throbber
Available online at wwwsciencedirecteom =
`
` Journal of Econometrics I2 (2004) 213~246
`
`ocreuel@ornlcro
`
`JOIIRNAL 9F
`Econometrics
`
`www.clsevier.com/Iocateleconbase
`
`An empirical model of learning and patient
`spillovers in new drug entry
`
`Andrea Coscelli“, Matthew Shum'”
`I'Lenm'on, Ltd, Orion Home, 5 Upper St. Martin's lane, London WCZHQEA, UK
`I’Drrpart‘nmu of Economics, Johns Hopkins University, Mergenthler Hall 463, 3400M Charles Street.
`Baltimore, MD 21218, USA
`
`Awepterl 3 September 2003
`
`Abstract
`
`We specify and estimate a diffusion model for the new molecule omeprazole into the anti-ulcer
`drug market. Our model is based on a Bayesian learning process whereby doctors update their
`beliefs about omeprazole’s quality relative to existing drugs alter observing its reflects on the pa-
`tients that have been prescribed this drug. The model also accommodates informational spillovers
`and heterogeneity in informativeness across patients with diflerent diagnoses. We obtain estimates
`of the learning process parameters using a novel panel data set tracking doctors’ complete pre-
`scription histories over a 3-year period.
`© 2003 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
`
`JEL classification: [10; L10
`
`Keywords: Entry of innovative drugs; Barriers to entry; Structural diffusion models
`
`1. Introduction
`
`First—mover advantage is a well—documented phenomenon in many differentiated
`product markets (see Urban et a1. (1986) for a survey of the evidence). Economists have
`tended to attribute this phenomenon to lack of information among consumers about the
`quality or attributes of an entrant’s product; for example, Shapiro (1982, p. 7) states that
`
`...the fundamental source of the entry barrier is an information one: consumers
`have better information about established brands than about new ones [...] infor-
`mation is the basic barrier to be overcome by a new product...
`
`' Corresponding author. Tel: +1—410—516—8828; fax: +1-410-516—7600.
`E—mail Wessex: andrea.eosoelli@lexeoon.co.uk (A. Coscelli), mshurn@jhu.edu (M. Shum).
`
`0304-4076/3-see front matter © 2003 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
`doi:10.10l6/jjeconom2003.09.002
`
`Argentum Pharm. LLC V. Alcon Research, Ltd.
`Case IPR2017-01053
`
`ALCON 2075
`
`

`

`214
`
`A. Coscelli, M. Shum / Journal of Econometrics 122 (2004) 213 – 246
`
`The doctor/patient relationship is fraught with uncertainty. Doctors have incomplete
`information on the medical condition of a patient, and which treatment is best for the
`patient. Doctors learn about the quality of alternative treatments both through direct
`experience (actual prescriptions of the new drug), and indirect experience (such as
`promotional activity by pharmaceutical companies, articles in medical journals and
`attendance at medical conferences). This paper focuses on direct information, which
`accumulates slowly, and is confounded by heterogeneity across diagnoses: what works
`for diagnosis X may not work as well for diagnosis Y.
`Using a novel panel data set of complete prescription histories for a sample of
`doctors in the Rome (Italy) metropolitan area, we study the di)usion process of a
`new anti-ulcer drug (omeprazole) during a 3-year period (1990–1992). The evolu-
`tion of omeprazole’s market share over time was marked by the gradual di)usion
`which characterizes new product entry into many product markets: omeprazole’s mar-
`ket share (as a proportion of total prescriptions) climbed from under 5% in the latter
`half of 1990 to about 15% in early 1992, and eventually up to 25% by the middle
`of 1995.
`In this paper, we gauge how well this gradual di)usion pattern can be explained by
`a learning model in which doctors, initially uncertain about the quality di)erential be-
`tween omeprazole and the incumbent drugs, update their beliefs about this di)erential
`after observing noisy signals from patients to whom they have prescribed omeprazole.
`To that end, we specify and estimate the parameters of such a learning model. Fur-
`thermore, in order to accommodate features speciIc to the pharmaceutical prescription
`process, we extend the basic learning model to allow for spillovers across all the pa-
`tients of a given doctor, as well as heterogeneity in informativeness across patients.
`While there are alternative explanations for the individual-level di)usion process (such
`as the publication of the results of post-marketing clinical trials in medical journals),
`we focus on a learning explanation because our data includes especially rich detail on
`doctors’ prescription histories.
`Our results suggest that the learning model does very well in generating the ob-
`served slow di)usion path of omeprazole in the Italian market. The parameters of
`the learning model quantify, in informational terms, the disadvantage that omeprazole
`su)ered relative to the existing drugs upon its entry into the Italian anti-ulcer mar-
`ket. This informational disadvantage can arise from either doctors’ initial pessimism
`about omeprazole’s quality, or risk aversion. In addition, we Ind that the informa-
`tional spillovers are negative across some diagnosis groups, which tends to retard
`the speed of learning. That
`is, we Ind that a positive outcome when prescribing
`omeprazole for certain diagnoses leads doctors to regard it as less attractive for other
`diagnoses.
`The next section provides some background on the international and Italian anti-ulcer
`drug markets. Section 3 describes the doctor-level learning model, Section 4 describes
`our panel data set of complete prescription histories and Section 5 derives the estimating
`equations associated with the learning model. Results from several speciIcations of the
`learning model are presented and interpreted in Section 6, and we conclude in the last
`section.
`
`

`

`A. Coscelli, M. Shum / Journal of Econometrics 122 (2004) 213 – 246
`
`215
`
`2. Background
`
`Several studies have documented the existence and, more importantly, the nature of
`barriers to entry into pharmaceutical markets. Bond and Lean (1977) found evidence of
`substantial pioneer advantage, but they also found that products containing some thera-
`peutic novelty managed to gain large market shares when backed by heavy promotional
`campaigns. Berndt et al. (1997) document similar e)ects in the anti-ulcer drug market.
`Their Indings clearly show that technological advances do not necessarily translate into
`large market shares without tremendous marketing muscle. 1 As striking as the results
`from the two studies are, however, they never explain the causes of pioneer advantage.
`The availability of doctor-level prescription histories allows us a unique opportunity
`to assess the role of information in explaining the di)usion patterns observed in many
`product markets. 2
`This paper joins a growing empirical literature examining behavioral explanations for
`di)usion patterns for new products in experience good markets. Among these studies,
`Ackerberg (2002) and Erdem and Keane (1996) estimated structural learning models
`to explain consumers’ purchase patterns for, respectively, yogurt and laundry deter-
`gent. Ching (2000) has also estimated a demand model for pharmaceuticals based on
`a Bayesian learning procedure. Our work di)ers from these papers because we con-
`sider a more general learning model which allows for spillovers across all the patients
`of a given doctor, as well as heterogeneity in informativeness across patients. These
`extensions seem especially appropriate for pharmaceutical markets, since prescription
`drugs (and in particular anti-ulcer drugs) are usually prescribed for several di)erent
`diagnoses.
`Using aggregate market share data, Azoulay et al. (2003) estimate a di)usion model
`to study the importance of consumption externalities in explaining the di)usion patterns
`of H2-antagonist drugs into the anti-ulcer drug market. Our analysis extends their work
`by using a novel micro-data set to quantify the extent of network-type spillovers across
`patients belonging to the same doctor. 3
`
`3. The learning model
`
`In this section, we describe the behavioral model which forms the basis of our
`empirical analysis. In what follows, we index doctors by the subscript i, and assume
`that patients are heterogeneous in their diagnoses, which we subscript by j. We begin
`
`1 Using a similar data set, Azoulay (2002) investigates how promotional activity and scientiIc informa-
`tion arising from clinical trials a)ect the di)usion of competing molecules in the anti-ulcer drug market.
`King (2000) focuses on the role of marketing in increasing the perceived product di)erentiation (i.e., degree
`of substitutability) between competing anti-ulcer drugs.
`2 A related literature (Stern, 1996; Ellison et al., 1997) has investigated the extent of competition in
`pharmaceutical markets by estimating cross-price elasticities between the competing drugs in a market.
`Unlike these papers, we abstract away from competition between existing anti-ulcer drugs.
`3 Finally, there has been a long interest in di)usion models in the marketing literature. See Bass et al.
`(1990) for a review of this largely theoretical and macro-level empirical literature. Chandrashekaran and
`Sinha (1995) is one of the few papers in this literature which are formulated at the micro-level.
`
`

`

`216
`
`A. Coscelli, M. Shum / Journal of Econometrics 122 (2004) 213 – 246
`
`by describing a baseline version of the learning model in which doctors are assumed
`to be risk neutral. At the end of this section, we discuss an alternative model which
`allows for risk aversion.
`Consider a given patient k, from diagnosis group j, who visits doctor i during period
`t. We assume that doctor i distinguishes between two treatment alternatives: the new
`molecule, omeprazole (alternative 1), and any of the other molecules (alternative 0).
`The utilities for a given patient k with diagnosis j during period t from each alternative
`are:
`
`1j + (cid:14)i1(t) + (cid:13)∗1jkt = (cid:8)∗1 xi + (cid:10)p1t + (cid:12)∗
`
`
`1jkt
`U i
`
`
`
`U i
`
`0jkt = (cid:8)∗0 xi + (cid:10)p0t + (cid:12)∗0(t) + (cid:13)∗0j + (cid:14)i
`0jkt
`
`
`
`if take omeprazole;
`
`otherwise;
`
`(3.1)
`
`(3.2)
`
`where
`• p1t and p0t are, respectively, the price of omeprazole and a weighted average of the
`prices of the incumbent drugs weighted by their market shares at time t. The vector
`xi contains observed doctors’ characteristics.
`• (cid:13)∗
`1j and (cid:13)∗0j parameterize the “unobserved quality” of omeprazole and the incum-
`
`bent drugs when treating diagnosis j. These are unobserved by the econometrician.
`Doctors, however, are presumed to know (cid:13)∗
`0j, and have imperfect information about
`
`
`(cid:13)∗1j. As described below, doctors learn about (cid:13)∗1j by prescribing omeprazole to their
`patients.
`• (cid:12)∗
`1(t) and (cid:12)∗
`0(t) are Nexible functions of time, which parameterize period t factors
`which a)ect the attractiveness of, respectively, omeprazole and the incumbent drugs.
`These are the same over all doctors, patients, and diagnoses. In particular, the func-
`tion (cid:12)∗
`1(t) proxies for aspects of the learning process which we do not explicitly
`model, such as word of mouth, medical congresses, and articles in medical journals.
`• (cid:14)i
`
`1jkt and (cid:14)i0jkt are i.i.d. (over doctors, patients, diagnoses, and time periods) shocks as-
`sociated with, respectively, omeprazole and the incumbent drugs. They are observed
`by the doctors, but not by the econometrician.
`
`Throughout, we abstract away from agency problems between the doctor and the
`patient, and assume the doctor maximizes the patient’s utility from the prescription. 4
`Doctor i chooses the option with the higher per-period utility. 5 The choice rule for
`
`4 The reputation e)ects resulting from the long-term nature of many patient–doctor relationships in Italy
`(the National Health Service requires each enrollee to list a general practitioner) tend to minimize the
`divergence between doctors’ and patients’ objective functions which potentially form the basis of agency
`problems.
`5 For computational tractability we have assumed that doctors are myopic in our model, so that in any
`given time period, a doctor chooses the molecule with the highest per-period utility based solely on her
`current information. If the doctor were forward-looking, she would choose the molecule with the highest
`present discounted utility and thereby take into account the information that she would gain about omeprazole
`by prescribing it this period. Ongoing work by Crawford and Shum (2000) examines issues of uncertainty
`and matching in pharmaceutical demand in a fully forward-looking framework. Ferreyra (1999) has recently
`estimated a forward-looking dynamic learning model, using the same data that we use in this paper, but
`without allowing for spillovers across patients.
`
`

`

`A. Coscelli, M. Shum / Journal of Econometrics 122 (2004) 213 – 246
`
`217
`
`the doctor is to prescribe omeprazole if Et(U i
`1kjt) ¿ U i0kjt. If we assume that (cid:14)i
`
`1jkt and
`(cid:14)i
`0jkt are i.i.d. with the type 1 extreme value distribution, the probability that doctor i
`prescribes omeprazole takes the familiar logit form: 6
`exp((cid:8)xi + (cid:10)Rpt + (cid:12)(t) + Et(cid:13)j)
`Prob(prescribe omeprazole) =
`1 + exp((cid:8)xi + (cid:10) Rpt + (cid:12)(t) + Et(cid:13)j)
`
`
`
`1(t)−(cid:12)∗1−(cid:8)∗0 ; (cid:12)(t) ≡ (cid:12)∗
`where we have substituted (cid:8) ≡ (cid:8)∗
`and the (cid:12)(t) function are to be estimated. 7
`By distinguishing between di)erent diagnoses, we allow the entrant and incumbent
`anti-ulcer drugs to di)er in their e)ectiveness and suitability across diagnoses. This
`accommodates “segmentation” or “horizontal di)erentiation” in the market on the basis
`of diagnosis, which we believe to be an important feature of the anti-ulcer drug market.
`
`(3.3)
`0(t), and Et(cid:13)j ≡ Et(cid:13)∗1j−(cid:13)0j: (cid:8); (cid:10),
`
`3.1. Bayesian updating
`
`The main focus of the paper is to measure how well the di)usion pattern for omepra-
`zole can be explained by doctors’ learning about (cid:13). We explain this learning process
`in this section. Throughout, we assume that the learning processes are independent
`across doctors. 8 Therefore, we describe the learning process for doctor i, omitting the
`superscript i in most of the equations below for expositional clarity. We assume that, at
`time t = 0 (i.e., at omeprazole’s entry), she (doctor i) has the following initial beliefs
`about ˜(cid:13), the J -dimensional vector of quality di)erentials between omeprazole and the
`incumbent drugs:
`
`
`
`˜(cid:13) ∼ N
`
`˜(cid:13)1 ≡
`
`0
`...
`(cid:20)2
`(cid:13);J
`Throughout, we adopt the indexing convention that the subscript t denotes the be-
`ginning of period t; therefore, ˜(cid:13)1 denotes the mean of doctors’ beliefs at the beginning
`of period 1, corresponding to the mean of the doctors’ initial beliefs (and (cid:19)(cid:13);1 is sim-
`ilarly the initial variance–covariance matrix). The assumption that the initial variance–
`covariance matrix (cid:19)(cid:13);1 is diagonal implies that the information that doctors had about
`
`:
`
`(3.4)
`
`
`
`
`(cid:20)2
`(cid:13);1
`
`0
`
`: : :
`
`0
`
`0
`
`0
`
`0
`
`(cid:20)2
`(cid:13);2
`···
`0
`
`: : :
`···
`: : :
`
`
`
`;
`
`(cid:19)(cid:13);1 ≡
`
`
`
`E1(cid:13)1
`...
`E1(cid:13)J
`
`
`
`6 By aggregating all the non-omeprazole-based drugs into one alternative, we are implicitly assuming that
`all these drugs are perfectly substitutable, and that an omeprazole-based drug substitutes equally well with all
`of them. We make this assumption because we want to focus on the di)usion of drugs based on omeprazole
`into the marketplace.
`7 In most of the speciIcations reported below, we assume that the time function (cid:12)(t) is a quadratic time
`trend. As we point out below, since the price di)erential Rpt only varies over time, it would be impossible
`to separately identify the price coeScient (cid:10) apart from a full set of time dummies.
`8 Informational spillovers across doctors (“word of mouth”) at the aggregate level are captured by the
`(cid:12)(t)’s.
`
`

`

`218
`
`A. Coscelli, M. Shum / Journal of Econometrics 122 (2004) 213 – 246
`
`(3.5)
`
`omeprazole before its entry is speciIc to particular diagnoses. This reNects the institu-
`tional feature that clinical trials—the results of which constitute most of doctors’ prior
`information—are generally most informative as to a drug’s e)ectiveness for particular
`diagnoses, and less informative regarding interactions of e)ects for di)erent diagnoses,
`which would lead to non-zero o)-diagonal terms in the initial variance–covariance
`matrix. 9
`The evolution of doctor i’s beliefs over time can be derived period-by-period. As-
`sume that doctor i begins time period t with beliefs that
`˜(cid:13) ∼ N(Et
`˜(cid:13); (cid:19)(cid:13);t ≡ Et
`˜(cid:13)˜(cid:13)(cid:2) − (Et
`˜(cid:13))(cid:2))
`˜(cid:13))(Et
`(it will be clear later how these beliefs arise). During period t, the doctor prescribes
`omeprazole to kj of her patients with diagnosis j, and observes kj noisy signals of (cid:13)j.
`We assume that these kj signals ((cid:21)jtk; k = 1 → kj) take the following form:
`(cid:21)jtk = (cid:13)j + (cid:22)jtk;
`(3.6)
`where (cid:22)jtk is normally distributed, with zero mean. Doctors attempt to form estimates
`of (cid:13)j from observations of the noisy signals (cid:21)jtk’s.
`Correlation structure: In order to accommodate informational spillovers across pa-
`tients in di)erent diagnosis groups (i.e., to capture the idea that “what is good for
`diagnosis X may not be good for diagnosis Y”), we assume that, within a given pe-
`riod t, the noise terms (cid:22) are correlated across signals. We induce correlation across
`signals with the following variance components structure for each (cid:22):
`(cid:22)jtk = (cid:23)jt + jtk;
`j = 1; : : : ; J;
`(3.7)
`where (i) t is distributed N(0; (cid:20)2
`), i.i.d. over t; (ii) the jtk’s are independent over j,
`t, and k, and distributed N(0; (cid:20)2
` j), j = 1; : : : ; J ; and (iii) (cid:23)1; : : : ; (cid:23)J are time-invariant
`parameters. Given these assumptions, then, the following correlation structure among
`all the signals ((cid:21)’s) that doctor i observes in period t emerges:
`
` + (cid:20)2
`1. Var((cid:22)jtk) = (cid:23)2j (cid:20)2
`
` j,
`, for k (cid:7)= k(cid:2),
`
`2. Cov((cid:22)jtk; (cid:22)jtk(cid:1)) = (cid:23)2j (cid:20)2
`, for j (cid:7)= j(cid:2) and ∀ k; k(cid:2).
`3. Cov((cid:22)jtk; (cid:22)j(cid:1)tk(cid:1)) = (cid:23)j(cid:23)j(cid:1)(cid:20)2
`This one-factor variance components speciIcation reduces the number of parameters,
`while placing mild restrictions on the correlation structure. 10 In Appendix A we cal-
`culate the variance–covariance matrix of a vector of signals, for a simple example.
`Period-by-period updating: Given the normality assumptions on the signals (cid:21) as
`well as on the (cid:13)’s, a doctor’s posterior beliefs about ˜(cid:13) given ˜(cid:21)t are described by a
`normal distribution with a mean and variance that can be derived using the multivariate
`normal conditional mean and variance formulas (Amemiya, 1985, p. 3). The computed
`posterior distribution in period t serves as the prior distribution for period t + 1. In this
`way, we derive the sequence of a doctor’s posterior distributions over all the periods
`
`9 SpeciIc clinical evidence on omeprazole’s e)ectiveness for di)erent diagnoses is presented further below.
`10 We have attempted to estimate an extended model with a 2-factor variance components structure, but
`we have experienced problems identifying some of the parameters in that case.
`
`

`

`A. Coscelli, M. Shum / Journal of Econometrics 122 (2004) 213 – 246
`
`219
`
`by repeatedly applying the conditional mean and variance formulas for jointly normally
`distributed random variables.
`(cid:13)
`(cid:14)
`(cid:16)
`(cid:16)(cid:14)
`(cid:13)(cid:15)
`(cid:15)
`To this end, we characterize the joint distribution of (˜(cid:13); ˜(cid:21)t), during period t:
`˜(cid:13)
`˜(cid:13)
`(cid:19)(cid:13);(cid:21);t
`(cid:19)(cid:13);t
`Et
`(cid:19)(cid:2)
`˜(cid:13)(cid:21)t
`(cid:13);(cid:21);t (cid:19)(cid:21);t
`˜(cid:21)t
`
`∼ N
`
`;
`
`;
`
`(3.8)
`
`where ˜(cid:13)t and (cid:19)(cid:13);t are, respectively, the mean and variance–covariance matrix of ˜(cid:13)
`conditional on all the signals received before period t. ˜(cid:13)(cid:21);t and (cid:19)(cid:21);t are the mean and
`variance–covariance matrix of the vector of signals ˜(cid:21)t (Eqs. (A.2) and (A.3) in the
`appendix are examples of these formulas), and (cid:19)(cid:13);(cid:21);t is the matrix of covariance terms
`between ˜(cid:13) and ˜(cid:21)t (which is easy to derive given Eqs. (A.1), (3.6) and (3.7)).
`Recall our indexing convention, whereby ˜(cid:13)t+1 ≡ E(˜(cid:13)|˜(cid:21)t) and (cid:19)(cid:13);t+1 ≡ (cid:19)t(˜(cid:13)|˜(cid:21)t)
`are, respectively, the prior mean vector and variance–covariance matrix of the quality
`vector ˜(cid:13) at the beginning of period t +1 (i.e., conditional on all the information signals
`obtained up to, and including, period t). For the learning model described above, and
`given the initial beliefs (3.4), these quantities can be recursively deIned as
`(cid:21);t (˜(cid:21)t − (˜(cid:13)t));
`
`˜(cid:13)t+1 = ˜(cid:13)t + (cid:19)(cid:2)(cid:13);(cid:21);t(cid:19)−1
`(cid:19)(cid:13);t+1 = (cid:19)(cid:13);t − (cid:19)(cid:2)
`(cid:13);(cid:21);t(cid:19)−1
`(cid:21);t (cid:19)(cid:13);(cid:21);t
`for period t = 0; 1; 2; : : :
`Eq. (3.9) yields the means of the posterior distribution of the (cid:13)’s which are substi-
`tuted into the logit prescription probabilities (cf. Eq. (3.3)). These probabilities form
`the basis for our likelihood function, which is described in the next section.
`The parameters of the model which we estimate are: (i) the elements of the pe-
`riod zero initial mean vector (E1(cid:13)1; : : : ; E1(cid:13)J ); (ii) the diagonal elements of the initial
`
`
`variance–covariance matrix ((cid:20)2(cid:13);1; : : : ; (cid:20)2(cid:13);J ); (iii) the true values (cid:13)1; : : : ; (cid:13)J ; (iv) the pa-
`
` J , and (cid:20)2rameters of the correlation structure (cid:23)1; : : : ; (cid:23)J , (cid:20)2 1; : : : ; (cid:20)2
`
`; and (v) the param-
`eters which enter the utility speciIcation (cid:8); (cid:10), and the time function (cid:12)(t).
`
`(3.9)
`
`3.2. Remarks
`
`Rational expectations and risk aversion: In the preceding model, we have not
`allowed for risk aversion in the utility function. We can accommodate risk aversion
`directly in the utility speciIcation of Eq. (3.1) above by including the posterior vari-
`ance directly as an argument in the expected utility expression. Hence, the probability
`that doctor i prescribes omeprazole takes the form
`
`exp((cid:8)xi + (cid:10)Rpt + (cid:12)(t) + Et(cid:13)j + (cid:26) Vart (cid:13)j)
`1 + exp((cid:8)xi + (cid:10)Rpt + (cid:12)(t) + Et(cid:13)j + (cid:26) Vart (cid:13)j)
`
`;
`
`(3.10)
`
`where Vart (cid:13)j denotes doctor i’s posterior variance on (cid:13)j based on the information she
`has obtained from prescriptions prior to period t, and (cid:26) measures the degree of risk
`
`

`

`220
`
`A. Coscelli, M. Shum / Journal of Econometrics 122 (2004) 213 – 246
`
`Et(cid:13) =
`
`;
`
`aversion.11 Using the notation presented above in Eq. (3.8), we can write Vart (cid:13)j =
`(cid:19)(cid:13);t(j; j), the (j; j)th element of the period t variance–covariance matrix (cid:19)(cid:13);t.
`Without additional assumptions, we cannot separately identify the prior mean E1(cid:13)j,
`and the risk coeScient (cid:26). To see this, consider the simplest case of only one diagnosis.
`In this case, the sequence of prior means and variances is given by the well-known
`(cid:17)rt−1
`formulas (cf. DeGroot, Optimal Statistical Decisions, p. 167), for periods t = 2; 3; : : :
`
`(cid:20)2(cid:21)(cid:13)1 + (cid:20)2
`t(cid:1)=1 (cid:21)t(cid:1))
`1(
`1 ∗ rt−1
`
`(cid:20)2(cid:21) + (cid:20)2
`(cid:20)2(cid:21)(cid:20)2
`
`1
`1 ∗ rt−1
`
`(cid:20)2(cid:21) + (cid:20)2
`where rt−1 denotes the number of prescription of omeprazole up to (and including)
`period t − 1; (cid:20)2
`(cid:21) denotes the variance of the prescription signals, and (cid:13)1 and (cid:20)2
`1 denote
`the initial mean and variance. By substituting these expressions into the expression for
`the choice probability (in Eq. (3.10) above), we see that the mean and variance above
`always enter the choice probability as the sum
`
`Vart (cid:13) =
`
`;
`
`Et(cid:13)j + (cid:26) Vart (cid:13)j
`
`(cid:13)1 + (cid:26)(cid:20)2
`1
`
`(cid:13)1 + (cid:26)(cid:20)2
`1
`
`(cid:21)
`1 ∗ (cid:20)(cid:21) ∗(cid:20)(cid:17)rt−1
`
`t(cid:1)=1 (cid:22)t(cid:1)
`
`(cid:21)
`
`=
`
`=
`
`(cid:20)2
`
`(cid:20)2
`
`(cid:21) ∗(cid:18)
`(cid:21) ∗(cid:18)
`
`(cid:17)rt−1
`t(cid:1)=1 (cid:21)t(cid:1)) + (cid:26) ∗ (cid:20)2
`(cid:21)(cid:20)2
`
`(cid:20)2(cid:21)(cid:13)1 + (cid:20)2
`1(
`1
`1 ∗ rt−1
`(cid:19)
`(cid:20)(cid:17)rt−1
`
`(cid:20)2(cid:21) + (cid:20)2
`t(cid:1)=1((cid:13) + (cid:22)t(cid:1) ∗ (cid:20)(cid:21))
`+ (cid:20)2
`1
`1 ∗ rt−1
`(cid:19)
`
`(cid:20)2(cid:21) + (cid:20)2
`1 ∗ rt−1 ∗ (cid:13) + (cid:20)2
`+ (cid:20)2
`;
`(3.11)
`=
`1 ∗ rt−1
`
`(cid:20)2(cid:21) + (cid:20)2
`where we have re-written the signals as (cid:21)t(cid:1) =(cid:13)+(cid:22)t(cid:1)∗(cid:20)(cid:21) with (cid:22)t(cid:1) as i.i.d. standard-normal
`random variables.
`(cid:21) (the signal variance), (cid:20)2
`In our learning model, the parameters (cid:20)2
`1 (the prior vari-
`ance), (cid:13) (the true quality), (cid:13)1 (the prior mean), and (cid:26) (the risk aversion parameter)
`a)ect the likelihood function only through expression (3.11) above. Clearly, if one only
`has cross-sectional data for the initial period t = 1, it is impossible to identify all these
`parameters separately (in this case, r0 = 0 across all doctors, and the above expression
`reduces to the constant (cid:13)1 + (cid:26)(cid:20)2
`1).
`However, inspection of the above expression yields that variation in rt (the number
`of omeprazole prescriptions) across periods t and across doctors should be suScient
`
`
`
`to identify (cid:20)2(cid:21); (cid:20)21; (cid:13), and the sum [(cid:13)1 + (cid:26)(cid:20)21], just due to the non-linear updating
`formulas of the Gaussian learning model. Since the two remaining parameters (cid:13)1 and
`(cid:26) only enter the above expression via the sum [(cid:13)1 + (cid:26)(cid:20)2
`1], they cannot be separately
`identiIed (i.e., for any value of Z, the locus of pairs ((cid:13)1; (cid:26) = (Z − (cid:13)1)=(cid:20)2
`1) yields the
`same likelihood function value).
`
`11 With CARA utility, (cid:26) = 1
`2 r, where r is the coeScient of absolute risk aversion.
`
`

`

`A. Coscelli, M. Shum / Journal of Econometrics 122 (2004) 213 – 246
`
`221
`
`This discussion highlights the infeasibility of identifying the risk aversion parameter
`(cid:26) separately from the prior means E1(cid:13)j; j = 1; 2; 3; 4. Therefore, in our estimation, we
`consider an additional restriction which rules out pessimism by setting the prior means
`equal to the true qualities:
`
`E1(cid:13)j = (cid:13)j;
`
`j = 1; 2; 3; 4:
`
`(cid:17)
`
`This is a rational expectations assumption which is standard in many learning models,
`and which is based on the assumption that doctors’ beliefs should be right on average
`about the true quality of omeprazole. However, even with rational expectations, doctors
`(cid:13);j ≡
`still face uncertainty about its quality, as parameterized by the prior variances (cid:20)2
`Var1 (cid:13)j; j = 1; : : : ; 4.
`For the more complex multivariate learning model with varying numbers of signals
`per diagnosis employed in this paper, the argument for non-identiIcation is more diS-
`cult because the expressions for the posterior mean and variance cannot be written in
`the manner above, as a function of rt,
`t (cid:21)t(cid:1), and the estimated parameters. Hence, we
`explore the separate identiIcation of the (cid:26) and prior mean parameters by simulation,
`and our Indings are presented in Appendix C.
`Related work with the same data set: In ongoing work, one of the authors is
`using the same data set to estimate an explicitly dynamic (forward-looking) model of
`learning (cf. Crawford and Shum, 2000). Since the real world prescription process is
`much more complicated than either of these approaches, the models in the two papers
`accommodate contrasting sets of simplifying assumptions to shed light on di)erent
`aspects of the learning problems which we expect to be important in pharmaceutical
`markets. We discuss several important di)erences between the two papers here.
`First, the empirical questions considered in the two papers are quite di)erent. The
`current paper addresses the question of new good entry, and focuses on considering
`micro-level explanation for omeprazole’s aggregate di)usion pattern. For this reason,
`we assume here that agents are uncertain about the quality of only omeprazole, but not
`the other drugs. The Crawford–Shum paper, on the other hand, addresses the issue of
`patient–drug matches, and focuses on estimating a model which explains the observed
`treatment lengths and “switches” of patients from one drug to another. Since matching
`problems arise only when agents face uncertainty about the returns from a number of
`competing choices, the Crawford–Shum model assumes that patients are ignorant of
`the relative qualities of all the competing drugs, not just omeprazole. 12
`Second, the model considered in Crawford and Shum (2000) is fully dynamic, and
`features patients who choose drugs via a dynamic discrete-choice optimization prob-
`lem. Since the computational burden of such a model is quite severe, the information
`structure is kept quite simple, and no attempt is made to accommodate informational
`spillovers across patients at the doctor-level. In the current paper, however, we ac-
`commodate a more complicated information structure (including these spillovers) by
`abstracting away from the dynamic forward-looking aspect of the learning problem.
`
`12 The matching problem resembles the well-known “multi-armed bandit” problem in decision theory.
`
`

`

`222
`
`A. Coscelli, M. Shum / Journal of Econometrics 122 (2004) 213 – 246
`
`4. Data
`
`The data used in this analysis was collected by the Italian National Institute of Health.
`It records, for a 10% sample 13 of the doctors in the metropolitan area of Rome, all
`prescriptions of anti-ulcer drugs (therapeutic class A02B 14 ) to all their patients during
`a 3-year period (1990–1992). A prescription episode is the unit of observation in the
`data set. The data set contains more than 660,000 observations, each of which records
`the identity of the patient, the prescribing doctor, the drug prescribed, and the year and
`month of the prescription: 326 doctors, and 174,000 patients are represented in the data.
`The median number of prescriptions for the 326 doctors is around 2000 prescriptions
`during the 3-year sample period: 10% of the in-sample doctors have less than 1300
`prescriptions, while only 10% have more than 2800 prescriptions. Appendix B provides
`more details on the data, in particular describing the covariates which we use when
`estimating the learning model.
`The anti-ulcer drug market: The anti-ulcer drug market is the largest therapeutic
`drug market worldwide. It is naturally segmented, with preferred treatments di)ering
`across segments depending on the severity of the diagnosis, as summarized in the Irst
`three columns of Table 1.
`The two most common diagnoses requiring treatment using anti-ulcer drugs are peptic
`ulcers and Gastroesophageal ReNux Disease (GERD). A peptic ulcer is an area of
`
`Table 1
`Segmentation in the anti-ulcer drug market: diagnoses and treatments
`
`Diagnosis
`
`Treatmenta
`
`(1) Minor
`heartburn
`
`Drugs or no
`Prescription
`
`(2) Pathological
`hypersecretory
`conditions
`(3) Attack therapy
`for GERD
`or peptic ulcer
`(4) Maintenance
`therapy for GERD
`or peptic ulcer
`
`Anti-ulcer
`drugs
`
`Anti-ulcer
`drugs
`
`Anti-ulcer
`drugs
`
`Preferred
`drugsa
`
`Anti-acids
`
`omeprazole
`
`omeprazole
`
`H2-
`antagonists
`
`Empirical
`distinctionb
`
`Patient has
`6 2 in-sample
`prescriptions
`Q ¿ 133% average
`monthly quantity for
`ulcer in every month
`Q ¿ 133% average
`monthly quantity for
`ulcer in the month
`Q ¡ 133% average
`monthly quantity for
`ulcer in the month
`
`Frequency
`
`Percent
`
`135,466
`
`20.49
`
`32,362
`
`4.89
`
`132,361
`
`20.02
`
`361,054
`
`54.60
`
`aMedical Economics Co., 1997.
`bPrescription assigned to diagnoses by the authors using the daily dosage for the average patient requiring
`an ulcer treatment as suggested by Medical Economics Co. (1997).
`
`13 The doctors in the sample were not chosen following any sampling technique, since the only information
`available was their “id” number.
`14 This four digit code, the ATC code, is an international classiIcation s

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket