throbber
Document1
`
`4/21/201110:35 AM
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`M i c h a e l A b r a m o w i c z & J o h n F . D u f f y
`
`The Inducement Standard of Patentability
`
`a b s t r a c t . In Graham v. John Deere Co., the Supreme Court explained that patent law’s
`nonobviousness doctrine is meant to restrict the award of patents to only “those inventions
`which would not be disclosed or devised but for the inducement of a patent.” This Article argues
`that this inducement standard, largely ignored in practice, should serve as the doctrinal polestar.
`Such an approach would provide a solid economic foundation for the patentability standard and
`would align patent law with the many other fields of regulatory law that currently apply
`economic analysis in determining the scope and content of regulation. The Article also offers
`several refinements to the inducement standard and explains how the Patent and Trademark
`Office and courts could implement the inducement standard in an administrable way.
`
`
`a u t h o r s . Michael Abramowicz is Professor of Law, George Washington University. J.D.,
`Yale Law School. John F. Duffy is Oswald Symister Colclough Research Professor of Law,
`George Washington University. J.D., University of Chicago Law School. The authors would like
`to thank Beverly Chang, Ashkan Eshghi, and Alan Lau for research assistance, Ed Walterscheid,
`Arti Rai, and Ed Kitch, as well as participants in a University of Virginia workshop and a Federal
`Trade Commission-Department of Justice workshop. The authors also thank the Kauffman
`Foundation and the George Washington University Law School for financial support.
`
`
`
`
`1590
`
`
`Comcast - Exhibit 1027, page 1
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`the inducement standard of patentability
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`a r t i c l e c o n t e n t s
`
`introduction
`
`1593
`
`1603
`1603
`
`i. rehabilitating the inducement standard: a doctrinal
`foundation
`A. The Difficulties with a Cognitive Approach
`1. The Imaginary Person of Extraordinary Knowledge and Ordinary
`1605
`Creativity
`2. The Degree of Obviousness and the Commingling of Economic Factors 1608
`B. The Inducement Standard and the Statutory Text
`1612
`1. “Obvious” and Ease of Discovery
`1613
`2. “Ordinary” Skill
`1614
`3. The “Person” Who Possesses the Skill
`1615
`C. Reconciling the Patentability Standard with General Regulatory Theory
`1616
`D. Implications of the Inducement Standard
`1620
`1. Objectivity
`1620
`2. Trade Secrecy and Disclosure
`1622
`3. Nonpatent Inducements for Innovation
`1623
`
`ii. refining the inducement standard
`A. Time
`B. Competition
`C. Invention
`1. Speculative Patents
`2. Kitch’s Prospect Theory
`3. Merges’s Model of Nonobviousness
`
`iii. administering the inducement standard
`A. Methodological Questions
`1. Heuristics Versus Direct Application
`2. Courts Versus Agencies
`B. A Structured Economic Inquiry
`1. Obviousness of the Invention to a PHOSITA
`2. Secondary Considerations
`
`
`
`1625
`1626
`1632
`1642
`1643
`1647
`1650
`
`1655
`1657
`1657
`1659
`1662
`1663
`1669
`
`1591
`
`Comcast - Exhibit 1027, page 2
`
`

`

`
`
`the yale law journal
`
`
`
`1 2 0 : 1 5 9 0 2 0 1 1
`
`a. Considerations of Nonobviousness
`b. Considerations of Commercial Success
`c. Considerations of Obviousness
`
`conclusion
`
`
`1670
`1673
`1676
`
`1678
`
`1592
`
`
`Comcast - Exhibit 1027, page 3
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`the inducement standard of patentability
`
`The inherent problem was to develop some means of weeding out those
`inventions which would not be disclosed or devised but for the inducement of a
`patent.
`
` —A unanimous Supreme Court in Graham v. John Deere Co.1
`
`i n t r o d u c t i o n
`
`The quotation above is one of the most memorable and insightful lines
`from arguably the most important patent law case of the twentieth century: the
`Supreme Court’s 1966 decision in Graham v. John Deere Co.2 Graham’s
`preeminent place in the patent canon is well justified, for it is the Supreme
`Court’s seminal opinion on a patent law doctrine—the “nonobviousness”
`requirement—that is typically introduced as “the most important of the basic
`patent requirements,”3 “central to determining patentability,”4 “the key to
`defining what is a patentable invention,”5 or simply “the ultimate condition of
`patentability.”6 The basic rule of nonobviousness is easy enough to recite:
`under 35 U.S.C. § 103, a patent may not be granted on an invention that
`“would have been obvious at the time the invention was made to a person
`having ordinary skill in the art.”7 But the apparent simplicity of the
`requirement belies the complexities and difficulties that have historically
`bedeviled the doctrine.8 The inducement standard, as articulated in Graham,
`
`
`
`1.
`
`2.
`
`383 U.S. 1, 11 (1966).
`
`383 U.S. 1.
`
`3. ROBERT PATRICK MERGES & JOHN FITZGERALD DUFFY, PATENT LAW AND POLICY: CASES AND
`MATERIALS 643 (3d ed. 2007).
`
`4. Michael J. Meurer & Katherine J. Strandburg, Patent Carrots and Sticks: A Model of
`Nonobviousness, 12 LEWIS & CLARK L. REV. 547, 548 (2008).
`
`5. Alan L. Durham, Patent Symmetry, 87 B.U. L. REV. 969, 970 (2007).
`
`6. This phrase comes from the title of NONOBVIOUSNESS: THE ULTIMATE CONDITION OF
`PATENTABILITY (John F. Witherspoon ed., 1980), a prominent collection of articles
`celebrating the twenty-fifth anniversary of the codification of the obviousness doctrine in 35
`U.S.C. § 103 (2006). Other authors have since used the same phrase to describe the
`doctrine. See, e.g., Daralyn J. Durie & Mark A. Lemley, A Realistic Approach to the Obviousness
`of Inventions, 50 WM. & MARY L. REV. 989, 990 (2008).
`
`7.
`
`35 U.S.C. § 103(a).
`
`8. See, e.g., Durham, supra note 5, at 971 (“Obviousness is a difficult issue to resolve. It requires
`one to imagine how a claimed invention might have looked to a different person . . . at a
`different time . . . and without resorting to hindsight based on knowledge of the claimed
`invention . . . .”); Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Obvious to Whom? Evaluating Inventions from the
`
`
`
`1593
`
`Comcast - Exhibit 1027, page 4
`
`

`

`
`
`the yale law journal
`
`
`
`1 2 0 : 1 5 9 0 2 0 1 1
`
`appears to be vitally important to understanding the statutory nonobviousness
`requirement, for it offers a simple explanation for why society should deny
`patents on some innovations: if the innovation would be created and disclosed
`even without patent protection, denying a patent on the innovation costs
`society nothing (because the innovation would be developed anyway) and
`saves society from needlessly suffering the well-known negative consequences
`of patents, including the restriction on output caused by a patentee’s exclusive
`rights and the administrative and litigation costs associated with running a
`patent system.
`Yet despite its apparent promise as the theoretical basis for the most
`important patentability doctrine, Graham’s inducement standard has achieved
`only a modicum of influence.9 Though frequently cited, the inducement
`standard is often relegated to a passing mention or a footnote in introducing
`the patentability standard.10 Some articles have devoted more extended
`attention to the inducement standard, but these too have generally highlighted
`
`
`
`Perspective of PHOSITA, 19 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 885, 887 (2004) (stating that “the
`implementation of [the nonobviousness]
`standard poses certain administrative
`challenges”); Gregory Mandel, The Non-Obvious Problem: How
`the Indeterminate
`Nonobviousness Standard Produces Excessive Patent Grants, 42 U.C. DAVIS L. REV. 57, 59 (2008)
`(explaining that the indeterminacy of the nonobviousness standard results in too many
`patent grants even though “[t]he nonobvious standard is not simply too low, but both too
`high and too low. It is indeterminate.”); Joshua McGuire, Nonobviousness: Limitations on
`Evidentiary Support, 18 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 175, 175 (2003) (“To obtain a patent, one must
`have patentable subject matter that is useful, novel, nonobvious, and adequately described;
`however, the standard for a nonobvious invention is often difficult to apply.” (footnote
`omitted)).
`
`9. Some commentators, meanwhile, have criticized Graham for failing to articulate a clear test.
`T.J. Chiang, for example, notes: “The opinion gave all the appearance of expecting a
`solution to appear out of thin air once the formula was followed. The lack of an articulable
`rule meant that determinations of obviousness took the appearance—and arguably the
`reality—of resting on judicial whim . . . .” Tun-Jen Chiang, A Cost-Benefit Approach to Patent
`Obviousness, 82 ST. JOHN’S L. REV. 39, 49 (2008) (footnote omitted).
`
`10. For example, Rebecca Eisenberg begins the analysis in a recent article by noting: “In theory,
`[the nonobviousness] standard prevents the issuance of patents on inventions that,
`although new, are so close to the prior art that they are likely to be forthcoming even
`without the incentive of a patent.” Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Pharma’s Nonobvious Problem, 12
`LEWIS & CLARK L. REV. 375, 381 (2008). The footnote to that sentence quotes Graham’s
`articulation of the inducement standard, id. at 381 n.13, but inducement theory is never again
`mentioned in the remainder of the article. Similarly, Gregory Mandel quotes Graham’s
`inducement standard in a footnote. See Mandel, supra note 8, at 85 n.121. Yet Mandel
`describes the sentence from Graham as “dicta” and concludes that the Graham Court did not
`hold “that this is what the statutory nonobviousness standard actually measures.” Id.
`
`1594
`
`
`Comcast - Exhibit 1027, page 5
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`the inducement standard of patentability
`
`the difficulties in using the standard to decide cases or to shape legal doctrine.11
`For example, Ed Kitch’s classic verdict on Graham’s inducement standard
`emphasized that the nonobviousness requirement, as articulated by the courts,
`provides only an “awkward” tool “to sort out those innovations that would not
`be developed absent a patent system,” with the “focus” of the legal doctrine
`always being on other issues.12 Kitch’s view has become the consensus. Thus,
`in a widely cited and influential 2003 report, the Federal Trade Commission
`summarized the testimony of numerous legal and economics scholars as
`demonstrating that, even though the inducement standard represents “the
`right way to assess whether to grant a patent” from a “theoretical perspective,”
`the standard is not “administrable,” so “the more manageable standards of the
`patent statute have evolved to serve as the means by which to measure when to
`grant a patent.”13
`In some ways, we agree with these prior assessments of the inducement
`standard. There is a certain awkwardness in the relationship between the
`inducement standard and the nonobviousness requirement, at least as that
`requirement has previously been articulated by the courts. Moreover, the
`Supreme Court in Graham did not provide a rigorous foundation for deriving
`the inducement standard from the statutory language. The absence of such a
`legal foundation may explain why courts and the Patent and Trademark Office
`(PTO) have typically avoided looking to the inducement standard for guidance
`in interpreting and applying the statutory nonobviousness requirement. The
`one exception, an insightful but ultimately flawed panel opinion by Judge
`Posner, relied on the inducement standard to invalidate a patent but
`nevertheless failed to identify any administrable test or metrics for applying the
`inducement standard to the specific facts of that case or other cases.14 Posner’s
`
`
`
`11. Glynn Lunney considers the inducement standard in his treatment of obviousness doctrine,
`but in his view the lack of “empirical evidence [for] determining the point at which a patent
`becomes necessary to induce desirable invention” is a stumbling block to using the
`inducement standard more extensively in crafting patentability doctrine. Glynn S. Lunney,
`Jr., E-Obviousness, 7 MICH. TELECOMM. & TECH. L. REV. 363, 416 (2001). Similarly, Samuel
`Oddi has provided a treatment of inducement theory. A. Samuel Oddi, Un-Unified Economic
`Theories of Patents: The Not-Quite-Holy Grail, 71 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 267, 277-81 (1996).
`But he views the theory as merely one of several competing theories of the patent system, see
`id. at 268-71, and he does not attempt to refine the obviousness doctrine to conform to an
`inducement standard.
`
`12. Edmund W. Kitch, Graham v. John Deere Co.: New Standards for Patents, 1966 SUP. CT.
`REV. 293, 301.
`
`13. FED. TRADE COMM’N, TO PROMOTE INNOVATION: THE PROPER BALANCE OF COMPETITION
`AND PATENT LAW AND POLICY ch. 1, at 11 (2003).
`
`14. See infra notes 112-135 and accompanying text.
`
`
`
`1595
`
`Comcast - Exhibit 1027, page 6
`
`

`

`
`
`the yale law journal
`
`
`
`1 2 0 : 1 5 9 0 2 0 1 1
`
`panel opinion was vacated en banc,15 and that history has perhaps cemented the
`notions that the inducement standard conflicts with the statutory obviousness
`standard, is antipatent, or is simply too difficult to apply in actual cases.
`This Article aspires to show those notions to be wrong and to revitalize the
`inducement standard as the touchstone for understanding and refining the
`obviousness doctrine. The result should be more coherent, defensible, and
`predictable decisionmaking than is possible either under the current doctrine
`or under Judge Posner’s treatment, which missed important implications of the
`inducement standard.
`There are two motivations for undertaking this project. First, the time is
`right. In its 2007 decision KSR International Co. v. Teleflex, Inc.,16 the Supreme
`Court overturned a quarter-century-old test for nonobviousness that the
`nation’s expert appellate court for patent law, the Court of Appeals for the
`Federal Circuit, had meticulously constructed. The KSR decision has
`precipitated a vibrant debate among scholars seeking to help the courts rebuild
`a pragmatic obviousness doctrine that yields predictable answers and is more
`theoretically sound than the Federal Circuit doctrine rejected in KSR.17 That
`reconstruction project can have little hope of enduring success without
`
`
`15. See Roberts v. Sears, Roebuck & Co., 697 F.2d 796 (7th Cir.), vacated en banc, 723 F.2d 1324,
`1329 (7th Cir. 1983).
`
`16. 550 U.S. 398 (2007). The Court rejected the Federal Circuit’s test as excessively rigid and
`formalistic. Id. at 419. The Supreme Court explained that “familiar items may have obvious
`uses beyond their primary purposes, and in many cases a person of ordinary skill will be
`able to fit the teachings of multiple patents together like pieces of a puzzle,” precluding
`bright-line tests. Id. at 420.
`
`17. See, e.g., Durie & Lemley, supra note 6, at 998 (arguing for a more realistic inquiry into
`obviousness, and noting that “[i]n KSR, the Supreme Court ostensibly made the
`obviousness inquiry more ‘flexible’ and pragmatic”); Eisenberg, supra note 10 (analyzing the
`effect of KSR on the application of the nonobvious standard to pharmaceutical patents);
`Jeanne C. Fromer, The Layers of Obviousness in Patent Law, 22 HARV. J.L. & TECH. 75, 76
`(2008) (discussing the proper object of the nonobviousness inquiry and stating that
`“[d]espite this overarching purpose [of encouraging innovation] highlighted in KSR,
`neither courts nor scholars have analyzed or settled on the obviousness inquiry’s object, that
`is, the thing which must be nonobvious”); Meurer & Strandburg, supra note 4, at 548, 551
`(measuring the effect of the nonobvious standard on the “choice of research projects” and
`stating that “[t]he KSR decision clears the way for new thinking about the obviousness
`issue, which, despite its importance, is surprisingly under-theorized”); Joseph Scott Miller,
`Remixing Obviousness, 16 TEX. INTELL. PROP. L.J. 237, 240 (2008) (discussing the impact of
`KSR on the concept of the person having ordinary skill in the art and advancing a
`“framework for determining whether a combination claim is nonobvious”); Joshua D.
`Sarnoff, Bilcare, KSR, Presumptions of Validity, Preliminary Relief, and Obviousness in Patent
`Law, 25 CARDOZO ARTS & ENT. L.J. 995, 1036 (2008) (“Whatever the legal or factual status
`of the obviousness inquiry, KSR has enormous importance as it has clearly raised the bar for
`determining when inventions are non-obvious and thus patentable.”).
`
`1596
`
`
`Comcast - Exhibit 1027, page 7
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`the inducement standard of patentability
`
`reexamining and reevaluating the ultimate goal of the nonobviousness
`requirement.
`A second and more important motivation is the promise of the inducement
`standard in providing significant insights into some of the most difficult
`theoretical and practical problems in the field. Economic analysis of patent law
`frequently begins with the assertion that patents present a social tradeoff
`between providing incentives for innovation at the expense of accepting the
`deadweight loss associated with monopoly-like exclusive rights.18 And even
`beyond the law-and-economics literature, legal scholars often frame intellectual
`property law generally and patent law in particular as presenting a conflict
`between the public and private domains—a choice between openness and
`exclusivity.19 If, however, the law follows Graham’s inducement standard, such
`tradeoffs and conflicts do not necessarily exist.
`Under a rigorously enforced inducement standard, patents would cover
`only those innovations that otherwise would not be created or disclosed—in
`
`
`
`18. See, e.g., WILLIAM D. NORDHAUS, INVENTION, GROWTH, AND WELFARE: A THEORETICAL
`TREATMENT OF TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE 76 (1969) (creating a model for calculating
`optimal patent term by balancing increased incentives for innovation against greater
`deadweight loss); Richard Gilbert & Carl Shapiro, Optimal Patent Length and Breadth, 21
`RAND J. ECON. 106, 106 (1990) (referring to “the conventional analysis of optimal patent
`length, based on the tradeoff between the incentives for innovation and the extent of static
`monopoly deadweight loss”).
`
`19. See, e.g., James Boyle, The Second Enclosure Movement and the Construction of the Public
`Domain, 66 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS., Winter-Spring 2003, at 33, 38 (describing the “limits
`to intellectual property rights” as the “antierosion walls around the public domain” and
`more generally arguing that expansions of intellectual property rights erode the public
`domain); Niva Elkin-Koren, What Contracts Cannot Do: The Limits of Private Ordering in
`Facilitating a Creative Commons, 74 FORDHAM L. REV. 375, 375 (2005) (noting the effect of the
`expansion of intellectual property rights on the contraction of the public domain); Christine
`D. Galbraith, A Panoptic Approach to Information Policy: Utilizing a More Balanced Theory of
`Property in Order To Ensure the Existence of a Prodigious Public Domain, 15 J. INTELL. PROP. L.
`1, 4 (2007) (advocating for a more accessible public domain because “[u]nfortunately, the
`public domain appears to be diminishing as the recent trend in formulating information
`policy is to utilize an organizing concept of private property ownership”); Pamela
`Samuelson, Enriching Discourse on Public Domains, 55 DUKE L.J. 783, 791 (2006)
`(acknowledging the tension between intellectual property rights and protecting the public
`domain and quoting International News Service v. Associated Press, 248 U.S. 215, 250 (1918)
`(Brandeis, J., dissenting) (“The general rule of law is, that the noblest of human
`productions—knowledge, truths ascertained, conceptions, and
`ideas—become, after
`voluntary communication to others, free as the air to common use.”)); John R. Therien,
`Exorcising the Specter of a “Pay-Per-Use” Society: Toward Preserving Fair Use and the Public
`Domain in the Digital Age, 16 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 979, 1035 (2001) (arguing that “the
`judiciary must protect the public domain and fair use, whether impinged upon by
`technology-derived statutory rights or the technology itself”).
`
`
`
`1597
`
`Comcast - Exhibit 1027, page 8
`
`

`

`
`
`the yale law journal
`
`
`
`1 2 0 : 1 5 9 0 2 0 1 1
`
`other words, patents would cover only innovations that, without the patent
`system, would not have been in the public domain. The patent system would
`then have only positive effects on the public domain: patents would cover only
`inventions that would otherwise not be in the public domain and, when the
`patents expire, the inventions would enter into and enrich the public domain.
`Similarly, the apparent deadweight losses created by patent rights would be an
`illusion because, if patent rights had not been available, the invention would
`not have been available from competing firms but instead would have been
`either unavailable or covered by trade secrecy. As we will show in this Article,
`the optimal implementation of the inducement standard may not achieve such
`a Panglossian resolution because, at least in some circumstances, patents
`should be allowed even if they merely induce earlier innovation. Thus, the
`analysis suggested by the inducement standard helps to identify more clearly
`the precise economic tradeoff at issue: patents produce earlier innovation but at
`the cost of higher prices and associated deadweight loss in a later period (when
`the invention would have existed even without the inducement of the patent).
`This point highlights another deep theoretical strength of the inducement
`standard, for it holds out the hope of grounding patentability decisions in a
`more rigorous economic framework and thereby bringing patent law closer to
`the vast body of modern regulatory law that commonly uses economic analysis
`in making specific decisions about the scope and extent of regulation.
`The Article’s rehabilitation of the inducement standard begins, in Part I,
`with an investigation of doctrinal difficulties associated with Graham’s
`inducement standard. As Professor Kitch noted over forty years ago, the
`nonobviousness requirement seems at first to be an awkward way to
`implement an inducement standard. We agree that perhaps one natural
`interpretation of the statutory text points toward a cognitive definition of
`nonobviousness that focuses on whether individuals have epistemic awareness
`of technological solutions to problems. In embracing the inducement standard
`as the ultimate theory underlying nonobviousness, the Graham Court
`embraced an economic definition of nonobviousness and implicitly rejected a
`cognitive approach in interpreting the statute. The Court, however, failed to
`provide a sufficient legal justification for that interpretation, and that failure
`has almost certainly made courts and lawyers wary of placing too much
`reliance on the theoretical standard. Yet establishing a legal justification for the
`inducement standard is not so difficult. The statute itself sets the obviousness
`standard by reference to a highly fictional concept, the “person having ordinary
`skill in the art.”20 Defining that fictional person’s abilities by reference to
`
`
`
`20. 35 U.S.C. § 103(a) (2006).
`
`1598
`
`
`Comcast - Exhibit 1027, page 9
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`the inducement standard of patentability
`
`economic incentives rather than technological cognition is no more radical than
`the now-familiar use of economics to define the behavior of the fictional
`reasonable person in tort law.21
`The awkwardness of the inducement standard is, however, only partially
`remedied by the development of a more rigorous legal basis justifying the use
`of the standard in patentability determinations. Part II of the Article introduces
`ambiguities, puzzles, and other difficulties associated with the inducement
`standard. Because the inducement standard has not been taken seriously in the
`past, these ambiguities and difficulties have not been resolved. Our analysis
`leads to three necessary clarifications of Graham’s inducement standard.
`First, Graham’s articulation of the inducement standard may be fairly
`criticized for treating a fundamentally dynamic issue—invention—as if it were
`static, with no time frame specified or implicit. Graham’s inducement standard
`asks which inventions would be devised and disclosed even without the
`inducement of a patent, but it is silent on the crucial question: devised and
`disclosed by when? Even with no patent system, it is hard to imagine that
`many inventions would remain undevised and undisclosed forever. Thus, if the
`Graham inducement standard were interpreted as trying to identify “those
`inventions which would not [ever] be disclosed or devised but for the
`inducement of a patent,”22 then almost nothing would be patentable. On the
`other hand, if the inducement standard were interpreted as trying to identify
`“those inventions which would not [immediately] be disclosed or devised but
`for the inducement of a patent,”23 almost everything would be patentable
`because patent law presumably provides at least marginal incentives for
`inventing earlier. Both extremes must be wrong. We show that Graham’s
`inducement standard is best interpreted as requiring patents to cover only
`those inventions that, but for the inducement of a patent, would not have be
`disclosed or devised for a substantial period of time. Our reformulation
`produces a dynamic inducement standard, which is consistent with the
`growing body of literature that views the patent system as attempting not so
`much to increase but to accelerate invention.
`A second insight relies upon an important feature of the patent system:
`competition. The modern patent system does not grant monopolies to industry
`participants that the sovereign happens to favor. Rather, patents are awarded
`competitively, and the competition to obtain patents has
`important
`implications for the practical enforcement of the patentability standard. Our
`
`
`
`21. See, e.g., United States v. Carroll Towing Co., 159 F.2d 169 (2d Cir. 1947).
`
`22. Graham v. John Deere Co., 383 U.S. 1, 11 (1966).
`
`23. Id.
`
`
`
`1599
`
`Comcast - Exhibit 1027, page 10
`
`

`

`
`
`the yale law journal
`
`
`
`1 2 0 : 1 5 9 0 2 0 1 1
`
`dynamic adjustment to the inducement standard introduces the concept of a
`“substantial period of time,” which naturally leads to the question of just how
`substantial a time period is necessary. Yet the competitive structure of the
`patent system makes the answer to that question less important than it first
`seems. The strong incentives of the patent system, coupled with the
`competition to obtain patents, should substantially accelerate the time of
`innovation, often by a period longer than the patent term itself, except in
`certain specific circumstances—the circumstances that make a patent-
`motivated innovator insignificantly better (that is, insignificantly earlier) than
`an innovator not motivated by the patent system. Those circumstances can
`serve as proxies for the inducement standard so that, by looking for such
`circumstances, government officials and judges can identify inventions not
`induced by the patent system without invoking any complex models of
`technological acceleration. These circumstances include a rapid decline in the
`cost of innovation, for example, because of the development of a technology
`that is an input into the new technology, or a positive demand shock shortly
`before invention, especially where multiple firms respond to the shock by
`developing the technology and even more so if some of those firms do not
`appear to be patent-motivated.
`A third and final clarification to Graham’s inducement standard resolves the
`ambiguity in the concept of “invention.” Once it is recognized that the
`inducement standard must be interpreted dynamically—so that the inquiry is
`whether the inducement of the patent accelerated the arrival of the invention—
`then a crucial question becomes: what precisely must be accelerated, the
`conception of an invention or its practical, commercial implementation? Our
`conclusion is that Graham’s standard should be interpreted as requiring the
`inducement of an earlier arrival of the commercialized invention, not merely
`the “invention” in theory or on paper in a patent disclosure. A contrary
`approach would induce what we call “speculative patents”—patents that
`describe possible future applications of embryonic technologies. Such
`speculative patents, if they were to be allowed, might have a high option
`value—they would be valuable if technological development takes a particular
`course. But if the patents do little or nothing to advance the actual arrival of
`new technology in practical terms, then they would have little or no social
`value.
`This third clarification to the inducement standard provides insight into
`what has so far been a muddled debate about the meaning and desirability of
`so-called patent trolls. The term “patent troll” has been generally, if somewhat
`loosely, defined in the literature as a “nonpracticing entity,” an entity that has
`
`1600
`
`
`Comcast - Exhibit 1027, page 11
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`the inducement standard of patentability
`
`technology.24 Such
`its patented
`never commercialized or “practiced”
`nonpracticing entities have generated enormous controversy in recent years
`and, as the label “troll” suggests, some patent practitioners have a visceral sense
`that, at least in some circumstances, such nonpracticing entities stand in the
`way of true innovators. But under orthodox patent doctrine and theory, it
`should not matter whether an entity practices a patent, because the quid pro
`quo of the patent is said to encompass merely the disclosure in the patent
`document. Our approach to the Graham inducement standard shows why it
`can matter whether an entity is practicing its invention: while a nonpracticing
`patentee might accelerate the actual practice of an invention, it is difficult to
`believe that has happened if other parties have independently invented and
`commercialized the technology without even planning to seek patent
`protection. Such circumstances would seem to be powerful evidence that the
`inducement of the patent was unnecessary to generate the invention and thus
`that the patent may be invalid under the inducement standard.
`While Parts I and II are devoted to resolving the previously perceived legal
`and theoretical awkwardness of the inducement standard, Part III focuses on
`the other major criticism of the standard—that it is unadministrable. Many
`doctrines of patent law can be subjected to the simplistic objection that they
`lack mathematical precision, and prior approaches to the nonobviousness
`standard have been especially vulnerable to such attacks. A reinterpreted
`inducement standard need not demonstrate perfection. It can be an
`administrative success if it is even just a bit better than current doctrine as a
`helpful theoretical and pragmatic guide for applying the obviousness doctrine.
`We believe that the inducement standard easily satisfies that test. As a
`theoretical matter, the inducement standard provides a sound basis for
`interpreting “the person having ordinary skill in the art” not only as a person
`possessing technological knowledge but also as someone who is responsive to
`both economic incentives and economic limitations. Those economic incentives
`and limitations not only help to answer the previously intractable question of
`how obvious something must be to be obvious under the statute; they also help
`to unify patent law with bodies of regulatory law as diverse as common law
`torts, antitrust law, and modern federal administrative law. Beyond its
`
`
`24. Peter Detkin, former assistant general counsel of Intel, claims to have created this term in
`2001 while describing companies that do not create patents but rather buy them and then
`demand unusually high license fees by threatening costly litigation in the alternative. See
`Peter N. Detkin, Leveling the Patent Playing Field, 6 J. MARSHALL REV. INTELL. PROP. L. 636,
`636 (2007). The broadest definition describes a patent troll as an entity that extracts profits
`by offering a target entity an option of purchasing a license or facing litigation. See Thomas
`S. Kim & Michael D. Stein, Patent Value: Increased Interest Extends Beyond ‘Trolls,’ LEGAL
`INTELLIGENCER, May 23, 2005, at IP3.
`
`
`
`1601
`
`Comcast - Exhibit 1027, page 12
`
`

`

`
`
`the yale law journal
`
`
`
`1 2 0 : 1 5 9 0 2 0 1 1
`
`theoretical successes, the inducement standard can also be a practical success.
`For example, it provides concrete guidance for how the nonobviousness
`standard should apply in fields like software, in which the costs of achieving
`any particular innovation may fall over time25 and mechanisms other than
`patents (such as copyright protection) are likely to provide very significant
`inducements for innovation. The inducement standard suggests that patent
`e

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket