISPOR 8th Annual European Congress in Florence in 2005, at
`the ISPOR 11th Annual International Meeting in Philadelphia in
`2006, and at the 14th Annual Internationai Meeting in Orlando
`in 2009. The Task Force reviewed other lSPOR guidance docu—
`ments that were developed to inform good scientific conduct
`[1-3}. The Task Force subgroups held teleconferences and used
`electronic mail to exchange outlines and ideas during the subse—
`quent months. The ISPOR Task Force on Good Research
`Practices~wUse of Drug Costs for Cost Effectiveness Analysis
`(DCTF) subgroups met
`to develop core assumptions and an
`outline before preparing draft subgroup reports. Several teiecon—
`ferences of the Task Force subgroup leaders were held to diseuss
`the draft reports, incorporate feedback, and make revisions. Each
`part of the Task Force Report was prepared by Task Force
`subgroup cochairs and members and circulated to 174 Task
`Force primary reviewers (who were self—identified from a broad
`range of perspectives). After this review, new drafts was prepared
`by the Task Force subgroups and made accessible for broader
`review by all lSPOR members. Comments for these reports by
`Task Force primary reviewers and ISPOR membership are pub-
`lished at the lSPOR website. All opinions reflect those of the
`authors and not necessarily their affiliations.
`
`Introduction
`
`The primary purpose of economic evaluation (specifically, CEA
`as recommended in numerous international payer guidelines [4])
`in health care is to provide valid and reliable information to
`health-care policymakers and decision-makers regarding the rela-
`tive value of alternative health—care interventions. The key ratio-
`nale supporting these economic evaluations is that the market for
`health-care interventions is so severely distorted by insurance
`coverage, third—party payments, information failure, times, sub—
`sidies, and numerous competition barriers that prices do not
`serve the normal economic function of guiding efficient resource
`allocation. Unlike a competitive market, in health care, Adam
`Smith’s “invisible hand” of price signals is so severely withered
`and atrophied that it must be replaced by the virtual reality glove
`of the economic analyst to ensure that scare resources are allo-
`cated appropriately [5].
`Although there are many areas of health care where prices are
`distorted, perhaps no area is subject to more complexity, confu-
`sion, imprecision, misunderstanding, or conflicting methods than
`that of what price measurements to use for the cost of pharma—
`ceuticals in economic evaluations [6]. The fundamental reason
`for this is that pharmaceuticals are launched into the market only
`after lengthy governmental review of safety and efficacy (e.g., the
`US Food and Drug Administration or the European Medicines
`Agency). Prescription drugs are only sold by licensed medical
`professionals under strict reguiations regarding allowable usage
`indications, patient populations, and appropriate marketing.
`Pharmaceutical research, development, and innovation are
`rewarded and encouraged primarily through patents, giving the
`innovative manufacturer
`(the patent holder)
`a
`time-limited
`monopoly over drug pricing for the patented drug. Because
`patents
`reward
`innovation
`by
`transferring brandwspecific
`monopoly profits (the excess of drug price over drug marginal
`cost) from consumers to innovator pharmaceutical producers,
`they distort competitive drug prices with the specific intent of
`encouraging future drug RSCD. Without patent protection, drug
`
`Page 2 of 5
`
`Page 2 of 5
`
`

`

`lSPOR Drug Cost Task Force Report Overview
`
`able to take maximum advantage of one’s local monopsony
`market power to drive drug prices as low as possible for both
`payment and evaluation purposes. Because such organizations or
`countries cannot impact REED innovation substantially, it is in
`their interest to “free-ride” on larger payers and countries whose
`drug payments do have a significant impact on drug manufac-
`turer profits and RSCD incentives.
`Frank Ramsey showed in 1927 that a monopolist facing
`segmented markets (e.g., consumers with high income/high insur-
`ance coverage vs.
`low incomel'iow insurance coverage] would
`achieve both higher profits and higher social Welfare by setting
`prices in each market segment
`inversely proportional
`to the
`market segment elasticity of demand [7,8]. it is beneficial to both
`pharmaceutical producers and many consumers to engage in
`market segmentation; but because it is diificult to prevent leakage
`from lower-priced markets to higher-priced markets, the phar—
`maceutical
`industry engages in extraordinarily complex and
`often secretive negotiations with different customers with the
`explicit purpose of preventing richer market segments from
`knowing the actual transaction prices in the more demand-elastic
`market segments.
`For example, in the United States, the Medicaid program is
`required by law to receive the lowest manufacturer price avail—
`able to private and certain public purchasers for single source
`drugs. Nevertheless,
`this transaction price is fully disguised
`through secret volume rebates paid from the pharmaceutical
`manufacturers to the state Medicaid programs. Thus, even
`though they are all directly involved in the purchase and sales of
`Medicaid drugs, Medicaid patients,
`retail pharmacists, drug
`wholesalers, and other intermediaries have no idea what the real
`transaction prices are for the Medicaid drug purchases.
`Similar secretive price discounting mechanisms, often trig-
`gered by volume targets, formulary placement and multidrug
`purchasing from the same manufacturers, as well as rebates for
`formulary placement, make it extremely difficult to know what
`any given government or third-party payer actually pays for
`specific pharmaceutical products. Moreover, there is no require»
`ment
`to make such information publicly known. Generally
`speaking, those organizations with the greatest market power
`(e.g., single—payer government health-care systems) and those
`with the highest demand elasticity will capture greater discounts
`from publicly quoted or published prices, while those with the
`least market power and lowest demand elasticity will achieve
`smaller discounts and pay close to full price.
`It should be kept in mind that the traditional method for
`rewarding pharmaceutical R8cD through patent protection and
`monopoly prices for new drugs is the result of historical prece-
`dent and institutional
`inertia. it is an imperfect system for
`rewarding biomedical
`innovation;
`often
`allocating scarce
`resources towards “me-too" patentable new molecules rather
`than towards genuine innovations, although leaving critically
`important innovations {c.g., low-dose aspirin for heart disease or
`generic antibiotics for ulcers) to languish for years without being
`widely researched or adopted due to inability to obtain patent
`protection and to profit from valuable innovations [9].
`Moreover, it is vitally important to provide adequate incen—
`tives for biomedical
`research in general and pharmaceutical
`RESCD in particular. There is consensus among health economists
`that the societal returns to biomedical RSCD are on the order of
`10—100 to 1 [10,11]. Cutler or a]. have recentiy estimated that
`within the US population, average life year gains from £987 to
`2000 were approximately 3 to 2 years and the average quality-
`adjusted life year (QALY) gains were 3 to 4 years |l2|. Valuing
`these QALY gains at a societal willingness to pay of $150,000,
`and assuming that 2 in 3 of these gains are due to medical care
`
`5
`
`innovations [13],
`improvements, mostly due to biomedical
`implies that medical care gains added $90 trillion, or approxi-
`mately $2.7 trillion annually to the societal wealth of the US
`population during this time period. The global value of biomedi-
`cal innovation wouid be several times larger than these estimates.
`Several alternatives to the patent system have been proposed
`to reward biomedical RBCD [6—8,14]. These include user licenses,
`government patent buyouts, rewards or tax-funded pharmaceu-
`tical R861). Whether such alternative mechanisms can be imple-
`mented to incentivize pharmaceutical RSCD without requiring a
`monopoly pricing structure for brand name pharmaceuticals, it
`would be feasible to use marginal cost (or generic) drug prices in
`economic evaluations of pharmaceutical interventions, particu—
`larly when done from a societal perspective. In fact, given that
`the monopoly profits awarded to drug manufacturer patent-
`holders is not a true cost, but rather a transfer payment from one
`member of society to another [15], there is a strong argument to
`exclude these profits from drug costs when conducting economic
`evaluations from a societal perspective.
`In fact, one can demonstrate that government buyouts of
`drug patents with all drugs being sold at generic pricing levels
`could achieve a much better outcome for government programs,
`private consumers, and third party payers without damaging the
`incentives for pharmaceutical RaCD. Currently, the brand name
`pharmaceutical spending on R&D is about $60 billion [16]. US
`federal drug spending is $81 billion {17]. Each year, the US
`federal government could buy out all drug patents (by fully
`subsidizing the private costs of pharmaceutical RSCD) and still
`save money because it would be able to purchase all drugs at
`generic prices. US consumers would additionally benefit by more
`than $100 biiiion per year if all drugs were generic.
`Beyond these theoretical concerns,
`there are institutional
`complexities and opaque payment structures in every country
`and health-care financing system that make drug cost measure—
`ment difficult even when the analytic perspective is straight-
`forward and clear. For example,
`in the US managed care
`environment, a particular medication could experience a dozen
`or more different transaction prices depending on where it is in
`the supply chain from manufacturer, to wholesaler, to retailer, to
`patient, and where it
`is in the payment/reimbursement chain
`from manufacturer to managed care organization, to pharma-
`ceutical benefits manager, to patient, to rebate coupon. Aithough
`this report is not an exhaustive compilation of all of the com-
`plexities and variations in drug transaction costs, it does give
`examples from many of the typical scenarios that CEA analysts
`will encounter around the globe. More importantly, it provides
`guidance and recommendations based on the authors‘ and
`reviewers’ experience and understanding of what works best.
`
`Purposes of the Report
`
`The purposes of this Task Force Report are: 1} to develop a
`coherent set of guidelines for those developing or reviewing drug
`cost measurements in CEAs; and 2) to develop a format for good
`research practices in drug cost measurement that is useful for
`decision-makers from various perspectives. The intended audi—
`ence is research anaiysts who perform CEA analyses for health-
`care decisionunakers as well as health-care decision-makers who
`are responsible for local or national formularies. Others who
`may find this document useful
`include members of the press,
`patient advocacy groups, health-care professionals, drug and
`other technoiogy manufacturers, and those developing guidelines
`for their settings. The panel
`recognizes that the methods int
`measuring and reporting drug costs continue to develop. This
`
`Page 3 0f 5
`
`Page 3 of 5
`
`

`

`Hay at al.
`
`prices in either the base case or sensitivity analyses of phar—
`macoeconomic models. It is aiso appropriate to inciude
`longer—term trends in applicable drug prices {net of general
`inflation) for chronic disease medications.
`ISPOR should publish a website where current DCTF rec-
`ommendations for drug costing are updated as important
`new information becomes available.
`
`6.
`
`7. Population-based estimates of drug costs should incorpo—
`rate predicted adherence and persistence with drug therapy.
`8. When done from a patient/consumer perspective, the total
`net out-of-pocket payments for medications should be used
`as the drug cost measurement.
`Implications of extreme
`changes in marginal or average drug costs on patient drug
`utilization (e.g., completion of deductible expense limits,
`reaching maximum coverage benefits, Medicare-type cover-
`age “doughnut holes,” etc.) should be fully evaluated and
`expiained.
`9. For international comparisons, drug units should be stan-
`dardized in terms of volumel'weight of active ingredient,
`regardless of package and dosing frequency or strength
`variations across countries.
`
`10. Drug costs should be measured in focal currency per unit of
`active ingredient and should be converted to other curren-
`cies using Purchasing Power Parity indexes or a currency
`exchange rate relevant to the decision-maker.
`11. When using drug prices from different years, the consumer
`price index (preferably the medical care component price
`index or the pharmaceutical component price index) for the
`local currency should be applied before the currency
`conversion.
`
`Acknowledgments
`
`\Ve acknowledge the valuable assistance of Daniel Kim, Dorothy
`Noviius, and the ISPOR staff.
`
`Source of financiai support: None.
`
`References
`
`[u
`
`LII
`
`l Mauskopf ]r\, Sullivan SD, Annemans L, et al. Principles of good
`practice for budget
`impact analysis: report of the ISPOR task
`force on good research practices—budget impact analysis. Value
`Health 2007;10:336—47.
`Wcinstciu MC, O’Brien B, Hornbergcr }, ct al. Principles of good
`practice for decision analytic modeling in health care CValuation:
`report
`of
`the
`ISPOR Task
`Force
`on
`good
`research
`practices—modeling studies. Value Health 2003;69—3 7.
`3 Ramsey S, Wilikc R, Briggs A, ct al. Good research practices for
`cost-effectiveness alongside clinical triais: the ISPOR RCT—CEA
`Task Force report. Value Health 2005;32521—33.
`4 ISPOR. Pharmacocconomic guidelines around the world. Avail-
`able item: http:.n'.lw\vw.ispor.orgI'PEguidclincsiindcx.asp [Accessed
`February 21, 2009].
`Hay]. Application of cost effectiveness and cost benefit analysis
`to pharmaceuticals. 1n: Santoro M, Corrie T, eds. The Grand
`Bargain: Ethics and the Pharmaceutical
`Industry in the let
`century. New York NY: Cambridge University Press, 2006.
`6 Hoyle M. Future drug prices and cost-effectiveness analyses.
`Pharmacocconomics 2008;26:589—602.
`7 Ramsey FP. A contribution to the theory of taxation. Econ j
`1927;37:47—61.
`S Danzon
`P. Neglected
`2007;449:176—9.
`9 Hay ], Y1: W. Drug patents and prices, can we achieve better
`outcomes? ln: Triplctt ], cd. Measuring the Prices of Medical
`Treatments. Washington, DC: Brookings Press, 1999.
`
`diseases:
`
`at what
`
`price? Nature
`
`6 r
`
`eport highlights areas of consensus as well as areas where con—
`tinued methodological development is needed.
`The Good Research Practices for Measuring Drug Costs in
`Cost Effectiveness Analyses Report is published in six parts based
`on analytic perspective. The next five articles in this issue of
`Value in Health report the issues and recommendations for phar—
`maceutical pricing from the different perspectives, including: 1)
`Societal [18]; 2) Managed care [19]; 3) Medicare, Medicaid, and
`other US Government Payers [20}; 4) Industry [21]; 5) EurOpean
`countries and other international country perspectives [22].
`These perspective-specific analyses are presented to provide guid-
`ance and recommendations on how to obtain and use appro-
`priate drug cost measurements when conducting economic
`evaluations of health-care interventiOns for different health-care
`decision-maker audiences.
`
`is over—
`task force report
`this initial
`We recognize that
`represented by topics relating to US payment and reimbursement
`issues. This happened despite strong efforts by the task force to
`recruit ISPOR members from all countries and regions and is not
`meant to give offense to anyone. The task force members serve as
`volunteers, and because of a large number of drug payment
`policy issues coming forward in the US context recently, there
`were more people motivated to address these topics. We certainly
`hope and expect that this is just the first chapter of an ongoing
`effort to assess drug cost evaluation issues globally and that
`future reports of the DCTF will be comprehensively representa»
`tive of global drug evaluation concerns, whether they be different
`countries,
`regions, stakeholder perspectives, methodological
`approaches, or other issues. We certainly encourage any reader
`who sees gaps that need to be addressed to join the DCTF and
`add their perspective in future reports.
`
`General Recommendations
`
`Although most of the Task Force’s recommendations are specific
`to each of the analytic perspectives that we focused on, there are
`some general recommendations that we believe apply to drug
`cosr measurement in any cost effectiveness analysis setting or
`application.
`
`1. More clarification of the "societai perspective” is needed.
`‘
`For CEAS of brand name drugs performed from a societal
`perspective, either CEA analysts:
`il use a cost that more
`accurately reflects true societal drug costs (e.g., 20-60% of
`average sales price), or whether that is unrealistic and not
`meaningful for decision-makers; or ii) refer to their analyses
`as conducted front a "limited societal perspective.”
`2. Drug cost values and measurements shouEd be tranSparent
`and made available to any reader or user of a CEA, with the
`data sources and rationale fully documented.
`3. One-way andlor threshold CEA sensitivity analyses should
`demonstrate how much higher/lower drug costs would have
`to be to alter pharmacoecononiic model conclusions.
`4. CEAs performed from a payer perspective should use drug
`prices actually paid by the relevant payer net of all rebates,
`copays, or other adjustments. When such price adjustments
`are confidential, the analyst should apply a generic average
`discount that preserves this confidentiality. As a corollary of
`this, when done from a government perspective, drug costs
`should be net of any sales tax, value—added tax, or other
`taxes that are direct revenue offsets to the payer. Program
`eligibility and coverage issues should be cleariy stated or
`referenced.
`
`5. For drugs that are off-patent or likely to be ofpratent in the
`near future, it is appropriate to consider multisource drug
`
`Page 4 0f 5
`
`Page 4 of 5
`
`

`

`J'SPOR Drug Cost Task Force Report Overview
`
`the value in health care? Value Health
`
`10 Hay J. Where's
`2006:9514}.
`11 Hay J. Prices and innovation in pharmaceuticals and biotechnol-
`ogy.
`ln: Farquhar I, Summers K, Sorkin A, eds. Research in
`Human Capital and Development, vol. 16, The Value of Innova-
`tion: impacts on Health, Life Quality, and Regulamry Research.
`Bingiey, UK: Emerald Group Publishing; 2003:81—99.
`12 Cutler DM, Rosen AB, Vijan S The value of medical spending in
`the United States, 1960—2000. N Eagl J Med 2006;353:920—7.
`13 Luce B, Mauskopf J, Sloan F, et al. The return on investment in
`health care: 1980—2060. Value Health 2006;9:146—56.
`14 Goldman DP, Jena AB, Philipson T, Sun E. Drug licenses: a
`new model for pharmaceutical pricing. Health All 2008;27:122—
`9.
`15 Posnet RA. The social costs of monopoiy and regulation. J Polit
`Econ 1975;83:307—28.
`16 PhRMA. R8CD spending by U.S. Biopharmaceutlcal companies
`reaches record $58.8 billion in 2007. Avaiiablc from: http:."."www.
`phrma.org/news_roomlpress_releaseslus~biopharrnaceutical_
`compsnies_r&dmspending_reaches_reeord_5SS.8_hill ion_in_
`2007] [Accessed June 12, 2009].
`17 Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services. National health
`expenditure historical data. Available from: \V\V\V.Cm5.lill§.govf
`
`EB
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`NationalHeaithExpcndDataI'OZ_NationalI-IealthAccounts
`Historicaiasp [Accessed june 13, 2009].
`Garrison LP, Manslcy EC, Abbott TA Ell, etal. Good research
`practices for measuring drug costs in cost-effectiveness analyses: a
`societal perspective: the ISPOR drug cost task force report—Part
`11. Value Health. In press.
`Mansley EC, Carroll NV, Chen KS, et al. Good research practices
`for measuring drug costs in cost effectiveness analyses: a managed
`care perspective: the ISPOR drug cost task force report—Part III.
`Value Health. In press.
`Muilins CD, Seal B, Seoane—Vazquez E, et :1]. Good research
`practices for measuring drug costs in cost effectiveness analyses:
`medicare, medicaid and other US government payers perspectives:
`The ISPOR drug cost task force report—Part IV. Value Health.
`In press.
`Mycka JM, Dellamano R, Kolassa EM, et a!. Good research
`practices for measuring drug costs in cost effectiveness analyses:
`an industry perspective:
`the ISPOR drug cost
`task force
`reporw-i’art V. Value Health, In press.
`Shi 1., Hodges M, Drummond M, et al. Good research practices
`for measuring drug costs in cost effectiveness analyses: an inter»
`national perspective: the ISPOR drug cost task force report—"Part
`Vl. Value Health. In press.
`
`Page 5 0f 5
`
`Page 5 of 5
`
`

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket