throbber

`Exhibit A
`
`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 1 of 38
`
`

`

`https://web.archive.org/web/20180517015601/https:/www.unifiedpatents.com/j
`oin/
`
`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 2 of 38
`
`

`

`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 3 of 38
`
`

`

`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 4 of 38
`
`

`

`
`Exhibit B
`
`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 5 of 38
`
`

`

`https://web.archive.org/web/20180517015604/https:/www.eff.org/files/2016/0
`1/26/hacking_the_patent_system_belcher_and_casey_updated_january_2016.pdf
`
`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 6 of 38
`
`

`

` HACKING
`
`THE PATENT SYSTEM
`A GUIDE TO
`ALTERNATIVE PATENT LICENSING
`FOR INNOVATORS
`
`UPDATED JANUARY 2016
`
`BY MARTA BELCHER AND JOHN CASEY
`JUELSGAARD INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY & INNOVATION CLINIC
`STANFORD LAW SCHOOL
`
`
`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 7 of 38
`
`

`

`Table of Contents
`
`Introduction to Alternative Patent Licensing…………………………………….1
`The Patent System Is Broken…………………………………………………………1
`Innovators Are Hacking the System to Use Patents for Good………………...1
`Opting Out of the Patent System May Not Solve the Problem…………..……3
`These Hacks Highlight the Need for Patent Reform…………………………..…4
`Defensive Patent Aggregators………………………………………………..………4
`Unified Patents………………………………………………......……………………..4
`Allied Security Trust (AST)………………………………………………………….…6
`RPX Defensive Patent Acquisition Network......................................………..…8
`Patent Pledges……………………………………………………………………….……10
`Defensive Patent License (DPL)…………………………………..……………..…10
`Open Invention Network (OIN) ……………………………………...……………12
`Google’s License on Transfer Agreement (LOT)…………………………….….13
`Twitter’s Innovator’s Patent Agreement (IPA).……………………………….…15
`The Patent Pledge……………………………………………………………………16
`Google’s Open Patent Non-Assertion (OPN) Pledge…………………………18
`Mozilla Open Software Patent License Agreement (MOSPL)……….........…19
`Individual Pledges……………………………………………………………………20
`Patent Troll Insurance…..………………………………………………………….……21
`Unified Patents ‘Protect: Membership with Insurance’……....……………..…22
`RPX Insurance Services.............……………………………………...……………24
`Association of National Advertisers (ANA) Insurance Program………….....26
`Comparison Tables………………………………………………………………………29
`Overview of Options………………….…………………………………………………30
`
`
`
`
`
`This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License
`
`
`
`i
`
`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 8 of 38
`
`

`

`Introduction to Alternative Patent Licensing
`
`
`The patent system is intended to incentivize innovation, but the current system often does the
`opposite. The traditional model of patent licensing—whereby a company pays a patent owner to
`license an invention that the company legitimately uses—has been hijacked by non-practicing
`entities (“patent trolls”) and other aggressive patent holders who assert overbroad patents that
`never should have been granted in the first place. Within this broken patent regime, companies
`are increasingly hacking the system—that is, finding alternatives to the traditional patent
`licensing model in order to both promote open innovation and protect the companies themselves.
`These strategies can be organized into three broad categories: (1) defensive patent aggregators,
`which pool member companies’ resources to defensively purchase patents for the group and to
`fight patent trolls; (2) patent pledges, whereby companies opt to openly and defensively license
`their patents to others; and (3) patent troll insurance. This paper provides a guide to these
`alternative patent licensing options for small companies and startups that care about protecting
`themselves and not making a broken patent system any worse.
`
`The Patent System Is Broken
`
`
`The core purpose of the patent system is to incentivize innovation. Patents give inventors
`monopolies over their inventions for a period of time in order to allow inventors to recoup the
`costs of R&D and to generate profits that reward inventors’ efforts—thereby encouraging future
`investments. In exchange, patentees dedicate their inventions to the public domain once their
`patents expire.
`
`Yet, in many high-technology industries today, the patent system is a scourge on innovation.
`Patent trolls buy overbroad patents, often from bankrupt companies, for the sole purpose of
`extorting licensing revenues from companies that are actually innovating and creating new
`products. Overworked patent examiners increasingly grant overbroad, obvious, and non-novel
`patents—particularly on software. Some companies aggressively assert their patent portfolios to
`keep legitimate competitors out of the market entirely. Small companies are particularly
`vulnerable, since the cost of fighting a lawsuit (even a flagrantly frivolous one) could easily put a
`startup out of business. Faced with the constant threat of crippling litigation, small companies
`often perceive their best—or only—option to be laying low and hoping to stay off patent
`holders’ radar.
`
`Innovators Are Hacking the System to Use Patents for Good
`
`
`Fed up with the patent mess left by Congress, the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office, and the
`courts, companies are collaborating to formulate private solutions. These patent licensing
`alternatives broadly fit into three categories: defensive patent aggregators, patent pledges, and
`patent troll insurance.
`
`Defensive patent aggregators use membership fees to purchase patents and give perpetual
`licenses to members so that future owners of the patents (should the organization subsequently
`sell the patents) cannot sue members for infringement. Defensive patent aggregators are different
`
`
`
`1
`
`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 9 of 38
`
`

`

`from trolls because they buy patents solely for defensive purposes and promise never to assert
`the patents they own. These organizations often also use membership fees to challenge patents
`that may be asserted against their members. Defensive patent aggregators include Allied Security
`Trust, which uses a bidding system to distribute the cost of purchasing each patent among the
`members who are most interested in each patent; RPX, which buys patents and patent rights on
`behalf of all of its members; and Unified Patents, which purchases and challenges patents in
`specific technology areas.
`
`Patent pledges are public commitments that companies make to license their patents in a manner
`that supports open innovation. By committing to the Defensive Patent License, for example,
`companies opt into a network in which each company has promised not to sue any other
`company in the network for patent infringement, except defensively. The Open Invention
`Network owns hundreds of patents that it licenses for free to any company that promises never to
`assert its own patents against Linux technology. Through the License on Transfer Agreement,
`participants agree to license their patents to all other participating companies, but each license
`only becomes effective if the patent is transferred to a third party. Companies can also make
`pledges unilaterally. For example, in its Innovator’s Patent Agreement, Twitter makes a
`commitment to its employee inventors that it will not make offensive use of any patent without
`the inventor’s permission. Other examples of unilateral pledges include The Patent Pledge,
`through which companies promise not to sue small startups for software patent infringement;
`Google’s promise through the Open Patent Non-Assertion Pledge not to assert certain patents
`against those who implement open source software; and Tesla’s opening of its patent portfolio to
`the public royalty-free.
`
`Two defensive patent aggregators—RPX and Unified Patents—as well as a professional
`organization for advertisers are now offering insurance to protect companies against the threat of
`patent troll litigation. Policyholders pay an annual premium, and if a patent troll sues, the
`insurance reimburses for certain defensive expenses, which may include litigation expenses, pre-
`litigation expenses, or settlement costs, depending on the policy. Insurance can provide much-
`needed predictability for companies that are worried about the sudden cash drain associated with
`a patent troll lawsuit—particularly small companies that could be crippled by such expenses. In
`many cases, insurance also provides the resources necessary to fight trolls on the merits rather
`than quickly settling a lawsuit just to avoid legal fees. Trolls often depend on the high cost of
`litigation to force their targets to settle, even when the trolls’ legal claims are dubious. For this
`reason, insurance that provides funds to defend a claim can help deter against troll lawsuits in the
`first place.
`
`Each option described in this paper has tradeoffs both for individual companies and innovation
`as a whole. Patent pledges, for example, make a powerful public statement about a company’s
`values, and can attract talent and publicity. On the other hand, pledging to openly license a patent
`might lower the patent’s market value and, consequently, the company’s value for potential
`buyers and investors. Defensive patent aggregators require annual membership fees that may be
`prohibitively expensive for some companies, but the licenses and patent intelligence services that
`come with membership may be well worth the cost for others. This paper explores these options
`and analyzes some of the drawbacks and benefits of each for small companies and startups, with
`
`
`
`2
`
`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 10 of 38
`
`

`

`
`
`the understanding that every company must consider its own unique situation in deciding
`whether to participate in any (or all) of these alternatives to traditional patent licensing.
`
`Opting Out of the Patent System May Not Solve the Problem
`Many of the patent licensing alternatives described in this paper—particularly patent pledges—
`assume that participants have obtained patents of their own. However, many innovators who
`have understandably lost faith in the patent system have opted out by declining to seek patents on
`their own inventions.
`
`There are many reasons that companies may opt out of the patent system. Obtaining a single
`patent can cost $20,000 in legal fees, if not more, and the process can take many years. Some
`conscientious employees may be reticent to patent their inventions and assign them to their
`employers out of fear that the patents will later be abused. Once a patent is obtained, asserting it
`offensively may reflect poorly on the company, alienating current and potential employees as
`well as the public. If the company were to fail, the patents would likely be sold, and might
`ultimately fall into the hands of a bad actor.
`
`However, for companies that are concerned with both self-preservation and furthering
`innovation, there may be some inherent benefits of obtaining patents in the first place:
`
`
`(cid:120) First, patents can be used defensively in infringement lawsuits brought by competitors.
`
`Defendants in patent infringement lawsuits can countersue the plaintiff for infringing one
`of the defendant’s own patents. This, of course, assumes that the plaintiff has products of
`its own that could infringe, which is not the case with many trolls or other non-practicing
`entities like universities—but it makes patents valuable for defending against litigious
`competitors as well as deterring lawsuits from competitors in the first place.
`
`(cid:120) Second, patenting an invention clarifies the prior art and can help prevent future patents
`
`on overbroad or obvious technologies. All patented inventions must be novel and non-
`obvious. When determining whether to grant a patent, patent examiners in the U.S. Patent
`and Trademark Office look for “prior art” that evidences that the technology had been
`invented before or is obvious in light of previous inventions. Patent examiners have
`limited time to conduct their research, however, and often miss important prior
`inventions. One of the most important sources for identifying prior art is other patents.
`Patenting an invention thus helps clarify who invented what, and can help to prevent bad,
`obvious, or overbroad patents from being granted in the future.
`
`(cid:120) Third, patenting an invention may help prevent others from claiming it as their own.
`
`Keeping an invention a trade secret rather than patenting it runs the risk that another
`company could independently invent and try to patent the same thing. (Patent law
`includes a prior use defense, but only if the original inventor was using the invention
`more than one year before the subsequent inventor filed its patent, and even then there are
`limitations to how the original inventor can use the technology.) Original inventors can
`also simply publicly disclose the invention without filing a patent application, which may
`serve as prior art to prevent others from patenting the disclosed invention.
`
`3
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 11 of 38
`
`

`

`
`For companies that choose to obtain patents rather than opting out of the patent system entirely,
`the alternative patent licensing options described in this paper provide opportunities both to
`engage with the patent system and to use patents for good.
`
`These Hacks Highlight the Need for Patent Reform
`
`
`The existence of these alternative patent licensing options does not supplant the need for patent
`reform; to the contrary, the necessity of these hacks demonstrates innovators’ continuing struggle
`to be free to operate. Rather than focusing their time, effort, and resources on innovating,
`companies are forced to turn to these options in an attempt to mitigate the damage caused by
`patent trolls and a broken patent system.
`
`Some of these alternative patent licensing options help to ensure that members’ own patents will
`not fall into the hands of trolls, some harness members’ collective buying power to limit the
`number of patents on the market available to trolls, and some use members’ pooled resources to
`challenge bad patents. However, none of these options can fully protect innovators from trolls. In
`order to completely address the problems driving innovators to turn to these patent system hacks,
`Congress must act.
`
`
`Defensive Patent Aggregators
`
`
`
`Defensive patent aggregators use the pooled resources of member companies to purchase patents
`that may otherwise have been purchased by trolls or aggressive companies and asserted against
`members. After purchasing each patent, aggregators grant perpetual licenses to their members, so
`that even if the patent later falls into a troll’s hands, the patent can never be asserted against
`those members. Some aggregators also challenge, invalidate, or amass prior art on patents that
`may be threats to members. Aggregators typically charge an annual membership fee that is
`calculated based on each company’s size. Many aggregators also offer patent intelligence and
`other services to members.
`
`
`
`
`Unified Patents
`What It Is
`
`
`Unified Patents is a subscription-based patent risk management organization. Unified identifies
`specific technology areas that it calls “Zones,” and works to monitor and defend each Zone’s
`technology from patent troll assertions. As of July 2015, Unified has five active Zones: cloud
`storage, content delivery, wireless, automotive, and electronic patents. Companies decide which
`Zones they would like to join and contribute annual membership fees in exchange for
`intelligence, statistics, legal support, and deterrence measures in those Zones. Smaller startups
`can join for free.
`
`Unified was founded in 2012 by former Intuit Head of Intellectual Property Litigation Kevin
`Jakel, with founding members including Google and NetApp.
`
`
`
`4
`
`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 12 of 38
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`How It Works
`
`
`For an annual subscription fee, companies join a Zone that focuses on protecting a particular
`technology area from patent trolls. Subscription fees vary based on the company’s size and the
`number of Zones the company seeks to join, but startups can join for free as of the time of
`writing. The cost of joining for non-startups ranges from $35,000 to $400,000 per Zone.
`
`Unified’s goal is to reduce the costs and risks associated with NPE activity in each Zone,
`ultimately deterring future troll assertions. Unified uses each Zone’s subscription fees to
`challenge troll-owned patents in the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office through ex-parte
`reexamination, inter partes review, and post-grant review proceedings, and to purchase patents
`before trolls can (but never to purchase patents from trolls). When Unified purchases a patent, all
`Zone members receive an immediate, perpetual license to that patent. Fees are also used to
`monitor troll activity, investigate prior art, and develop legal resources and acumen in certain
`technology areas.
`
`Unified’s belief is that the participation of startups helps everyone, with the understanding that
`small companies are often the first to receive troll demand letters and are often the most
`vulnerable targets. By encouraging startups to participate with low-cost (or free) membership,
`Unified gains valuable insight into troll demand letter campaigns as soon as they begin.
`Furthermore, when startups join Unified, they gain protection from certain troll demands,
`limiting the number of easy troll targets.
`
`In October 2015, Unified Patents launched its Protect: Membership with Insurance program,
`offering a new membership tier that includes patent troll insurance. This program is described on
`page 22 in the “Patent Troll Insurance” section.
`
`(cid:120) Unified encourages startups and small companies to participate by taking into account
`(cid:120) By including small companies and some of the world’s largest tech companies in each
`(cid:120) Unified focuses its efforts on specific technology areas, unlike defensive patent
`(cid:120) Unified makes all decisions regarding whether and when to challenge a patent in inter
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Pros
`
`company size in calculating membership fees, and (as of the time of writing) offering
`membership to some startups for free.
`
`
`Zone, startups benefit from larger companies’ monetary resources, while larger
`companies benefit from broader membership in the Zone, early insight into troll
`activities, and a stronger industry-wide deterrent effect.
`
`aggregators that broadly acquire any high-risk patents. This assures companies that
`operate in a specific technology space that their membership fees and resources are used
`to protect only what they care about.
`
`
`partes review. While this means that members do not have say in these decisions, it
`
`5
`
`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 13 of 38
`
`

`

`should allow members to benefit from inter partes review of dubious patents without
`becoming the “real parties-in-interest” in the review. A “real party-in-interest” in an inter
`partes review that reaches a final decision cannot later defend a patent infringement
`lawsuit using any argument that could have been raised during that inter partes review.
`
`members can be comforted that their membership fees will never, even indirectly, support
`troll activities. Furthermore, because Unified never pays trolls, it does not incentivize
`trolls to enter a Zone it protects.
`
`
`their own patents to other Zone members.
`
`Cons
`
`(cid:120) Unified refuses to pay trolls for patents, licensing, settlement, or any other activity, so
`(cid:120) Members do not give up any of their own patent rights, nor are they required to license
`(cid:120) The narrow, technology-specific Zone approach means that not all companies will fit
`(cid:120) Unified refuses to buy patents from trolls, so members do not benefit from potentially
`(cid:120) Compared to RPX, Unified currently has fewer patent assets and less patent-purchasing
`
`within one of Unified’s Zones of protected technology.
`
`dangerous patents being purchased directly out of trolls’ hands.
`
`activity.
`
`Allied Security Trust (AST)
`What It Is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Allied Security Trust (AST) acquires patents on behalf of its member companies based on a
`bidding system that distributes the cost of each patent among only those companies that are
`interested in purchasing it.
`
`AST has about 30 members. The publicly identified members include Google, IBM, Intel,
`Oracle, Philips, Cisco, Microsoft, Ford, and Sony.
`
`
`
`How It Works
`
`
`Companies pay an annual fee for AST membership. The annual fee is tiered based on company
`size, ranging from $25,000 for companies with up to $250 million in revenue, up to $200,000 for
`companies with more than $4 billion in revenue. Members have access to AST’s tool for
`analyzing available patents and can participate in collective purchases of assets in which they are
`interested.
`
`AST’s tool provides members with basic information about patent portfolios available for
`purchase, including the number of patent families in an available portfolio, the marketing
`
`
`
`6
`
`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 14 of 38
`
`

`

`materials provided by the seller, the technologies that the assets cover, and the products that they
`could potentially impact. AST holds calls with its member companies to review available assets
`that could be relevant to that member. After reviewing available patents, an AST member may
`decide to bid on the patents through AST, or seek to purchase them on their own or through an
`alternate channel. Without divulging identifying information, AST communicates common
`interest to other members to foster collaboration. Each member makes its own decision about the
`value of a patent license and provides a bid of that amount to AST. AST combines funds and
`uses as little of each member’s money as possible while still seeking to provide the seller a
`market rate. A typical AST purchase involves three or four member companies contributing to
`the cost of the patent. Members thus share the cost of acquiring useful patents while controlling
`the amount they bid and maintaining anonymity under most circumstances.
`
`Once a patent or portfolio is acquired, the AST members that funded the purchase receive a
`perpetual, irrevocable, non-exclusive license that continues even if the companies leave AST. A
`member company that did not participate in the initial acquisition may obtain a subsequent
`license through a Subsequent License Option (SLO). The licensing fee for an SLO is always
`equal to the highest price paid by one of the initial funders. The proceeds from the SLO are then
`given to the original bidders, allocated using a formula that pays back members that spent the
`most first. New members are allowed to take an SLO to any portfolio currently owned by AST.
`
`AST engages in a “catch, license, and release” model for patents rather than aggregating patents.
`AST purchases a patent, licenses it to members, and then sells the patent (with the licenses still
`binding all future owners), and distributes the proceeds among the members that funded the
`acquisition. AST does not take any commission through this process, nor does it charge members
`for its services in acquiring patents beyond the annual contribution.
`
`AST does not proactively challenge patents in U.S. Patent and Trademark Office proceedings,
`but it does intervene in active litigation upon member request.
`
`
`
`Pros
`
`the patents they want rather than paying for licenses in technology areas irrelevant to
`their businesses.
`
`If a member leaves AST, the patents they have licensed go with them, which gives
`companies flexibility to leave.
`
`
`(cid:120) AST avoids the “one size fits all” aggregation model by allowing members to bid only on
`(cid:120)
`(cid:120) AST purchasing decisions can move quickly, and the “delivery date” of a patent is within
`(cid:120) Members include some of the world’s largest tech companies, which means smaller
`(cid:120)
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`a few weeks of an accepted offer, which can be an advantage for fast-paced companies.
`
`
`companies can benefit from their purchasing power.
`
`In addition to getting a license to the patent, early bidders get money back when other
`member companies later license the patent, and when AST ultimately sells the patent.
`
`7
`
`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 15 of 38
`
`

`

`
`
`they required to license their own inventions to other members.
`
`Cons
`
`(cid:120) Members do not give up any of the rights to their own, non-AST patent portfolios, nor are
`(cid:120) For privacy-sensitive companies, AST conducts most of its transactions completely
`(cid:120) AST buys and sells patents on the open market, which means that AST may be feeding
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`anonymously. However, when AST sells patents on the open market, the name of the
`patent’s licensees can be disclosed to potential buyers against the member’s will (by a
`majority vote of other members licensed to that portfolio).
`
`patent trolls by buying patents from them, and that the patents AST owns may later fall
`into the hands of trolls. AST members that contributed to the purchase of those patents
`have perpetual licenses and cannot be attacked with these patents, but members with
`strong anti-troll convictions may take exception to the idea of indirectly doing business
`with trolls.
`RPX Defensive Patent Acquisition Network
`
`What It Is
`
`
`RPX is a membership-based patent risk management service that acquires patent rights to license
`to members for defensive purposes, provides patent intelligence, and offers insurance policies to
`cover the legal and settlement costs of being sued for patent infringement.
`
`RPX was founded in 2008 by John Amster and Geoffrey Barker, both former vice presidents of
`controversial patent assertion entity Intellectual Ventures. As of January 2016, nearly 250
`companies are members, including Google, Microsoft, Oracle, and Intel.
`
`
`
`How It Works
`
`
`Companies join RPX for an annual membership fee calculated based on the client’s annual
`financial results. As of 2014, annual fees ranged from $85,000 to around $7 million. Each
`member receives a license to all patent rights that RPX owns. These licenses last for as long as
`the company remains a member of RPX, with licenses becoming perpetual after a certain number
`of years of membership. Members do not give up any of their own patent rights, nor are they
`required to license their own patents to other members.
`
`As of March 2014, RPX had spent $810 million on acquiring patents and patent rights for its 178
`members. RPX purchases rights to high-value or high-risk patents on the open market—
`sometimes only buying licenses for its members, and sometimes acquiring the entire patent,
`which preempts trolls from buying the patent. RPX also buys patent rights out of active litigation
`in which its members are defendants. RPX claims to have prevented more than 3,000 lawsuits
`and claims to have intervened to secure dismissals for clients more than 800 times.
`
`
`
`8
`
`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 16 of 38
`
`

`

`
`
`RPX members also gain access to the RPX client portal—an online resource with detailed
`profiles of NPEs, overviews of the litigation history and chain of title of individual patents, and
`other market intelligence. In May 2014, RPX announced the launch of a free search engine that
`allows users to search RPX’s proprietary database for every U.S. patent and application, every
`U.S. district court patent litigation action since 2000, and every patent owner and party in
`litigation today. The tool also allows users to create custom alerts for patent troll activities.
`
`RPX’s insurance offerings are described on page 24 in the “Patent Troll Insurance” section.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`(cid:120) RPX not only purchases patents preemptively, but also intervenes in active litigation in
`(cid:120) RPX’s size gives it massive purchasing power to buy patents and license them to
`(cid:120) Members do not give up any of their own patent rights, nor are they required to license
`(cid:120) RPX’s online client portal is a useful tool, particularly for companies with in-house
`(cid:120) RPX appears to buy patents and patent rights from trolls, which members might find
`(cid:120) RPX sometimes sells patents (after licensing them to its members) and is willing to sell to
`(cid:120) Licenses only last for as long as a company remains a member of RPX—though licenses
`(cid:120) RPX’s business model is being challenged in court. A patent troll called Cascades
`
`Pros
`
`which clients are defendants.
`
`members. RPX claims to represent 10% of transaction activity on the open market. As
`RPX grows in size, so does its usefulness to its customers.
`
`their own patents to other members.
`
`attorneys. RPX’s free search engine offers a limited view into RPX’s database.
`
`
`Cons
`
`
`
`objectionable.
`
`trolls. While its members should be safe from these patents, all other companies—large
`and small—could be attacked by trolls armed with patents sold by RPX.
`
`become perpetual after a certain number of years of membership. Companies that choose
`not to renew membership before their licenses become perpetual may suffer some
`diminution of rights.
`
`Computer Innovation (CCI) sued RPX and some of its members alleging antitrust
`violations and a conspiracy to “monopsonize” the market (that is, drive down the prices)
`for certain patents. The judge tossed out CCI’s conspiracy allegations, but the antitrust
`claims survived a motion to dismiss, and a jury trial is tentatively scheduled for January
`2017. However, since CCI’s patent has been found not infringed in another lawsuit, it is
`
`9
`
`Bradium Exhibit 2049
`Unified Patents Inc. v. Bradium Technologies LLC
`IPR2018-00952
`Page 17 of 38
`
`

`

`(cid:120)
`
`possible that the judge will dismiss the lawsuit against RPX for lack of damages.
`
`It is troubling for one entity to own so many patents. While RPX has promised never to
`assert or litigate the patents in its portfolio, its business model could change, and it might
`assert its patents through shell companies in a manner similar to Intellectual Ventures.
`
`
`Patent Pledges
`
`
`Patent pledges are commitments that companies make to license their own patents in a particular
`way. Many of the pledges described in this paper are multilateral pledges through which
`companies opt into networks with other companies that have made the same pledge (for
`example, by promising not to offensively assert patents against any other member of the network
`that has made the same commitment). Pledges can also be made unilaterally, and any company
`can create its own pledge to license its patents in a way that benefits open innovation—for
`example, by promising that the company will never assert its employees’ patents offensively
`without each inventor’s permission. Pledges offer a way for companies to continue to patent their
`inventions while assuring the public—and potential employees—that their patents will be used
`responsibly.
`
`
`
`
`The Defensive Patent License (DPL)
`What It Is
`
`
`The Defensive Patent License (DPL) is like a non-aggression pact for patents: companies
`commit to never asserting any of their patents offensively against any other company that has
`also committed to the DPL.
`
`Berkeley Law Professor Jennifer Urban and New York University Law Professor Jason Schultz
`launched DPL 1.1 in November 2014.
`
`In the interest of full disclosure, representatives from Engine, the Electronic Frontier Foundation,
`and the Open Invention Network who participated in preparing this paper also serve on the DPL
`Advisory Board.
`
`
`
`How It Works
`
`
`Any company can opt into the DPL network by pledging never to assert any of its patents against
`any other company in the DPL network, except

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket