throbber
ABA Section of Intellectual Property Law
`
`Landslide Magazine
`
`Thinking Economically about Commercial Success
`
`By R. DeForest McDuff, Ryan C. Andrews, and Matt D. Brundage
`
`R. DeForest McDuff, PhD, is a partner at Insight Economics; he is an expert in applied business
`economics and provides expert witness testimony on intellectual property and other areas. Ryan C.
`Andrews is a former senior associate at Intensity; he has extensive experience evaluating lost profits.
`reasonable royalties, commercial success, and other areas. He is currently pursuing his MBA at The
`Wharton School at the University of Pennsylvania. Matt D. Brundage is an analyst at Intensity; his
`experience includes economic research and analysis for commercial success, reasonable royalties. and
`other economic damages. They may be reached, respectively, at deforest@insighteconomics.com,
`ryanandr@wharton.upenn.edu, and matt.brundage@intensity.com. The opinions expressed are those of
`the authorts) and may not reflect the views of their employers. clients, or any of their respective
`affiliates. This article is for general information purposes and is not intended to be and should not be
`taken as legal advice.
`
`Economic experts frequently evaluate commercial success as a secondary consideration of the obvious-
`ness of a patented invention.l While other common economic inquiries are often based on widely recog-
`nized methodologies (e.g., the Panduit factors for lost profits, the Georgia-Pacific factors for reasonable
`royalties), experts often base analysis of commercial success on a layperson's notion of "success," with-
`out appreciation of its purpose. For example, an expert may conclude that a product is a commercial
`succms because sales and profits are “large" or "substantial,” appealing to preconceived notions of suc-
`cess in other contexts (“sales of $100 million a year? .
`.
`. sounds like a success to me!”).
`
`We should be wary of such simplistic approaches to evaluating commercial success, which often fail to
`ask a fundamental economic question: success compared to what? Just as one individual's success in
`life may differ from another's, commercial success for one product in a particular context may differ
`from commercial success for another product in another context. Improper analysis of commercial suc-
`cess can be particularly problematic in pharmaceuticals, for example, which often require billions of
`dollars in sales for economic incentives to have existed for others to bring the product to market sooner.
`Evaluations of commercial success without proper context (or. for some experts, without any context at
`all) are unhelpful to the role of commercial success in patent litigation.
`
`Recent case law has clarified the purpose of commercial success and what it is intended to demonstrate.
`For example, the Federal Circuit stated in Merck u. Teoa that commercial success is relevant “because
`the law presumes an idea would successfully have been brought to market sooner, in response to market
`forces. had the idea been obviousto persons skilled in the art."2 This makes sense, from an economic
`perspective, because other parties would have economic incentives to commercialize obvious inventions
`
`Published in Landslide Magazine, Volume 9, Number 4. ©2017 by the American Bar Association. Reproduced with
`permission. All rights reserved. 111i; information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or
`by any means or stated in an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consenl of the American
`Bar Association.
`
`Page 1 of 7
`
`WATSON LABORATORIES v. UNITED THERAPEUTICS, IPR201T-01621
`
`UNITED THERAPEUTICS, EX. 2078
`
`

`

`ABA Section of Intellectual Property Law
`
`landslide Magazine
`
`if there were economic incentives to do so. However. based on our experience evaluating dozens of
`expert reports on commercial success. all too often experts fail to provide relevant context and/or tie
`any alleged success back to the fundamental purpose outlined by the courts.
`
`This article summarizes challenges and shortcomings with common approaches to evaluating commer-
`cial success. and offers guidance for providing appropriate economic analysis. We draw upon numerous
`expert evaluations of commercial success. with a focus in pharmaceuticals and electronics, to provide
`practical insights on commercial success for both plaintiffs and defendants.
`
`Overly Simplistic Analysis of Commercial Success
`Overly simplistic evaluations of commercial success frequently fail to provide suflicient information and
`analysis to conclude that economic incentives existed to bring the product to market sooner. Such
`analysis often simply tabulated; sales. profits, and market shares, followed by some grand conclusion on
`whether those constitute commercial success. Very little is said for whether sales are sufficient to com-
`pensate for the economic costs needed to develop the product and bring it to market. Experts often fail
`to compare sales and profits from the product in question to other comparable products in the industry.
`even though millions of dollars in one market might be successful in one industry and an utter failure in
`another.
`
`In our experience. this kind of analysis is too often set forth as alleged evidence of commercial success.
`This overly simplistic approach to evaluating commercial success often misses the economic purpose of
`commercial success in informing on obviousness. Analyses rooted in a layperson's notion of success are
`not necessarily unscientific or false—rather. they simply fail to connect with the purpose of the commer-
`cial success established by the courts.
`
`
`
`Overtime. courts have clarified the purpose of commercial success in evaluating a patent‘s obviousness.
`Dating back to Smith v. Goodyear Dental (1376), the Supreme Court grappled with how to determine
`whether a new product was a legitimately novel invention.3 The Court indicated what might be learned
`from one product displacing others previously used fur the same purpose. establishing the relevanCe of
`a product's market performance. but provided no clear economic standard for what kind of displace-
`ment would be informative.4 The Supreme Court later identified commercial success as a secondary
`consideration for nonobviousness in Graham v. John Deere (1966).5 a role that was strengthened upon
`establishment of the Federal (fircuit in 1982.6 One scholar suggested that commercial success was
`transformed “from a tiebreaker to a virtual trump card.” Most recently. the Federal Circuit stated in
`Merck u. Tenn (2005) (citing to Graham 1;. John Deere) that '[c]ommercial success is relevant because
`the law presumes an idea would successfully have been brought to market sooner. in response to market
`forces. had the idea been obvious to persons skilled in the art."8
`
`Merely reporting sales or market shares in a vacuum misses the point of a commercial success analysis
`as explained by the courts. Net sales or market shares in isolation tell us very little about whether mar-
`ket forces would have existed for other companies to have responded by bringing the product to market
`sooner. As one author noted: "For commercial success to be persuasive, a patentee must do more than
`show sales or market share data for her patented product. (Although. under some older cases, this was
`
`Published in landslide Magazine. Volume 9. Number 4. @017 by the American Bar Association. Reproduced with
`pcrmission. All rights reserved. 'l11is information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or
`by any means or stored in an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American
`Bar Associlnion.
`
`UNITED THERAPEUTICS, EX. 2078
`WATSON LABORATORIES v. UNITED THERAPEUTICS, |PR2017-01621
`Page 2 of 7
`
`

`

`r,__._
`
`ABA Section of intellectual Property Law
`
`Landslide Magazine
`
`enough)."9 Rather, commercial success should inform on whether sales and profits provide objective
`evidence on whether material economic incentives (i.e., “market forces”) would have incentivized oth-
`ers to bring the product to market, had the invention been obvious. Other economists and scholars
`agree that this is, in essence. the fundamental purpose of commercial success analysis."1| Said another
`way. ideas are brought to market when there is a profit opportunity, not merely when sales or market
`shares are “high” or “substantial” in some abstract sense.
`
`Economic Analysis of Commercial Success
`A better approach to evaluating commercial success focuses on factors that are economically relevant
`for its purpose. While each analysis will be unique and specific to the facts of the particular case, some
`principles can provide guidance to improve putting forth or rebutting evidence of commercial success.
`This section elaborates on several such factors: (1) comparisons to relevant benchmarks, (2) compar-
`isons to commercialization costs, (3) evaluation of market shares, and (4) evaluation of the inferential
`limitations of any alleged commercial success.
`
`Comparisons to Relevant Benchmarks
`One useful measure in evaluating commercial success is a comparison of sales to relevant benchmarks
`in the industry—for example: average product sales, sales of competitors, and projectioas of potential
`sales. This provides guidance on what level of sales or revenues in the field are typical, sought. and
`expected, and would yield an economic profit for a particular industry at a particular point in time.
`
`In the pharmaceutical industry, for example, economic literature provides context on the range of drug
`sales by drug type [e.g., cardiovascular, neurologic, etc.) and time period. For drugs launched from 1990
`to 1994, anesthetic drugs earned $556 million over the product life cycle, on average, compared to more
`than $2 billion for anti-infective drugs and more than $3 billion for cardiovascular drugs." Economic
`research examining drugs by decile (i.e., lst docile from goth percentile to ggth percentile, 2nd decile
`from 80th percentile to 89th percentile) often provides additional context for where a drug fits into the
`broader industry.l2 Notably. research indicates that only the top three deciles of drugs tend to be eco-
`nomically profitable. and that an average drug tends to yield close to break-even or even negative prof-
`its.'3 All else equal, it is unlikely that a drug with sales below an average drug would be a commercial
`success."
`
`All too often, experts assert that sales are “high” in some abstract sense (even with little or no profit).
`without evaluating what sales might have been expected or what sales have been earned by competitor
`products. By adding comparisons to the types of benchmarks described herein. sales can be evaluated in
`proper context and better inform whether material economic incentives for development existed.
`
`Comparisons to Commercialization Costs
`Another useful but often overlooked measure in evaluating cammercial success is a comparison to com-
`mercialization costs for a product. Properly evaluated, including economic costs associated with actual
`expenditures, costs of capital, risk, and uncertainties, comparisons to commercialization costs can pro-
`vide information for whether sales and profits are sufficient to generate an economic return on invest-
`ment—in other words. a material economic incentive for others to bring the product to market. For
`
`Published in Landslide Magazine. Volume 9. Number 4. ©2017 by Ihe American Bar Association. Reproduced with
`penuission. All fights reserved. ‘ihis information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or
`by any means or stored in an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American
`Bar Association.
`
`WATSON LABORATORIES v. UNITED THERAPEUTICS, IPR2017-01621
`Page 3 of 7
`
`UNITED THERAPEUTICS, EX. 2078
`
`

`

`ABA Section of Intellectual Property Law
`
`,
`
`Landslide Magazine
`
`example, some economists argue that "commercial success could in principle be defined by a single cri-
`' teriou: Does the patented invention earn a positive net return (risk-adjusted) on invested capital after
`accounting for all relevant costs associated with developing and commercializing the patent as well as
`any alternatives available to the patent holder?"15 Techniques such as net present value analysis can be
`helpful for comparing sales over time with costs associated with commercialization.
`
`In the pharmaceutical industry. a number of authors have determined that the cost of bringing a new
`pharmaceutical product to market exceeds $1 billion (and more than $2 billion based on estimates for
`more recent products).'6 These costs include out-of-pocket expenses of development and clinical trials,
`the cost of capital over time, and the risk of nonapprova] (in which case all expenditures would be
`wasted), all of which are expected and considered when evaluating products in the pharmaceutical
`industry.” If a drug product does not earn revenues and profits that sufficiently compensate pharma-
`ceutical companies for significant economic costs in bringing a product to market, that product will tend
`not to he a commercial success, all else being equal.13
`
`Despite the economic foundation and connection to material economic incentives, experts frequently
`fail to take into account the costs of deveIOpment and commercialization when evaluating commercial
`success.‘9 By adding comparisons to potential costs of commercialization described herein, sales and
`profits can be evaluated relative to the expense and investment required to bring the product to market.
`providing further evidence on material economic incentives for commercialization.
`
`Evaluation ofMorket Shores
`Market shares are a factor frequently considered by experts in evaluating commercial success. because
`they provide implicit comparisons to competitor products. However. the interpretation of market shares:
`can be difficult. For example. experts are often pressed at deposition to define what market share would
`provide a global cutoff for a commercially successful product (e.g.. "Is it 5 percent? to percent? 25 per-
`cent? 50 percent”). The answer, because of how market shares are defined, is often: it depends.
`
`For example, a 5 percent share of one market might be commercially successful. whereas a 20 percent
`share of another market might not be. The former market might be significant and commercialization
`costs may below. whereas the second market might be smaller and commercialization costs may be
`high. As another example, a product may have a very high revenue share but a very low quantity share
`due to factors like patent protection of competitors (e.g.. branded versus generic pharmaceuticals}. Try-
`ing to define an absolute cutoff for what market share. in the abstract, denotes a commercial success is a
`futile exercise.” Experts often disagree about market definition—ta. which products define competi-
`tion and which do not—yet the market definition and market share are interrelated. It is the overall con-
`text. rather than a particular market share per se. that defines whether market shares are interpreted as
`persuasive evidence of commercial success.
`
`Unlike the other economic factors described thus far. market shares are less directly connected to
`whether material economic incerrtives existed to bring the product to market sooner. Yet they can. at
`times. provide insight on the market opportunity for an invention and. in that sense. may inform on
`incentives to bring a product to market sooner when other information is less concrete.
`
`Published in landslide Magazine, Volume 9. Number 4. ©2017 by the American Bar Association. Reproduced with
`permission. All rights reserved. This information or any portion Ihereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or
`by any means or stored in an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American
`Bar Association.
`
`Page 4 of 7
`
`UNITED THERAPEUTICS, EX. 2078
`WATSON LABORATORIES V- UNITED THERAPEUTICS, |PR2017-01621
`
`

`

`
`
`ABA Section of Intellectual Property Law
`
`Landslide Magazine
`
`Economic Relevon cc of Com mercial Success
`Finally, a thoughtful analysis of commercial success may consider whether any alleged success, if it
`exists, is relevant for evaluating the existence of material economic incentives to bring a product to mar»
`ket sooner. There are circumstances where even sales and profits that might normally be sufficient to
`generate economic interest in the product (e.g., a potential commercial opportunity) might not be infor-
`mative on obviousness at the time of the invention because of other factors.
`
`For example, the presence of blocking patents or regulatory exclusivity often limits the economic rele-
`vance of commercial success. In this case, incentives for development may only exist for the party with
`that exclusivity and not for the market more generally. In Merck 1:. Terra, the plaintiff argued that Fos-
`amax, the patented product in question, was commercially successful.m The Federal Circuit agreed. but
`found that Merck’s earlier patent (a so-called “blocking patent” that blocked others from commercializ-
`ing a Fosamax product) limited the economic relevance of commercial success because other parties in
`the market could be blocked from bringing the product to market.“ The court stated: "Because market
`entry by others was precluded on those bases, the inference of non-obviousness .
`.
`. from evidence of
`commercial success, is weak."23
`
`As another example, there may be contemporaneous evidence around the time of the invention that
`shows a lack of commercial interest, even if the product later turns out to be commercially successful. In
`such a situation, sales and profits may provide limited evidence on whether material economic incen-
`tives existed to bring the product to market sooner, above and beyond the contemporaneous evidence
`already demonstrating this directly.
`
`In summary, experts can often benefit from asking whether commercial success, even if it exists. is rele-
`vant in evaluating the existence of material economic incentives around the time of the invention and,
`in turn, in evaluating obviousness of a particular patent at issue.
`
`Conclusion
`
`.
`
`While the purpose of commercial success has been established for some time, too often we see basic
`principles being misapplied, misunderstood. or not acknowledged at all. Evaluating "success" in a vac-
`uum. without proper context or benchmarks for comparison, can result in a flawed and misguided
`analysis. There is, of course, no single set of factors that are dispositive on commercial success in every
`situation. but providing additional context relating to the purpose of commercial success (i.e.. whether
`sales and profits demonstrate material economic incentives existed to have brought the product to mar-
`ket sooner) appears to be a step in the right direction. Success, both in business and in life, requires an
`understanding and appreciation for what is meant to be achieved.
`
`Endnotes
`
`1. Commercial sucmss is one of several secondary considerations intended to inform on whether a
`particular technology is obvious—Le, whether it differs enough from prior art in order to qualify as a
`patentable invention—which are often evaluated when defendants challenge a patent's validity in patent
`litigation. Because obviousness is the most common basis for finding that a patent is invalid, commer—
`
`Published in landslide Magazine. Volume 9. Number 4, ©2017 by the nmerican Bar Association. Reproduced with
`permission. All rights reserved. This informalion or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or
`by any means or stored in an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American
`Bar Association.
`
`WATSON LABORATORIES V. UNITED THERAPEUTICS, IPR2017-01621
`Page 5 of 7
`
`UNITED THERAPEUTICS, EX. 2078
`
`

`

`ABA Section of Intellectual Property Law
`
`Landslide Magazine
`
`cial success can play an important role. For discussion and references. see Andrew Blair-Stanek, Profits
`as Commercial Success, 1 17 YALE LJ. 642. 646 (2008); and Rebecca S. Eisenberg. Obvious to Whom?
`Evaluating Inven tions from the Perspective ofPHOSITA. 19 BERKELEY TECH. 1...]. 885, 885 (2004).
`2. Merck 8: Co. v. Teva Pharm. USA. Inc.. 395 F.3d 1364, 1376 (Fed. Cir. 2005).
`3. Smith v. Goodyear Dental Vulcanile Co.. 93 0.8. 436. 495 (1876).
`4. Id. at 495—96, cited in Blair-Stanelc, supra note 1, at 647.
`5. Graham v. John Deere (20.. 383 U.S. 1, 17—18 (1966) ("Such secondary considerations as commer—
`cial success. long felt but unsolved needs. failure of others. etc.. might be utilized to give light to the cir-
`cumstances surrounding the origin of the subject matter sought to be patented. As indicia of
`obviousness or nonobviousness, these inquiries may have relevancy.").
`6. Blair~Stanek. supra note 1. at 647—48; seeGraham. 383 US. at 11.
`'7. Robert P. Merges. Commercial Success and PatentStondara‘s: Economic Perspectives on Innova-
`tion. 76 CAL. L. Rev. 803. 827 (1988).
`_
`B. Merck 8: Co. v. Teva Pharm. USA, Inc.. 395 F.3d 1364, 1376 (Fed. Cir. 2005).
`9. Merges. supra note 7, at 823.
`10. Jesse David 8: Marion 3. Stewart. Commercial Success: Economic Principles Applied to Patent
`Litigation, inEconomc APPROACHES TO lmuscruat PRorr-zmv: Poucv. Lineman, AND MANAGE—
`MENT 196—99 (Gregory K. Leonard 8: Lauren J. Stiroh eds., 2005) ("A patented invention should be con-
`sidered a commercial success if it can be shown to have earned, or can reasonably be expected to earn, a
`positive net return on invested capital after accounting for all relevant costs associated with develop-
`ment and commercialization .
`.
`. 3'); Blair-Stanek. supra note 1. at 649 (“The potential for commercial
`success presumably provides incentives for others to try to perfect the invention. and the failure of oth-
`ers to do so suggests nonobviousness. Put most simply, the classical theory-based argument goes. ‘if an
`invention is both obvious and lucrative, why wasn't it thought of earlier?"): Rahul Guha et al.. The Eco—
`nomics ofCommerciai Success in Pharmaceutical Patent Litigation, 1 LANDSLIDE, no. 5, Manyune
`2009, at 8 (“From an economic perspective. commercial success supports a conclusion of nonobvious-
`ness because it suggests that an economic incentive existed to produce the invention”).
`11. Joseph DiMasi et al.. RM) Costs and Returns by Therapeutic Category. 38 DRUG INFO. J. 211, 219
`[2004)-
`12. Henry Grabowslti et al.. Returns on Research and Development for 19903 New Drug Introduc-
`tions. 20 PHARMACOECONOMICS 11. 17. 22 (Supp. 3 2002).
`13.1o‘. at 17. 23; Ernst R. Berndt et al.. Decline in Economic Returnsfrom New Drugs Raises Ques-
`tions about Sustaining Innovations, 34 HEALTH AFF. 245. 245, 252 (2015).
`14. Skeptics might question why so many unprofitable drugs are brought to market. Reasons may
`vary. of course. but one impactful factor is the uncertain process of clinical trials and FDA approval
`occurring over many years. Once a company incurs sunk costs of development and clinical trials, it may
`be worthwhile to proceed to the market, even if the product never recoups all of those sunk costs.
`15. David 82 Stewart. supra note 10. at 196.
`16. For sources and discussion, see Joseph DiMasi et al.. Innovation in the Pharmaceutical Industry.-
`New Estimates of12er Costs, 47 J. HEALTH Econ. 20 (2016). For a variety of other sources and refer
`811685 over time. see JORGE MES'I'RE-MRANDIZ ET AL, OFFICE OF HEALTH ECON., THE REID COST OF A
`New MEDICINE 1-86 (2012}; Joseph A. DiMasi 8: Henry G. Grabowski. R&D Costs and Returns to New
`Drug Development: A Review of the Evidence. inTHE OXFORD HANDBOOK OF THE ECONOMICS OF THE
`Bloruamaceuncar. INDUSTRY 29 (Patricia M. Danzon 3: Sean Nicholson eds, 2010); Joseph A. DiMasi
`
`Published in Landslide Magazine, Volume 9. Number 4. ©2017 by the American Bar Association. Reproduced with
`permission. All rights reserved. This infonnation or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or
`by any means or stored in an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American
`liar Association.
`
`Page 6 of 7
`
`UNITED THERAPEUTICS, EX. 2078
`WATSON LABORATORIES v- UNITED THERAPEUTICS, IPR201T-01621
`
`

`

`
`
`ABA Section of Intellectual Property Law
`
`Landslide Magazine
`
`at al.. The Price ofInnovation : New Estimates ofDrug Development Costs, 22 J. HEALTH Econ. 151, 151
`(2003); Joseph A. DiMasi 8: Henry G. Grabowski, The Cost of Biopharmaceutical RM): ls Biotech Dif-
`ferent?, 28 MANaGERtAL 81 DECISION Econ. 4159, 477 (2007); and Grabowski et al., supra note 12.
`17. SeeMEsrRE-FERRANDIZ Er AL, supra note 16; Biblical et al.. Innovation in the Pharmaceutical
`Industry, supra note 16; DiMasi et al., The Price oflnnouation, supra note 16; Grabowski et al., supra
`note 12.
`
`18. Interestingly, some authors have argued that pharmaceutical products may be commercially suc-
`cessful even when they do not generate a positive return on investment, because there may still be some
`therapeutic value associated With their use. See,e.g., Guha et 31., supra note 10, at 11—12 n.10 (“[A] lack
`of positive return on capital investment should not necessarily undermine a conclusion of commercial
`success. A few 'blockbuster' drugs generate the majority of profits for the drug companies. That means
`the majority of smaller drugs may ,not be profitable in the sense of recouping all the costs of their dis-
`covery and development, even it' they have proven therapeutic value“). However. products may he ther—
`apeutically valuable or desirable Without being commercially successful and sufficient to provide
`incentives to bring products to market sooner.
`19. While the costs of commercialization are often not available in historical records, either due to the
`passage of time or nonspecific attribution of costs to a particular product, we have had success linking
`the facts and circumstances of a particular product to peer-reviewed published literature on commer-
`Cialization costs, accounting for time of launch, therapeutic category, and the actual duration of clinical
`costs.
`
`20. See, e.g., David 8: Stewart, supra note 10, at 196 ('However, under certain circumstances. rapid
`sales growth and gains in market share will not necessarily reflect a profitable underlying invention").
`21. Merck 8: Co. v. Teva Pharm. USA. Inc., 395 F.3d 1364, 1376 (Fed. Cir. 2005).
`22.1d. at 1376—77.
`23.1ci. at 1377.
`
`Published in Landslide Magazine. Volume 9. Number 4. ©2017 by the American Bar Association. Repioduced with
`tnrmission. All rights reserved. This iniomiation or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or
`by any means or stored in an electronic database or retrieval system willnout the express written consent of 1 he American
`Bar Association.
`'
`
`UNITED THERAPEUTICS, EX. 2078
`
`
`
`WATSON LABORATORIES v. UNITED THERAPEUTICS, IPR2017-01621
`
`Page 7 of 7
`
`
`
`

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket