throbber
TCHICAGO
`
`
`Jr"
`
`'1' II Ii
`
`1.
`
`in. W 5 (1 H0012.
`
`Q THE UNIVERSITY HF EHIL‘AEI] PRESS lEIIJHNAlE
`
`The Booth School of Business. University of Chicago
`
`Does Intellectual Property Restrict Output? An Analysis of Pharmaceutical Markets
`
`Author(s): Darius Lakdawalla and Tomas Philipson
`
`Source: The Journal 01" Law & Economics, Vol. 55, N0.
`
`1 (February 2012), pp. 151-187
`
`Published by: The University of Chicago Press for The Booth School of Business,
`
`University of Chicago and The University of Chicago Law School
`Stable URL: http=//www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/6633‘15
`Accessed: 14-12-2017 19:14 UTC
`
`LTSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
`
`range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
`
`facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about TSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
`
`Your use of the TSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
`
`http://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`The University of Chicago Law School, The Booth School of Business, University of
`Chicago, The University of’ Chicago Press are collaborating with ISTOR to digitize,
`preserve and extend access to The Journal of Law & Economics
`
`
`
`J STOR
`
`This content downloaded from 430.121.19 on Thu, 14 Dec 2017 19: 14:29 UTC
`All use subject to http://ab0ut.jstor.org/terms
`
`Argentum Pharm. LLC V. Alcon Research, Ltd.
`Case lPR2017-01053
`
`ALCON 2076
`
`

`

`Does Intellectual Property Restrict Output?
`An Analysis of Pharmaceutical Markets
`
`Darius Lakdawalla University of Southern California
`Tomas Philipson University of Chicago
`
`Abstract
`
`Standard analysis of intellectual property focuses on the balance between in-
`centives for research and the welfare costs of restraining output through mo-
`nopoly pricing. We present evidence from the pharmaceutical industry that
`output often fails to rise after patent expirations. Patents restrict output by
`allowing monopoly pricing but may also boost output and welfare by improving
`incentives for marketing, a form of nonprice competition. We analyze how
`nonprice factors such as marketing mitigate and even offset the costs of mo-
`nopoly associated with intellectual property. Empirical analysis of pharmaceu-
`tical patents suggests that, in the short run, patent expirations reduce output
`and consumer welfare by decreasing marketing. In the long run, patent expi-
`rations benefit consumers, but by 30 percent less than would be implied by the
`reduction in price alone. Focusing only on the pricing issues of intellectual
`property may lead to incomplete or even inaccurate conclusions for welfare.
`
`1. Introduction
`
`Intellectual property (IP) spurs innovation by increasing the rewards for dis-
`covery, but it does so by granting a monopoly in the event of discovery. According
`to standard analysis (see Nordhaus 1969), the research and development (R&D)
`benefits of a patent system must be weighed against the associated output lost
`to patent monopolies, which reduce price competition. This analysis implies that
`patent expirations always lead to increased competition, lower prices, and higher
`market output. From this point of view, Figure 1 is surprising. The figure depicts
`
`For helpful comments and suggestions, the authors would like to thank Jay Bhattacharya, Richard
`Manning, and Richard Wang along with seminar participants at the University of Chicago, University
`of California, Los Angeles, the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Health Care Program
`meetings, the NBER Summer Institute, and the Southern Economic Association meetings. We are
`grateful to the National Institute on Aging (Lakdawalla) and the George J. Stigler Center at the
`University of Chicago (Philipson) for financial support.
`
`[Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 55 (February 2012)]
`䉷 2012 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0022-2186/2012/5501-0006$10.00
`
`151
`This content downloaded from 4.30.121.19 on Thu, 14 Dec 2017 19:14:29 UTC
`All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`

`

`152
`
`The Journal of LAW& ECONOMICS
`
`Figure 1. Effect of patent expirations on quantity sold, for a sample of prescription drugs
`
`the percentage change in quantity—comparing the month before patent expi-
`ration with the month after—for a sample of U.S. pharmaceutical products whose
`patents expired between 1992 and 2002.1 For about 40 percent of drugs, output
`falls after patent expiration and expands only modestly for many others.
`Figure 1 suggests that there may be more to a patent expiration than the end
`of monopoly pricing alone, and consequently more to the welfare effects of IP
`protection. We argue that the standard analysis of IP must incorporate various
`aspects of nonprice competition, which may reinforce or mitigate the effects of
`monopoly pricing. For example, while monopolists have incentives to restrict
`quantity through higher prices, they may also have different incentives to pro-
`mote their product through advertising, to provide durability of goods, and to
`vertically integrate with upstream or downstream firms. These forms of nonprice
`competition can change the efficiency impact of IP regulations by either miti-
`gating or reinforcing the conventional effects on price competition.
`Motivated by this idea, we examine the effect of marketing—a particularly
`important form of nonprice competition—on the static and dynamic efficiency
`
`1 To be specific, Figure 1 shows the percentage decline or growth in prescriptions filled (in grams)
`between the month before and the month after expiration. More detail on the data is given in Section
`3.2.
`
`This content downloaded from 4.30.121.19 on Thu, 14 Dec 2017 19:14:29 UTC
`All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`

`

`Intellectual Property and Pharmaceutical Markets
`
`153
`
`Figure 2. Mean trends in price and quantity for fully advertised drugs
`
`of patents.2 Patent expirations decrease the private returns to marketing, which
`may be limited when goods are sold at marginal cost. As a result, expirations
`may actually reduce output if they decrease marketing effort by enough to offset
`the impact of price reductions. From a normative point of view, advertising by
`a monopolist is valuable because it moves output toward its efficient level.
`Notably, this is true even if advertising is purely persuasive and provides no
`valuable information to consumers.
`To assess the importance of these arguments more fully, we estimate the impact
`of marketing on welfare using patent expirations in the U.S. pharmaceuticals
`market between 1990 and 2003. This industry is a natural choice for empirical
`analysis of R&D and marketing because it is among the highest spending in-
`dustries in both categories. The industry spends approximately 15 percent of
`sales on marketing and 16 percent of sales on R&D.3 By comparison, about 2
`and 3 percent of U.S. gross domestic product are allocated to advertising and
`R&D, respectively.
`Figures 2 and 3 provide some illustrative data from the pharmaceutical in-
`
`2 Different forms of nonprice competition merit separate analyses. For example, monopoly has a
`range of possible effects on quality provision. Mussa and Rosen (1978) show that monopolists will
`overdifferentiate their product and induce a lower quality choice by consumers. Subsequent authors
`have demonstrated how these results can be altered or even reversed under different specifications
`for demand (Gabszewicz and Wauthy 2002).
`3 Many drugs have seen dramatic increases in direct-to-consumer (DTC) advertising since the
`change in Food and Drug Administration guidelines on such advertising in 1997.
`
`This content downloaded from 4.30.121.19 on Thu, 14 Dec 2017 19:14:29 UTC
`All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`

`

`154
`
`The Journal of LAW& ECONOMICS
`
`Figure 3. Mean trends in price and quantity for drugs not fully advertised
`
`dustry. The figures are based on data—described in Section 3.2—from 101 mol-
`ecules with expiring patents. Each figure depicts monthly time series, relative to
`the month of patent expiration, for branded quantity, branded price, total quan-
`tity, and total price, at the molecule level. Figure 2 depicts these trends for
`molecules that are advertised, while Figure 3 does so for molecules that are not.4
`For all drugs, price declines steadily after the month of patent expiration. For
`the nonadvertised drugs, quantity rises fairly steadily over this period as well.
`However, for the advertised drugs, quantity appears flat after patent expiration.
`This suggests that patent expirations have different effects for advertised drugs
`than for their nonadvertised peers.
`To estimate these effects more formally, we use the timing of patent expirations
`as instruments for the price and incentives of a molecule. Changes in supply
`induced by patent expiration allow us to identify the demand for drugs as a
`function of both price and advertising effort. The estimated demand function
`implies that in the short run (the first 5 months), output decreases after patent
`expiration because the reduction in advertising more than offsets the reduction
`in price. This output loss is estimated to cost consumers roughly $1 million per
`month for each drug whose patent expires. Not until several years have elapsed
`
`4 Figures 2 and 3 show the percentage change between the month of patent expiration and the month
`shown on the x-axis. In all cases, price is per gram. A fully advertised drug has at least 1 month of
`nonzero samples dispensed, at least 1 month of nonzero promotional visits to doctors, and at least 1
`month of nonzero medical journal advertisements. Drugs that do not meet these criteria are considered
`to be not fully advertised. The figures are discussed in more detail in Section 3.3.
`
`This content downloaded from 4.30.121.19 on Thu, 14 Dec 2017 19:14:29 UTC
`All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`

`

`Intellectual Property and Pharmaceutical Markets
`
`155
`
`does the price effect dominate the reduction in advertising. In the long run,
`patent expiration increases quantity and benefits consumers, but the reduction
`in advertising reduces the total gain to consumers from patent expiration by
`about 30 percent. However, even from a long-run perspective, monopoly mar-
`keting provides benefits to consumers. We estimate that, even if advertising is
`purely persuasive and provides no valuable information, the value to consumers
`is roughly 20–25 percent of total monopoly revenue, roughly on par with the
`costs of marketing to firms. Therefore, even if firms did not benefit from mar-
`keting at all, it would be no worse than welfare neutral.
`Our project integrates a great deal of work that has separately considered
`advertising and intellectual property.5 Several papers have studied the unique
`aspects of pharmaceutical advertising: Rosenthal et al. (2002) study direct-to-
`consumer advertising, while Bhattacharya and Vogt (2003) consider how brand
`loyalty affects pricing under IP. In the economic analysis of IP, an equally ex-
`tensive literature tackles the question of how to generate efficient R&D effort.
`There is a large literature analyzing the effects and desirability of public inter-
`ventions affecting the speed of technological change.6 Less effort has been devoted
`to studying the joint problem of advertising and IP, even though the interaction
`between these two factors has many important normative and positive impli-
`cations, particularly for the marketing of pharmaceuticals in the United States.
`The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 considers the impact of nonprice
`competition on the welfare effects of patents and outlines the full impact of
`patents on static and dynamic welfare. Section 3 estimates demand as a function
`of price and advertising and infers changes in welfare from marketing and patent
`expiration. Section 4 concludes and discusses future research.
`
`2. Marketing and Intellectual Property
`
`From a positive point of view, IP protection has ambiguous effects on quantity
`provided, depending on the strength of incentives to market. Normatively, the
`static costs (or benefits) of patents depend on whether patent protection moves
`quantity toward or past the efficient level.
`
`2.1. The Welfare Effects of Patents
`
`W
`W
`as the annual level of aggregate welfare (social surplus)
`and
`Define
`C
`M
`under monopoly and competitive provision of an invention, respectively. The
`
`5 Kaldor (1949) provides a seminal analysis of advertising along both positive and normative
`dimensions. Dixit and Norman (1978) and Telser (1962) provide an initial discussion of the meta-
`preference approach to welfare analysis of advertising developed formally and systematically by Becker
`and Murphy (1993). There are also summary treatments of advertising in Tirole (1988), Shapiro
`(1982), Schmalensee (1987), and Bagwell (2005).
`6 Representative treatments include Nordhaus (1969), Loury (1979), Wright (1983), Judd (1985),
`Gilbert and Shapiro (1990), Klemperer (1990), Horstman, MacDonald, and Slivinski (1985), Gallini
`(1992), Green and Scotchmer (1995), and Scotchmer (2004).
`
`This content downloaded from 4.30.121.19 on Thu, 14 Dec 2017 19:14:29 UTC
`All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`

`

`156
`
`The Journal of LAW& ECONOMICS
`
`net present value of welfare associated with a patent of length t years is then
`given by
`
`W(t) p n(t)W ⫹ [n(⬁) ⫺ n(t)]W .
`
`M
`
`C
`
`n(t)
`is the date-zero present value of a claim that pays $1 for t years. The
`Here,
`net present value of profits associated with this patent is given by
`p(t) p n(t)p ,M
`represents monopoly profits. To represent technological investment
`where
`pM
`induced by IP protection, define the increasing, differentiable, and strictly con-
`cave function
`as the probability of discovering an invention, as a function
`m(r)
`of R&D investment r. The privately optimal R&D associated with a patent of
`length t maximizes expected profits:
`r(t) p arg max m(r)p(t) ⫺ r.
`
`(1)
`
`r
`
`This implies that increases in the profits expected from discovery also stimulate
`marketing activity, because innovators expect greater rewards (Nordhaus 1969).
`Therefore, innovation is complementary with all investments that stimulate prof-
`its, including marketing.
`This level of R&D induces the expected social surplus:
`ES(t) p m[r(t)]W(t) ⫺ r(t).
`
`(2)
`
`t
`
`r
`
`t
`
`The dynamically optimal patent length that maximizes expected welfare is there-
`fore given by the following first-order necessary condition:
`r [mW(t) ⫺ 1] ≥ m(⫺W ).
`The marginal gains from increasing R&D levels through IP (the left-hand side)
`are made up of the extra R&D induced by the patent extension,
`, multiplied
`rt
`mW(t) ⫺ 1
`by the net social value of that extra R&D,
`, which consists of the
`r
`marginal social gain from more invention net of research spending. The optimal
`patent life equates this marginal benefit of an extension with the marginal cost
`of the extension, which is the welfare cost of an additional year of monopoly
`(on the right-hand side). The marginal cost of patent expiration—the loss of
`welfare once the technology has been discovered—is given by the static welfare
`effect,
`
`(3)
`
`dW dnp (S ⫹ p ⫺ S ),
`dt
`dt
`
`M
`
`C
`
`M
`
`where SM and SC are consumer surplus under monopoly and competition, re-
`S ⫹ p ! S
`spectively. Patents are costly on the margin whenever
`; this is the
`M
`M
`C
`condition for static deadweight loss from monopoly. Below we demonstrate that
`marketing lowers the relative cost of patents and that it can sometimes lower
`cost to zero or below. In such cases, infinite patent length is desirable.
`
`This content downloaded from 4.30.121.19 on Thu, 14 Dec 2017 19:14:29 UTC
`All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`

`

`Intellectual Property and Pharmaceutical Markets
`
`157
`
`2.2. Positive Effects of Advertising under Patent Monopoly
`
`We first show that advertising limits and sometimes fully offsets the quantity-
`restricting effects of patent monopoly. Consider the standard monopoly profit-
`maximization model:7
`
`max Q(p, A)p ⫺ MC # Q(p, A) ⫺ A.
`
`p, A
`
`For simplicity, consider the constant elasticity demand function, Q(p, A) p
`␧ ⫺gA p
`. Monopoly equilibrium with advertising exists and is well defined when
`0 ! ␧ ! 1
`.8 The
`g 1 1
`demand is elastic to price and inelastic to advertising:
`and
`optimal price is given by the standard Lerner markup condition:
`
`[p]:p p
`
`cg
`g ⫺ 1
`
`.
`
`The first-order condition for optimal advertising equates the marginal value of
`marketing to its marginal cost, according to
`
`[A]:
`
`dQ
`dA
`
`(p ⫺ c) p 1.
`
`This expression demonstrates why perfectly competitive firms have no incentives
`to advertise. Without a markup, it is not valuable to stimulate more quantity.
`Using the constant elasticity form, the first-order condition for advertising
`can be rewritten as
`
`⫺g
`
`␧p (p ⫺ c) p A .
`
`1⫺␧
`
`Combining the two first-order conditions, the equilibrium level of advertising
`1⫺␧A p ␧c [1/ (g ⫺ 1)]
`is given by
`. The monopoly quantity can be written as
`
`Q p c
`
`M
`
`⫺g
`
`⫺g
`
`(
`
`g
`g ⫺ 1
`
`)
`
`␧
`
`A p c
`
`⫺g
`
`(
`
`g
`g ⫺ 1
`
`)
`
`⫺g
`
`[
`
`(
`
`␧c
`
`)(
`
`cg
`1
`g ⫺ 1 g ⫺ 1
`Q p c
`. And the
`By comparison, the competitive level of quantity is given by
`Q p c
`[g/ (g ⫺
`⫺g
`monopoly quantity in the absence of marketing would be
`⫺g
`M0
`M
`Q ! Q
`. It will always be true that
`and that marketing leads to higher
`1)]
`
`⫺g ␧/(1⫺␧)
`
`]
`
`)
`
`C
`
`M0
`
`.
`
`⫺g
`
`7 The static model is useful and appropriate for advertising. However, a more dynamic approach
`may be needed for the analysis of other types of nonprice competition, like quality, that influence
`research and development.
`8 The condition on the price elasticity is standard. The condition on the advertising elasticity
`follows as a corollary of the Dorfman-Steiner theorem. Observe that
`
`␧
`c
`A
`cq
`p p pq ⫺ cq ⫺ A p pq 1 ⫺ ⫺ p pq 1 ⫺ ⫺ p pq
`pq
`pq
`p
`g
`
`(
`
`)
`
`(
`
`)
`
`(1 ⫺ ␧)
`g
`
`.
`
`Nonnegative profits imply that
`
`␧ ! 1
`.
`
`This content downloaded from 4.30.121.19 on Thu, 14 Dec 2017 19:14:29 UTC
`All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`

`

`158
`
`The Journal of LAW& ECONOMICS
`
`g
`
`MQ
`quantity provision in the marketplace.9 However,
`may be higher or lower
`CQ
`than
`, depending on the configuration of parameters.
`Q /Q p [g/ (g ⫺ 1)] A p (c/p) A
`⫺g
`␧
`␧
`M C
`Observe that
`. The higher the price
`markup, the greater the restriction in quantity; this is the standard incentive
`effect of monopoly, encapsulated by the first term. However, monopolists restrict
`(␧)
`quantity less when the responsiveness of demand to marketing
`is higher.
`To take a few concrete examples, monopoly quantity is nearly 50 percent
`,c p .1 g p 1.6
`
`higher than competitive quantity for the parameters
`, and
`␧ p .9
`; under this scenario, more than half of revenue (.9/1.6) is spent on
`
`,c p .1 g p 1.6
`␧ p .5
`marketing. In contrast, for
`, and
`, monopoly quantity is
`more than 80 percent below competitive quantity, and less than one-third of
`revenue (.5/1.6) is spent on marketing.
`This implies that marketing can partially or completely offset monopoly pric-
`ing and can even overcorrect for the quantity distortions of monopoly, depending
`on the strength of incentives to market. Note that the analysis so far is strictly
`positive in nature, as the competitive level of quantity may be equal to or below
`the efficient level.
`
`2.3. Normative Analysis of Patents with Advertising
`
`The cost of monopoly is the reduction in quantity suffered by consumers. In
`the absence of advertising, this is easy to calculate: the quantity provided after
`patent expiration is assumed to be the competitive and efficient level; the dif-
`ference between the monopoly quantity and the postexpiration quantity yields
`the social cost.
`The introduction of marketing makes the situation more complex for two
`reasons. First, competition may increase or decrease quantity. Second, since
`competition may not produce the efficient level of quantity, the competitive level
`of output cannot be used as a simple benchmark for efficiency. Nonetheless, the
`competitive level of quantity can usually help bound the welfare costs of patents,
`as we show.
`In general, the welfare effects of patents are a priori ambiguous because their
`quantity effects are ambiguous. Recall from Section 2.2 that patent expiration
`has offsetting effects on quantity. Patent expiration increases quantity by lowering
`the market price but decreases it by reducing market advertising. Ultimately, the
`welfare effects depend on the value of changes in quantity and (sometimes) on
`the direct consumption value of changes in advertising. The ambiguous effect
`on quantity thus creates ambiguity for the welfare effects of patents. Moreover,
`the same forces that move quantity in opposite directions—namely, price cuts
`and advertising reductions—also move consumer welfare in opposite directions.
`Therefore, patents may help or harm consumers, depending on the shape of the
`demand and cost curves of a particular industry.
`
`9 Suppose not. In this case,
`cannot be an equilibrium.
`
`␧A ! 1
`
`, which implies that
`
`A ! 1
`
`and that, on the margin,
`
`D ! 0
`A
`
`. This
`
`This content downloaded from 4.30.121.19 on Thu, 14 Dec 2017 19:14:29 UTC
`All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`

`

`Intellectual Property and Pharmaceutical Markets
`
`159
`
`Figure 4. Welfare effects of patent expiration under informational advertising
`
`2.3.1. Advertising as Information
`
`We first consider the welfare effects of patents when advertising provides
`valuable information about a product but does not add value to the product
`itself or provide direct utility to consumers. In this case, advertising does not
`affect the true value of a good to consumers but does move perceived value
`toward the true value. Let
`represent the inverse demand as a function
`p(x, a)
`of quantity
`and advertising
`(x)
`. Price falls in quantity but rises in advertising.
`(a)
`We denote by
`the full-information demand curve defined by
`p(x)
`lim p(x, a) p p(x), Gx.
`ar⬁
`
`The change in welfare due to patent expiration is given by the change in true
`social surplus, which is evaluated at the true, fully informed demand curve. We
`define this as
`
`M 冕
`
`Info
`
`C
`
`D { S ⫺ S p p(q)dq ⫺ (p x ⫺ p x ).
`
`x C
`
`C C
`
`M M
`
`(4)
`
`xM
`
`Figure 4 illustrates this argument for the case in which patent expiration reduces
`quantity. The change in quantity is evaluated along the true demand curve,
`which differs from the observed demand curves both before and after patent
`
`This content downloaded from 4.30.121.19 on Thu, 14 Dec 2017 19:14:29 UTC
`All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`

`

`160
`
`The Journal of LAW& ECONOMICS
`
`expiration. In this case, the welfare cost of patent expiration is given by the area
`L, which measures the welfare loss from patent expiration, assuming zero mar-
`ginal cost of production, and yields the consumer surplus associated with the
`additional quantity consumed under monopoly.
`Since advertising moves observed demand toward the true demand curve, we
`can use observed consumer surplus as a lower bound on the true consumer
`surplus, according to
`
`冕
`
`冕
`
`x
`
`C
`
`p(q)dq ≥
`
`x
`
`C
`
`p(q, a )dq.
`M
`
`x
`
`M
`
`x
`
`M
`
`On the basis of this inequality, our empirical analysis uses the observed change
`in consumer welfare as a bound on the true change in welfare. In particular, we
`construct the estimator
`
`Info 冕
`
`˜D { p(q, a )dq ⫺ (p x ⫺ p x ),
`
`x C
`
`M
`
`C C
`
`M M
`
`(5)
`
`≤ D
`˜D
`if and only if patent expiration increases quantity. Therefore,
`where
`Info
`Info
`the estimator is a lower bound, in absolute value, on the true increase in welfare.
`
`xM
`
`2.3.2. Advertising as Persuasion
`
`Some forms of advertising seek to persuade rather than inform. An example
`is the provision of in-kind prescribing incentives to physicians. Informational
`advertising moves demand toward its fully informed level. Purely persuasive
`advertising moves demand above its true level and may create socially excessive
`consumption.10 To separate this case from that of advertising as consumption,
`suppose further that advertising confers no direct consumption benefits on phy-
`sicians or patients.
`The welfare effects of persuasive advertising depend on the strength of mar-
`keting incentives and whether these boost quantity past its efficient level. While
`persuasive advertising always pushes the demand curve above its efficient level,
`it does not always push equilibrium quantity past this point. Figure 5 illustrates
`this case, in which market demand, DM, exceeds the true demand curve, DT.
`Region L shows welfare loss due to patent monopoly with persuasive advertising,
`(cid:4)
`and L show this loss for patent monopoly without
`and the combined regions L
`advertising. Even though demand is pushed past its efficient level, the monopolist
`does not choose to boost demand by so much that the equilibrium quantity
`exceeds its efficient level, XC. As a result, the “inefficient” growth in demand
`actually reduces deadweight loss due to underutilization. Therefore, even per-
`suasive advertising partially offsets the monopoly restriction on quantity and
`thus improves social welfare.
`
`10 If advertising is only partially persuasive and fails to increase demand above its true level, the
`analysis is substantially similar to the case of advertising as information.
`
`This content downloaded from 4.30.121.19 on Thu, 14 Dec 2017 19:14:29 UTC
`All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`

`

`Intellectual Property and Pharmaceutical Markets
`
`161
`
`Figure 5. Welfare effects of patent expiration under persuasive advertising
`
`Implicit in this last point is the premise that advertising cost must be strictly
`less than the additional consumer surplus generated by the growth in utilization.
`This is a straightforward implication of profit-maximizing behavior by the mo-
`nopolist, who will never spend more than the incremental value created for
`consumers. An alternative case is one in which demand rises by so much as to
`push equilibrium quantity past XC. In this case, advertising may create static
`welfare loss because of overutilization.
`Empirically, the only difference with persuasive advertising is that the com-
`petitive demand curve coincides with the true demand and lies below the mo-
`nopoly demand curve. Therefore, the competitive demand curve serves as the
`best approximation of true demand.
`In this case, we use the estimator
`
`x C
`
`Pers 冕
`Info 冕
`
`˜D { p(q, a )dq ⫺ (p x ⫺ p x ).
`
`C
`
`C C
`
`M M
`
`(6)
`
`Observe that
`
`xM
`


`D p D ⫹
`
`Pers
`
`x C
`
`[p(q, a ) ⫺ p(q, a )]dq.
`
`M
`
`C
`
`xM


`! D
`. Intuitively, when we assume that
`The latter expression implies that
`D
`Pers
`Info
`advertising is persuasive, we are implicitly assuming that the true demand for
`the product is lower than in the informational advertising case. Under persuasive
`advertising, therefore, patent expiration benefits consumers less. As before, this
`
`This content downloaded from 4.30.121.19 on Thu, 14 Dec 2017 19:14:29 UTC
`All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`

`

`162
`
`The Journal of LAW& ECONOMICS
`
`estimator is a lower bound on the true absolute change in welfare due to patent
`expiration.
`
`2.3.3. Advertising as Consumption
`
`Suppose that advertising confers utility through two channels. The first is
`direct: exposure to advertising produces utility. For example, pharmaceutical
`companies may provide perquisites to consumers (in the form of samples) or
`to physicians (in the form of gifts or in-kind transfers). The second operates
`through complementarity with consumption. Advertising may increase the true
`value of and consumers’ willingness to pay for a product. That is, consumers
`may derive more utility from using a heavily advertised product. In this case,
`the consumer welfare effect of patent expiration satisfies
`
`D { S ⫺ S p V(a ) ⫹
`
`C
`
`C
`
`M
`
`冕
`
`x C
`
`p(q, a )dq ⫺ V(a )
`
`M
`
`C
`
`C
`
`冕
`
`0
`
`xM
`
`(7)
`
`p(q, a )dq ⫺ (p x ⫺ p x ).
`
`C C
`
`M M
`
`M
`
`⫺
`
`0
`
`V(a )
`V(a )
`represent the direct utility value of competitive and
`and
`The terms
`M
`C
`monopoly advertising levels, respectively. When advertising has consumption
`value, patent expiration can raise output while still lowering welfare: the decline
`in price raises output and welfare, but the reduction in advertising has a direct
`negative effect on welfare.
`These results are illustrated by Figure 6, which depicts the change in gross
`surplus that occurs at patent expiration when advertising provides utility. In that
`case, patent expiration lowers price and shifts demand inward. Regions G and
`L show the respective gain and loss in gross social surplus attributable to a
`simultaneous reduction in advertising and price. The welfare impact is ambig-
`uous and depends on the sizes of G and L. When advertising has value in itself,
`therefore, care must be taken when inferring changes in welfare from changes
`in output. For example, it is possible that the optimal patent life is infinite, even
`when patent expiration increases output.
`Another possibility is differential marketing to consumers with different will-
`ingness to pay. While price discrimination may be difficult, discrimination
`through marketing is much easier. This applies to the promotion of drugs to
`doctors, called “detailing” in pharmaceutical markets. Differential advertising
`across doctors and markets may act as a form of price discrimination. Since
`advertising cannot be resold, it is more easily implemented than traditional forms
`of price discrimination. Thus, advertising may shrink pricing inefficiencies and
`thereby lower the marginal cost of patent extension. Discriminatory advertising
`may lower or even remove the deadweight losses associated with patent mono-
`polies.
`When advertising has consumption value, it is necessary to estimate the direct
`
`This content downloaded from 4.30.121.19 on Thu, 14 Dec 2017 19:14:29 UTC
`All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`

`

`Intellectual Property and Pharmaceutical Markets
`
`163
`
`Figure 6. Welfare effects of patent expiration under advertising as consumption
`
`utility of advertising in order to capture the full value of patent expiration. In
`the absence of this estimate, we can say that consumers benefit less from patent
`expiration whenever they derive consumption value from advertising.
`
`3. Empirical Analysis
`
`This section investigates the empirical impact of pharmaceutical marketing
`on consumer welfare. Our approach is to use patent expirations as a means of
`identifying the demand curve for pharmaceuticals, where demand depends on
`both price and advertising effort. These estimates are then used to calculate how
`much patent expiration benefits (or costs) consumers.
`We focus on direct-to-physician marketing, which accounts for about 86 per-
`cent of all pharmaceutical marketing (Kaiser Family Foundation 2003). We es-
`timate the value of marketing under the alternative models of advertising as
`information (Section 2.3.1) and advertising as persuasion (Section 2.3.2). We do
`not have the data necessary to estimate the direct utility value of such marketing
`to consumers or physicians. If this exists, it will further increase the value of
`marketing and reduce the cost of patents.
`We begin by presenting our empirical model and approach to welfare esti-
`mation. We then describe our data and present descriptive analyses of the re-
`lationships between patent expiration, quantity changes, and marketing effort.
`Next, we discuss our approach to measuring advertising and lay out our iden-
`tification strategy. We finish with our estimated models and welfare effects.
`
`This content downloaded from 4.30.121.19 on Thu, 14 Dec 2017 19:14:29 UTC
`All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
`
`

`

`164
`
`The Journal of LAW& ECONOMICS
`
`3.1. Model and Approach to Welfare Estimation
`
`The basic framework for this analysis is the following demand function:
`ln x p b ⫹ b ln p ⫹ b ln a ⫹ f ⫹ M(t) ⫹ ␧ .
`
`it
`
`0
`
`1
`
`it
`
`2
`
`it
`
`i
`
`it
`
`(8)
`
`x
`p
`is the corresponding
`is the price of molecule i in month t,
`In this equation,
`it
`it
`quantity of the molecule, and
`is a measure of advertising. There is also a
`a it
`molecule fixed effect,
`, and a polynomial time trend,
`. We are particularly
`M(t)
`f
`i
`interested in using the demand function to ascertain the effects of patent ex-
`piration on quantity and on welfare. It is straightforward to assess the quantity
`effects, but estimating the welfare changes (in terms of consumer surplus) re-
`quires more discussion.
`The demand function (and its associated inverse demand) implies forms for
`the changes in consumer surplus presented in Section 2.3. Consider first the
`cost of quantity restriction alone, which would be present without advertising.
`Suppose that
`represents demand at the consumer’s true valuation of the
`p(q)
`(cid:4)
`good. Monopoly quantity is given by
`. Finally, define by
`the counterfactual
`x
`x
`C
`M
`quantity that would obtain under competition if prices changed but advertising
`remained at its monopoly level. If
`dp/p
`is the percentage change in price due to
`(cid:4)
`x { x [1 ⫹ (dp/p) ␧]
`patent expiration, we can define
`.

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket