throbber
THE JOURNAL OF INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS
`
`Volume LII
`
`September 2004
`
`0022-1821
`
`No. 3
`
`WHAT EXPLAINS THE USE OF DIRECT-TO-CONSUMER
`ADVERTISING OF PRESCRIPTION DRUGS?*
`
`TOSHIAKI IIZUKA'l‘
`
`Following the clarification of advertising regulation in 1997, direct—to—
`consumer advertising (DTCA) of prescription drugs has skyrocketed in
`the US, creating a controversy over the role of DTCA. Little is known,
`however, regarding what affects firms’ advertising decisions and which
`drugs have been advertised to consumers. Using brand—level advertising
`data, I examine the determinants of DTCA of prescription drugs. I find
`that drugs that are new, of high quality, and for under—treated diseases
`are more frequently advertised. Furthermore, advertising outlays
`decrease with competition. These results complement the demand—side
`evidence that DTCA has a market—expanding effect but little business—
`stealing effect.
`
`I.
`
`INTRODUCTION
`
`Direct-to-consumer advertising (DTCA) of prescription drugs had been
`viewed as taboo for a long time. Traditionally, pharmaceutical firms have
`promoted their prescription drugs through detailingithe face-to-face
`selling by medical representatives directly to physicians. The clarification of
`advertising regulations in 1997, however, changed this tradition drastically.
`Now,
`firms can use product-specific television commercialsiwhich
`mention both the name and the use of the drugito promote their
`prescription drugs to consumers without fully disclosing the risks of the
`drugs. As a result, within only five years after the clarification of regulations,
`prescription drug advertising expenditures skyrocketed from $800 million in
`1996 to $2.7 billion in 2001.
`The dramatic increase of DTCA has created a new controversy over the
`role of advertising in the prescription drug market. The main argument in
`favor of the new policy is that consumers can gain valuable information
`through DTCA. It is argued, for example, that advertising can inform
`patients about new medications for diseases that were believed to be
`
`*I wish to thank Dan Ackerberg, Bill Comanor, Austun Goolsbee, V. Joseph Hotz, Tom
`Hubbard, Phillip Leslie, Jean—Laurent Rosenthal, the editor and an anonymous referee for
`helpful comments and suggestions. I am grateful for TNS Media Intelligence/Competitive
`Media Reporting (CMR) for generously providing the data for this study. Remaining errors
`are my own.
`
`TAuthor’s affiliations: Owen Graduate School of Management, Vanderbilt University, 401
`21SI Ave. South, Nashville, TN 37203, USA.
`e—mail: toshi.iizuka@owen. vanderbilt.edu
`© Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2004, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK, and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.
`349
`
`Argentum Pharm. LLC v. Alcon Research, Ltd.
`Case IPR2017-01053
`
`ALCON 2070
`
`

`

`350
`
`TOSHIAKI IIZUKA
`
`untreatable by medicines. On the other hand, critics are concerned, for
`example, that DTCA may affect the choice of treatments by providing
`information of suspect quality and encourage people to try more expensive
`drugs though equally effective, but cheaper, drugs may be available.
`Responding to these concerns, the Food and Drug Administration (FDA)
`has recently announced that it will review its policy on DTCA.1
`Despite the surge of DTCA, its potential effects on consumer health, and
`the intensive policy debates, economics research on DTCA of prescription
`drugs is scarce. In particular,
`little is known about what affects
`pharmaceutical firms’ advertising decisions and which drugs have been
`advertised to consumers. The main objective of this paper is to fill this gap by
`analyzing the determinants of DTCA. A striking feature of DTCA is that,
`unlike detailing promotion, it is concentrated on a small number of drugs in
`some specific therapeutic categories. Using a unique panel data set that
`contains more than 600 drug-year observations over 1996–1999, I examine
`when and why firms advertise. To this end, a censored regression model,
`which takes into account zero advertising expenditure by many firms, and a
`two-stage model, which allows for a qualitative difference between ‘whether
`to advertise’ and ‘how much to advertise’ are estimated. I make reference to
`various classes of advertising theories to guide the empirical analysis.
`To be sure, the main reason for the lack of research is that DTCA of
`prescription drugs is only a recent phenomenon. On the demand side,
`however, a few recent papers have started exploring the effects of DTCA.
`Rosenthal et al. [2003] examine the effects of DTCA on the sales of six
`therapeutic classes and find that DTCA has a significant effect on aggregate
`demand but does not affect market shares within each class. Similarly,
`Iizuka and Jin [2003] find that DTCA leads to a large increase in outpatient
`visits, but has no effect on doctors’ specific choices among prescription drugs
`within a therapeutic class. Wosinska [2002] focuses on cholesterol-reducing
`drugs and finds that DTCA affects the demand for an individual brand
`positively, but the impact is substantially smaller than that of detailing
`promotion. All of these papers suggest that DTCA may have a large market-
`expanding effect but little or no business-stealing effect.
`On the supply side, as noted before, little research exists on DTCA of
`prescription drugs. Previous papers have examined, instead, various aspects
`of detailing promotion. Leffler [1981] observed a cross-section of 35
`therapeutic categories (not individual drugs) and examined the differences in
`detailing intensity across the categories. He found that empirical results are
`consistent with both ‘informative’ and ‘persuasive’ views of advertising.
`Hurwitz and Caves [1988] looked at a cross-section of 56 off-patent drugs
`
`1 The Wall Street Journal, ‘FDA to Review Policy Allowing Drug Ads on TV,’ March 28,
`2001.
`
`r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2004.
`
`

`

`DIRECT-TO-CONSUMER ADVERTISING OF PRESCRIPTION DRUGS
`
`351
`
`and analyzed the determinants of detailing intensity. They found that,
`among other findings, branded products’ detailing intensity decreases as the
`number of generic competitors increases.
`Several empirical results are worth noting. First, I find that firms are more
`likely to advertise newer and higher-quality drugs rather than older and
`lower quality ones, other things being equal. The latter indicates that DTCA
`and product quality complement each other in this market. Second, firms
`advertise more when the number of potential patients, rather than currently
`treated patients, is large. This complements the demand-side evidence that
`DTCA has a market-expanding effect but little or no business-stealing
`effect. This result is also consistent with the claim of proponents that DTCA
`targets under-diagnosed therapeutic classes and, thus, could be welfare
`improving. Third, I find that firms advertise less when therapeutic and
`generic competition gets intense. This suggests that DTCA does not have a
`strong effect to shift market shares among alternative drugs, which is also
`consistent with the demand-side finding discussed above. Lastly, I find early
`entrants are more likely to advertise than late entrants. This suggests that the
`return from DTCA is higher for early entrants, i.e., ‘first mover advantages’
`in DTCA appear to exist in this market.
`The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section II briefly
`reviews regulations and controversies on DTCA. Section III discusses the
`potential determinants of DTCA. After describing the data and variables in
`the next section, Section V discusses estimation and identification issues.
`Section VI presents results, and Section VII discusses alternative explana-
`tions. Section VIII concludes the paper.
`
`II. PRESCRIPTION DRUG ADVERTISING: REGULATION AND CONTROVERSY
`
`II(i). An Overview of Advertising Regulation
`
`Promoting prescription drugs directly to consumers is a recent phenomen-
`on. Traditionally, prescription drugs have been marketed exclusively to
`physicians either by detailing promotion, or, to a lesser extent, by advertising
`in medical journals. Pharmaceutical firms assumed that doctors would never
`accept a program that bypassed them, and DTCA was conceived as suicidal
`(Pines [1999]).
`In the early 1980s, however, a few firms started advertising their products
`directly to consumers. The FDA took this seriously and asked the industry
`for a voluntary prohibition period during which the FDA would study the
`impact of DTCA on public health. In 1985, the FDA announced that current
`regulations, the Kefauver-Harris drug amendments of 1962, were sufficient
`to protect consumers. This meant that, as long as manufacturers provided a
`‘brief summary’ of contraindications, side effects, and effectiveness and
`maintained ‘fair balance’ among them, DTCA would be permissible. The
`
`r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2004.
`
`

`

`352
`
`TOSHIAKI IIZUKA
`
`FDA appeared to move in this new direction because, for one reason, it
`recognized that consumers increasingly wanted to obtain more information
`about prescription drugs (Pines [1999]).
`Not surprisingly, DTCA increased thereafter but was mostly limited to
`newspapers and magazines because of the ‘brief summary’ requirement.
`Providing the ‘brief summary’ is costly for firms since it commonly occupies
`a full page or more of magazine space even though firms use very tiny fonts to
`describe them. The FDA essentially required TV advertising to abide by the
`same rule, and thus DTCA was prohibitively expensive for TV media.
`Accordingly, firms did not often use TV commercials to promote
`prescription drugs.
`There were two conditions, however, under which firms could avoid
`the ‘brief summary’ in TV advertising. One was the so-called ‘help-seeking’
`ad in which only disease symptoms were mentioned but not the specific name
`of the drug. The other was when the firm mentioned only the name of the
`drug without saying what it was for. The use of these types of ads
`continuously increased during the mid 1990s. The rapid growth of
`Health Maintenance Organizations (HMOs) and the increase of break-
`through drugs might have encouraged firms to use this new channel of
`communication.
`It was not until 1997, however, that a breakthrough occurred when the
`FDA further relaxed its regulation of ethical drug advertising on TV. For the
`first time, the FDA permitted product-specific DTCA on TV, which
`mentioned both the drug’s name and the condition for which it was to be
`used, without disclosing the ‘brief summary.’ Now firms needed only to
`include ‘major statements’ of the risks and benefits of the drug, which
`required substantially less information and airtime. Thus, by reducing the
`cost of advertising, the policy change contributed to the surge of DTCA after
`1997. Pines [1999] explains that the FDA made this change because it
`recognized that ads that mentioned a drug’s name but not its use were non-
`communicative and even confusing to consumers. Wilikes et al. [2000] also
`point out that ‘the political and regulatory climate was moving toward
`allowing consumers more choice and empowering them to share in medical
`decision making.’
`An interesting feature of DTCA is that the FDA assumes jurisdiction over
`it because the FDA views DTCA as a ‘label,’ a package insert describing the
`characteristics of the drug. Accordingly, the FDA monitors and enforces
`information contents of DTCA quite vigorously.2 In fact, pharmaceutical
`firms often ask the FDA to review their advertising commercials before they
`launch an advertising campaign. Because of these interactions, as well as the
`
`2 The FDA has threatened violating firms with legal actions,
`including seizure and
`injunction. Pines [1999] discusses the history of the FDA’s enforcement activities in detail.
`
`r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2004.
`
`

`

`DIRECT-TO-CONSUMER ADVERTISING OF PRESCRIPTION DRUGS
`
`353
`
`‘major statements’ and ‘fair balance’ requirements, prescription drug
`advertising is likely to convey credible information on drug attributes.
`
`II(ii). The Effects of the Relaxation of Advertising Regulation
`
`Following the FDA clarification in 1997, DTCA of ethical drugs increased
`dramatically. Within five years of the clarification, DTCA surged from $800
`million in 1996 to $2.7 billion in 2001. The surge of DTCA, however, was not
`observed equally across drugs and therapeutic classes. On the contrary,
`firms have been very selective in the use of DTCA. In 1999, approximately
`41% of total DTCA ($1.8 billion) was spent for the top ten advertised drugs,
`while their sales share was only 9%.3 Why do firms sometimes use DTCA to
`promote their drugs but not always? I will discuss some potential
`determinants of DTCA in this market in the next section.
`Anecdotal evidence shows that DTCA has indeed encouraged potential
`patients to seek medical help. Based on a national survey conducted in 1998,
`Prevention magazine found that DTCA encouraged a projected 21.2 million
`consumers to talk with their doctors about a medical condition or illness
`they had not previously talked with their doctor about before seeing an
`advertisement. Furthermore, the magazine estimates that 12.1 million
`people received a prescribed drug as a direct result of seeing a DTC
`advertisement. A Time survey conducted in 1998 also shows that one-fourth
`of consumers who saw an advertisement on television or in a magazine and
`spoke with their physicians about it received a prescription.
`
`II(iii). Controversies
`
`The tremendous increase in DTCA and prescriptions in recent years has
`created a major controversy over the effects of such advertising on
`pharmaceutical demand. In particular, two distinct views exist on the
`effects of DTCA. Proponents of DTCA argue that the match between
`patient and drug could be improved if consumers were informed about
`prescription drugs through direct consumer advertising (Masson and Rubin
`[1985]). They also argue that direct advertising plays an important role in
`informing the public of the existence of treatments of diseases, some
`previously not believed to be treatable by medicines (Masson and Rubin
`[1985]; Holmer [1999]). It is known that a number of leading diseases,
`including diabetes, high-cholesterol, and high-blood pressure, are under-
`diagnosed or under-treated. Thus, they argue, DTCA could help improve
`the health of people with these conditions. Holmer [1999]
`further
`
`3 DTCA figures are from IMS Health’s press release,
`‘IMS Health Reports U.S.
`Pharmaceutical Promotion Spending Reached Record $13.9 billion in 1999,’ on April 20,
`2000. Sales figures are also from IMS Health reported in Pharmacy Times, ‘The Top 200 Drugs
`of 1999,’ http://www.pharmacytimes.com/ top200.html.
`
`r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2004.
`
`

`

`354
`
`TOSHIAKI IIZUKA
`
`hypothesizes that ‘DTCA merely motivates patients to learn more about
`medical conditions and treatment options and to consult their physicians,
`but once the dialogue is started, the physician’s role is preeminent (page
`381).’ In sum, proponents claim that DTCA provides valuable information
`to consumers and increases physician visits. They argue that DTCA does
`not, however, affect the choice of prescription.
`On the other hand, opponents of DTCA are concerned that it may affect
`the choice of prescription and increase the cost of services. Hollon [1999]
`argues that DTCA may provide information of suspect quality and, ‘by
`creating consumer demand, undermine the protection that is a result of
`requiring a physician to certify a patient’s need for a prescription drug.’
`Others also argue that DTCA may encourage people to try more expensive
`drugs although equally effective, but cheaper, drugs may be available
`(Cohen [1988]). Further, it is often reported that many physicians fear that
`under-informed patients will demand inappropriate therapies from doctors
`once they have seen DTCA. That is, opponents argue that DTCA may
`manipulate the choice of prescription, and this could be harmful for patients
`and increase medical costs as well. Clearly, the source of the controversy is
`the role of DTCA in this market.
`While the main objective of this paper is to examine the determinants of
`DTCA and not to distinguish between these two claims, nonetheless, some
`of the results of the paper might help clarify the validity of these claims. For
`example, I consider whether DTCA outlays are more responsive to ‘current’
`market size as opposed to ‘potential’ market size. Also, I examine whether
`competition with generic drugs would increase brand-name drugs’
`advertising outlays. If the answers are ‘yes’ to these questions, the results
`are less likely to support the proponents’ claim since the ‘informative’ role of
`advertising is secondary in this situation. Now, I turn to the analytical
`framework to examine the determinants of DTCA.
`
`III. DETERMINANTS OF DTCA OF PRESCRIPTION DRUGS
`
`DTCA in the prescription drug market is unique in that the use of
`advertising is concentrated on a small number of products. This section
`discusses various classes of advertising theories that may help explain why
`and when firms use DTCA to promote their prescription drugs.
`
`III(i). Competition and DTCA
`
`Brand Competition: Economists have long debated the effects of competi-
`tion on advertising (and vice versa).4 Earlier literature on this issue often
`
`4 A large number of earlier papers examined inter-industry relationship between profitability
`(or concentration) and advertising intensity (e.g. Telser [1964]; Schmalensee, [1972]; Comanor
`and Wilson, [1974]).
`
`r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2004.
`
`

`

`DIRECT-TO-CONSUMER ADVERTISING OF PRESCRIPTION DRUGS
`
`355
`
`found that advertising decreases as competition gets intense. For example, in
`their classic paper, Dorfman and Steiner [1954] showed that a monopolist’s
`advertising intensity decreases as demand elasticity increases, other things
`being equal. Based on this result, it is often argued that advertising intensity
`should decrease with competition, since demand is more elastic in comp-
`etitive markets.5 More recently, Grossman and Shapiro [1984] examined the
`effects of competition on advertising in the case of differentiated product
`oligopoly. They show that in the case of ‘informative’ advertising – which
`informs consumers about the existence and characteristics of the product –
`firms reduce their advertising when there are more close substitutes in the
`market. This happens because, as the number of close substitute increases,
`consumers are likely to receive an ad from a firm located close to the
`consumer, whose product provides a better match between the product and
`patient. This in turn reduces firms’ incentive to advertise.6 Moreover, if
`DTCA has a market-expanding effect but not a business-stealing effect as
`the demand-side papers suggest, then advertising should decrease with
`competition since competitors may be able to free ride on rival firms’
`advertising.
`Others argue, however, that firms increase advertising when competition
`becomes intense. Becker and Murphy [1993] argue that, as close substitutes
`increase, firms may try to differentiate themselves by using advertising, and
`this will lead to higher advertising expenditures. For example, they discuss
`that ‘Perdue chicken’ (and other products in a competitive market) is
`extensively advertised because ‘Perdue ads convince consumers that a pound
`of its chicken is worth more than a pound of other chickens.’ (pp. 954–55).
`Cabral [2000] also notes that as the number of competitors increases, each
`firm’s incentive to engage in business-stealing advertising may increase. This
`may be the case because the return from such advertising may increase as the
`residual demand increases. In summary, DTCA of prescription drugs could
`either increase or decrease as competition gets intense: which effect
`dominates the other is an empirical question.
`
`5 Becker and Murphy [1993], however, revisit the Dorfman and Steiner model and show that
`the earlier discussion was sensitive to the assumption, and incentive to advertise may indeed
`either increase or decrease with competition.
`6 Grossman and Shapiro [1984] assume that consumer has no alternative sources of
`information, and is unaware of the existence of a particular brand unless she sees an
`advertisement describing it. In addition, consumers are assumed to remember all advertising
`messages transmitted to them. Under these assumptions, they show informative advertising
`decreases with competition. I believe these assumptions are not unreasonable in the case of
`prescription drugs, especially for newly discovered drugs, because it is costly for consumers to
`obtain information on prescription drugs. However, if we relax these assumptions, above-
`mentioned results may not hold. For example, if patients do not know or remember the
`characteristics of the drug, a monopolist may wish to (re)inform the patients about the drug’s
`characteristics once a rival drug enters the market. In this case, informative advertising may
`increase with competition.
`
`r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2004.
`
`

`

`356
`
`TOSHIAKI IIZUKA
`
`Generic Entry: It is well known that generic entry has a major impact on the
`market share of brand-name drugs. Typically, within a few months after
`patent expiration, generic entry takes place, and firms sell their generic drugs
`as low as 80% below the branded drug’s former list price (S&P [1999]). While
`the price response to generic entry of branded products has been a source of
`controversy,7 market share of branded drugs typically drops substantially
`due to drastic demand shift to generics.8 As a result, revenue of branded
`drugs often drops sharply after patent expiration.
`To protect their profits, incumbents may increase DTCA to differentiate
`the brand-name drug from generics. Again, the motivation is very similar to
`the ‘Perdue chicken’ example discussed above and thus requires no further
`explanation. Note, however, that advertising is likely to be wasteful in this
`case since generics are mostly identical to the branded drug in terms of
`pharmacological benefits to patients. Unlike the case of competition among
`brands discussed above, advertising cannot improve the matching between
`products and patients here.
`On the other hand, firms may reduce DTCA upon generic entry due to
`externality of advertising. In particular, many states in the U.S. have
`adopted mandatory substitution laws that require pharmacists to dispense
`generics if they are available unless doctors say otherwise.9 This means that
`even when patients request a branded drug that they saw on television and a
`physician actually prescribes it, the brand-name drug may not be dispensed
`at a pharmacy if equivalent generic drugs are available. Since the return from
`advertising may be lower under this situation, firms may reduce advertising
`expenditure upon generic entry.
`
`III(ii). Market-Expanding vs. Business-Stealing
`
`Next, I examine whether DTCA is used to expand the size of the market or
`shift market shares among existing brands. Advertising is viewed as market
`expanding when it purely increases the total size of the market. In contrast, it
`is referred to as business stealing when it solely shifts market share among
`existing brands. This distinction has long been recognized in advertising
`literature. Friedman [1983], for example, described the two types of advert-
`ising as ‘cooperative’ and ‘predatory,’ respectively. Roberts and Samuelson
`[1988] empirically examined the nature of cigarette advertising and found
`that it had primarily a market-expanding effect rather than a business-
`
`7 See Caves, Whinston, and Hurwitz [1991], Grabowski and Vernon [1992], Frank and
`Salkever [1997], and Wiggins and Maness [forthcoming] for the debate.
`8 For example, during the first week of patent expiration of Prozac, a blockbuster anti-
`depressant drug selling $2.6 billion in 2000, eighty percent of U.S. patients switched to a generic
`equivalent (The Financial Times, ‘Majority of Prozac-Users Switch to Generics,’ August 21,
`2001)
`9 See Hellerstein [1998] for more about the mandatory substitution law and its effects.
`
`r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2004.
`
`

`

`DIRECT-TO-CONSUMER ADVERTISING OF PRESCRIPTION DRUGS
`
`357
`
`stealing effect. In contrast, Gasmi et al. [1992] found that advertising in the
`carbonated soft-drink industry is primarily characterized as business
`stealing. Typically, advertising has been viewed as welfare reducing unless
`it increases total market demand.10
`These distinctions are also important in the current context. As discussed
`in Section II, one of the main arguments in favor of DTCA was that DTCA
`encourages patients to visit physicians’ offices and seek medical help.
`Because many chronic diseases, such as high cholesterol and diabetes, are
`seriously under-diagnosed and under-treated, they argue, DTCA could
`potentially improve welfare by informing future patients of the existence of
`treatments. In other words, proponents argue that DTCA has primarily a
`market-expanding effect rather than a business-stealing effect. Empirically,
`I distinguish the two effects by examining whether DTCA is targeted to
`currently treated or untreated patients. Naturally, market-expanding
`advertising should be sensitive to the number of currently untreated
`patients, while business-stealing advertising should respond to the number
`of currently treated patients.
`
`III(iii). Drug Quality and DTCA
`
`Another issue of interest is the relationship between product quality and
`DTCA. Specifically, I ask whether firms spend more advertising dollars for
`high-quality drugs or low-quality ones. Traditionally, economists have
`discussed whether product quality and advertising are complements or
`substitutes. The most often cited theory that connects advertising to product
`quality is Nelson’s [1974] theory of advertising as a signal of quality. He
`argues that the mere fact that firms spend a lot of money in advertising
`reveals its high quality even when ads do not contain any explicit quality
`information. This is possible because, for experience goods whose quality
`can be judged only after consumption, high-quality products are more likely
`to attract repeat purchases. The return from advertising that induces initial
`purchases is higher for high-quality products, and thus high-quality firms
`will spend more on advertising. Milgrom and Roberts [1986] formalized
`Nelson’s idea by allowing both price and dissipative advertising to be used as
`signals of quality. They show that a separating equilibrium exists in which
`only high-quality firms advertise, as long as the marginal cost advantage of
`low-quality firms is not substantially large.11 If otherwise, price alone can
`signal quality and advertising will not be used as a signal.
`There are other situations, however, in which firms may advertise more
`when the drug is of high quality. In particular, if advertising can directly
`
`10 See Becker and Murphy [1993] (pp. 959–60) for more discussions.
`11 While I do not observe marginal costs in my data, marginal costs are typically small in the
`case of prescription drugs and may not increase substantially even for high-quality drugs.
`
`r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2004.
`
`

`

`358
`
`TOSHIAKI IIZUKA
`
`inform the quality of the product to consumers and marginal costs of high-
`quality products are not substantially higher than that of low-quality
`products, then marginal return from advertising may be higher for high-
`quality drugs. This would also encourage high quality producers to advertise
`more. In fact, this is also a plausible scenario in the current case since, as
`discussed before, prescription drug advertising is likely to convey credible
`quality information. Also, marginal costs are generally small and are not
`likely to increase substantially even for high quality drugs. Thus, at least two
`views predict that high-quality drugs will advertise more.
`
`III(iv). Order of Entry
`
`Next, I examine whether order of entry in each market affects the use of
`DTCA. This is certainly possible if the marginal return of DTCA is different
`depending on the timing of entry. One can easily think of a case in which
`early entrants advertise more than late entrants. For example, because the
`cost of learning is high for physicians, physicians might form a ‘habit’ and
`keep prescribing the same drugs, most likely pioneer drugs. In fact, such
`persistence of doctors’ prescription behavior has been shown in recent
`literature including Hellerstein [1998], Stern and Trajtenberg [1998], and
`Coscelli [2000]. Under this circumstance, return from advertising may be
`higher for early entrants, and this would make them advertise more than late
`entrants.
`Whether there is an asymmetry in the effectiveness of marketing
`instruments is a recent research agenda in marketing literature. Bowman
`and Gatignon [1996], for example, examined whether order of entry affects
`the effectiveness of advertising. Their results from two durables and three
`nondurables, however, did not support an asymmetric effect of advertising.
`In contrast, Shankar et al.
`[1998] showed that, using data from 13
`pharmaceutical brands in the 1970s and 1980s, noninnovative late entrants
`have less effective marketing spending compared to pioneers.
`It should be noted that if the order of entry does indeed affect the extent of
`advertising, then DTCA might affect market structure and firms’ R&D
`decisions in the long run. In particular, if early entrants enjoy the benefits of
`DTCA more than late entrants do, then returns for a pioneer would increase
`while the incentives to develop ‘me-too’ drugs would decrease. Thus, the race
`to become a pioneer may become intense and only a smaller number of firms
`may be able to exist in each market. DTCA may lead to a more concentrated
`market structure.
`
`III(v). Drug Age and DTCA
`
`Finally, I examine whether the use of DTCA varies depending on the age of
`the drug. Various advertising models predict different time paths. For
`
`r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2004.
`
`

`

`DIRECT-TO-CONSUMER ADVERTISING OF PRESCRIPTION DRUGS
`
`359
`
`example, if the role of advertising were to inform consumers about the
`existence of products as in Grossman and Shapiro [1984], then newer drugs
`would be advertised more often than older drugs. Over time, as people learn
`about the drug through advertisement, the informative role of advertising
`becomes less important, and thus DTCA may decrease as the drug gets
`older, other things equal. Nelson’s signaling model (e.g., Milgrom and
`Roberts [1986])Fwhich assumes perfect learningFpredicts the same time
`path because the return from signaling quality will diminish over time as the
`number of experienced consumers increases. Horstmann and MacDonald
`[1994], however, show that the conclusion may be reversed, i.e., advertising
`expenditures increase over time, if the learning of consumers is imperfect. In
`a separate paper (Horstmann and MacDonald [2003]), they examine
`compact disc players and show that advertising expenditures increase over
`time in this market.
`
`IV. DATA AND VARIABLES
`
`The data set was compiled from several sources, as described below. I have a
`total of 606 drug-year observations for 169 unique brand-name drugs over
`the period 1996–1999. These drugs belong to one of the following broad
`categories: central nervous system agents, respiratory agents, and renal and
`genitourinary agents.12 Drug Facts and Comparisons, a standard medical
`reference, was consulted to discover drugs that belong to each of these
`categories. Drugs approved before 1982 were excluded from the estimation
`because of the lack of comparable information. However, I included these
`drugs when counting the number of competing drugs in each therapeutic
`class (see below). Definitions of variables and data sources are summarized
`in Table I.
`DTCA Expenditure for each brand-name drug was obtained from TNS
`Media Intelligence/Competitive Media Reporting (CMR). CMR monitors
`advertising units and expenditures for several different media, including
`cable TV, network TV, newspapers and magazines. All ads for prescription
`drugs that appeared in these media are included in the CMR database. In the
`estimation, I use annual total DTCA expenditure as the dependent variable.
`Age of Drug was calculated as the year since FDA approval. The date of
`FDA approval was obtained from the FDA’s Orange Book. While the FDA
`approval date may not be exactly the same as the product launch date, the
`difference is usually not very large. Thus, I use the FDA approval date to
`calculate the age of the drug.
`
`12 I limit my samples to these categories largely due to the high cost of constructing the data
`set. While the estimation results may or may not extend to the remaining categories, these
`categories represent roughly 46% of industry sales in 1996 (S&P [1999]).
`
`r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2004.
`
`

`

`360
`
`TOSHIAKI IIZUKA
`
`Table I
`Definition of theVariables and Data Source
`
`Variable
`
`DTC ads
`HIGH_Q
`
`1st Move
`
`2nd Move
`
`AGE
`G_ENTRY
`
`THRP_COMP
`
`PTNT_SIZE
`
`CRNT_SIZE
`
`ACUTE
`
`IN

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket