throbber
Product Differentiation Advantages of Pioneering Brands
`
`By RICHARD SCHMALENSEE*
`
`This essay presents and explores a rela-
`tively simple market model in which rational
`buyer behavior in the face of imperfect infor-
`mation about product quality can give long—
`lived advantages to pioneering brands. The
`analysis has some implications for the varia-
`tion in the strength of such advantages across
`markets with different basic conditions. Twe
`sorts of evidence provide the motivation for
`this research.
`First, Joe Bain’s seminal empirical study
`of conditions of entry led him to conclude
`that “the advantage to established sellers
`accruing from buyer preferences for their
`products as opposed to potential entrant
`products is on average larger and more fre—
`quent in occurrence at large values than any
`other barrier to entry” (p. 216). Treating
`advertising as a proxy for product differenti-
`ation, a large literature has attempted to test
`this assertion by relating advertising to prof~
`itability in cross section.1 It is interesting to
`note, however,
`that Bain concluded that
`advertising was not the main force at work:
`
`seem to
`these things might
`All of
`the existence of fundamental
`suggest
`technical considerations,
`institutional
`developments, and more or less funda-
`mental consumer
`traits which make
`possible or even very probable the de—
`velopment of strong and stable prod-
`uct—preference patterns. They may also
`
`*Professor of applied economics, Sloan School of
`Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology. I
`am grateful to the US. Federal Trade Commission for
`its support of this research. I am also grateful for helpful
`comments to Steven Salop, a referee,
`the managing
`editor, and seminar audiences at MIT, Chicago, Harvard,
`Princeton, Rochester,
`the Department of Justice,
`the
`Federal Trade Commission, and the Santa Barbara and
`San Diego campuses of the University of California.
`Naturally, only I can be held accountable for this essay’s
`shortcomings and the opinions it expresses.
`1William S. Comanor and Thomas A. Wilson and
`Harold Demsetz provide interesting overviews of this
`literature; see also my forthcoming essay, especially
`Section 3.
`
`suggest that advertising per se is not
`necessarily the main or even the most
`important key to the product differ-
`entiation problem.
`[p. 143]
`
`Bain did not explicitly describe any mecha-
`nism by which product differentiation ad-
`vantages might be created, but a number of
`his remarks pointed toward buyer uncer-
`tainty about product quality as centrally
`involved.2
`Second, conventional wisdom in market—
`ing and scattered recent empirical research
`support the notion that there are important
`advantages to being the first entrant in some
`sorts of markets. Marketers usually predict
`little success for “me too” brands,
`those
`claiming to be identical to established brands
`but selling at a lower price.3 The success of
`generic and private—label brands of some
`consumer products makes it clear that the
`strength of any handicap under which such
`brands operate must vary considerably across
`markets of different sorts. Ronald Bond and
`
`David Lean (1977, 1979) find that important
`and long-lived advantages are enjoyed by
`pioneering brands of prescription drugs,
`advantages that can be overcome by later
`entrants only if
`they offer distinct
`ther-
`apeutic benefits, not just lower prices. Ira
`Whittin’s study of cigarette market segments
`points in this same direction, as do the
`cross-section analysis of marketing costs by
`Robert Buzzell and Paul Farris, and the study
`of order-of—entry effects reported by Glen
`Urban and his associates.
`
`The next section describes the assumptions
`and notation employed and outlines the
`analysis of Sections II—V. Buyer learning
`about quality takes place over time, so that
`buyers and sellers generally face dynamic
`decision problems when quality information
`
`2See pp. 116, 140, and 142, as well as other discus-
`sions in ch. 4.
`3For typical statements, see Kenneth Runyon, p. 214,
`or J. O. Peckharn.
`
`349
`
`
`
`Copyright © 2001 All Rights Reserved
`
`Argentum Pharm. LLC V. Alcon Research, Ltd.
`Case IPR2017-01053
`
`ALCON 2068
`
`

`

`350
`
`
`
`THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW
`
`
`
`
`
`JUNE 1982
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`is incomplete. In order to render those prob-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`lems more or less tractable, a number of
`
`
`
`
`
`rather drastic simplifying assumptions are
`made. Like most exercises in economic the-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ory, this analysis should thus be thought of
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`as a parable illustrating a general principle,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`not as a literal description of any particular
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`piece of reality.4 The findings and some of
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`their implications for research and for public
`
`
`
`
`
`
`policy are summarized in Section VI.
`
`
`
`
`1. Assumptions and Notation
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Consider a narrowly defined product class,
`like freeze-dried instant coffee or stainless
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`steel razor blades, such that individual con-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sumers can be sensibly modeled as using at
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`most one brand in the class at any instant. It
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`is assumed for simplicity that brands in this
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`class either “wor ” or “don’t work”;
`they
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`either perform as a brand in this class should,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`or they fail to perform acceptably. This makes
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`it possible to describe uncertainty about the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`quality of a new brand by a single parame-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ter, the subjective probability that it won’t
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`work. It is assumed that these products are
`
`
`
`
`
`
`what Phillip Nelson (1970) christened “expe-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`rience goods,” so that the only way a con-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sumer can resolve uncertainty about quality
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`is to purchase a brand and try it. One trial is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`both necessary and sufficient to determine
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`whether or not any single brand works.
`Consumers differ in their valuation of
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`products in this class. Let the function Q(v),
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`0 < v < V, give the number of consumers
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`willing to pay at least 1) for a brand in this
`class that is certain to work. Each consumer
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`values a unit that doesn’t work at —- qbo, with
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`<1) a nonnegative constant. (One might have
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`<1) > 0 for a bleach that could ruin clothes, for
`
`
`
`
`
`instance.) Consumers are perfectly informed
`
`4A number of related works deserve mention here.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Christian von Weizsacher, ch. 5, considers a basically
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`competitive model of this sort of situation. The Bond
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and Lean (1979) model of first-entrant advantages relies
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`heavily on assumptions about buyers’ response to ad-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`vertising. Cecelia Conrad presents a dynamic model
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`resembling mine in some aspects, but she neglects the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`first brand’s problems of getting buyers to learn about
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`it. The development here traces its ancestry to the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`simple model in the Appendix of my 1979 article. Carl
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Shapiro’s recent work has a number of formal similari-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ties to mine.
`
`
`
`
`1
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`except about product quality, so that neither
`
`
`
`
`informative nor persuasive advertising oc-
`curs.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`The time between purchases is assumed
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`constant and equal to one period, so that
`trial of a new brand consumes the entire
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`normal interpurchase time. This assumption
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`can be altered without changing the basic
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`results, as long as the cost of learning about
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`a new brand’s quality is not made negligible
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`relative to current and expected future unit
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price. Let the one-period discount rate, as-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sumed the same for all consumers, be r. All
`
`
`
`
`
`
`else equal, more frequent purchase implies a
`smaller value of r. Consumers are assumed
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`to be risk neutral, to have infinite horizons,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and to behave rationally in a sense to be
`
`
`
`made precise shortly.
`
`
`
`
`
`The analysis below considers a two-stage
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`scenario. In the first stage, a pioneering brand
`
`
`
`
`
`
`enters the market and attains steady-state
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`equilibrium. I have in mind here the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`appearance of a distinctly new product, like
`stainless steel razor blades. It is assumed that
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the first brand actually works for all buyers.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`If buyers knew enough about the costs of
`
`
`
`
`
`producing working and nonworking brands,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`they
`and if they were very sophisticated,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`might attempt to infer the pioneering brand’s
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`quality from its price or simply from its ‘
`
`
`
`
`
`existence. It avoids serious game-theoretic
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`problems and does little violence to reality,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`especially in the case of new products, to
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`assume that buyers do not have enough in— .
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`formation to behave in this fashion.5 Instead,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`it is simply assumed that prior to the intro-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`duction of the first brand, all consumers ‘
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`have subjective probability 7 that it will not
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`work, and all act to maximize the discounted
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`value of expected utility. Trial of a new .
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand of unknown quality yields both an
`
`
`
`
`
`immediate utility payoff and information,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the value of which depends on future prices
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of the brand. Section II analyzes the first
`
`.
`
`5My 1978 article defends neglect of such signalling
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`considerations in this general context. This assumption
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and the assumption that information sources such as
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`word-of—mouth do not exist seem most plausible when
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`quality is subjective, so that consumers can disagree
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`about whether a brand actually works. In the interests
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of simplicity, I have not attempted to incorporate this
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sort of preference heterogeneity explicitly.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`.
`
`

`

`VOL. 72 N0. 3
`
`
`
`
`
`
`SCHMALENSEE: PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION 0F BRANDS
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`351
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand’s pricing problem under the extreme
`
`
`
`
`
`assumption that buyers have static expecta-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tions about prices. Section IV examines the
`
`
`
`
`
`implications of the polar opposite extreme
`
`
`
`
`
`assumption of perfect foresight. Neither as-
`
`
`
`
`
`sumption is especially attractive, but
`to-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`gether they should at
`least bound actual
`
`
`buyer expectations.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`In the second stage of the scenario consid-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ered here, a second, objectively identical
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand appears on the market. Innovation is
`ruled out in order to focus on the effects of
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`order of entry and on related barriers to
`imitation. The second brand is also assumed
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`to have exactly the same cost structure as the
`
`
`
`
`
`first. Two additional simplifying assump—
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tions are made. First, it is initially assumed
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`that the second brand is subjectively identi-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`cal to the first at the introductory stage, so
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`It
`that
`the same value of
`7r applies.
`is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`straightforward to relax this assumption, and
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`this is done in Section V. Second, it is as—
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sumed that the first brand does not change
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`prices in response to entry and that the sec-
`ond brand knows this in advance. This is a
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`much more passive response to new competi-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tion than is usually considered plausible.6 In
`
`
`
`
`
`an undifferentiated world,
`this behavior
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`would permit the second brand to undercut
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the first by an arbitrarily small amount, steal
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`all the first brand’s customers, and duplicate
`
`
`
`
`
`
`its profit performance. Regardless of cost
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`conditions, it would thus make it impossible
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`for the first brand to earn positive profits
`
`
`
`
`
`
`without attracting new entry. Despite this
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`assumption, it is shown below that the addi-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tion of uncertainty about quality can make a
`
`
`
`
`
`
`profitable pioneering brand immune to sub-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sequent entry. This assumption permits us to
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`avoid (at least in this essay) modeling the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`complicated dynamic game between the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and second brands that would be played
`
`
`
`
`after the latter’s entry.7
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Section III analyzes the second brand’s
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`pricing problem for the case of static expec-
`tations and demonstrates that brand’s order—
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`GSee, for instance, Avinash Dixit and the references
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`he cites.
`
`
`7Conrad’s paper illustrates the seriousness of these
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`complications. It may be necessary to make basic changes
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`in the model presented here in order to obtain a tracta—
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ble post-entry game.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of—entry disadvantage. Section IV shows that
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`our basic conclusions are equally valid in the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`polar opposite extreme case of perfect buyer
`
`
`
`
`
`
`foresight. The consequences of relaxing the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`assumptions that buyers assign the same ini-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tial probability of inadequacy to both first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and second brands, that they know for cer-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tain the value to them of a working brand,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and that purchase is necessary to get infor-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`mation about quality are explored in Sec-
`tion V.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`In my forthcoming essay, this basic setup
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`is analyzed under the assumption that buyers
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`correctly expect sellers never to change price.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`This very ad hoc pricing restriction drasti-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`cally simplifies the model and turns out not
`to alter the basic nature of its conclusions.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Since both brands actually work, each sells
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`forever to those consumers who try it when it
`is introduced and to no others. Both brands
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`then have well—defined demand curves, with
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the second brand’s curve depending on the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`first brand’s price. It is shown that the sec-
`ond brand’s demand curve has the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand’s price as its intercept. It coincides
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`with the first brand’s demand curve only for
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`prices distinctly below the first brand’s price.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`This means that with economies of scale, the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`(common) long—run average cost schedule can
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`lie everywhere above the second brand’s de-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`mand schedule even though the first brand is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`earning positive profits. The analysis below
`
`
`
`
`
`
`obtains essentially the same results without
`
`
`
`
`
`
`restricting price changes. Since the second
`brand’s demand curve turns out not to be
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`easily defined in general, however, there does
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`not seem to be a simple graphical description
`
`
`
`
`
`of the second brand’s disadvantage.
`
`
`
`
`
`II. Pricing the Pioneering Brand
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`In this section and the next, buyers have
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`static expectations;
`they expect the most re-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`cently observed price to hold forever, even if
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price has changed in the past. Suppose that
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`in order to try a new brand, a consumer
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ceases for the trial period to use a substitute
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`that yields a nonnegative surplus, s. Assum-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ing away income effects and indivisibilities,
`one can take s = 0 for the first brand.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`If a consumer would be willing to pay 0
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`for a working brand in this class, immediate
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Copyright © 2001 All Rights Reserved
`
`

`

`352
`
`
`
`THEAMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW
`
`
`
`
`
`JUNE 1982
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`trial of a new brand selling at price p is
`
`
`
`
`
`rational if and only if the following inequal-
`
`
`
`ity is satisfied:8
`
`
`
`
`(1) 7T[(—<;>v—IJ)+(S/r)l+(1—w)
`
`
`
`
`
`
`><[(v—p)(l+r)/r] >s(l+r)/r.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`The first bracketed term on the left gives
`
`
`
`
`
`
`discounted surplus if the new brand is tried,
`
`
`
`
`
`doesn’t work, and the consumer switches
`back to the substitute. The second term on
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the left capitalizes the stream of surplus asso-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ciated with buying a brand that works at
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price p forever, and the term on the right
`
`
`
`
`
`
`gives the capitalized benefit of continuing to
`
`
`
`purchase the substitute.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Inequality (1) can be rewritten simply as
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`(2)
`
`p<v(1~r)*s,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`where the important quantity 1- is defined by
`
`
`
`
`
`r=7rr(l+<j>)/(l+r*w).
`(3)
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`If 1- = 0, condition (2) indicates that the new
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand will be purchased if and only if its net
`
`
`
`
`
`
`surplus, o — p, exceeds s. Larger values of 1-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`always discourage trial of a new brand. As
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`one would expect, a- is increasing in both 7r
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and n1), as these contribute to the expected
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`cost of trial. Larger values of r, which corre-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`spond to lower purchase frequency, also in-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`crease r. The lower is purchase frequency,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the more important is any single purchase
`relative to the entire future stream of
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`purchases. This makes the risk associated
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`with trying a new brand loom larger relative
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`to the alternative of sticking forever with the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`substitute. If 7?], condition (2) shows that
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`is so subjectively risky that it never
`trial
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`occurs at positive p. To rule this out, let us
`
`assume 0 < ‘1‘ <1 in all that follows.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`If the first brand on the market charges
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price p, and all buyers with v> p are sure
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`that it works, its sales equal Q( 17). Let 11(1))
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`be the per period profit function correspond-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ing to this demand curve. When the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand initially appears on the market, nobody
`
`8One can derive condition (1) with s = 0 more rigor-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ously by letting buyer utility be the sum of utility from
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`this product class (either zero, 0, or — 9512) and income
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`left over to spend on other goods. It is then straightfor-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ward to show that
`trial of the pioneering brand is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`optimal if and only if (1) holds with s = 0.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`is sure that it works, and condition (2), with
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`s=0, implies that a price 12 will produce ‘
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sales of Q[ p /(1 - 1-)]. Let the profit function
`
`
`
`
`
`corresponding to this less-attractive intro-
`‘
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ductory—period demand curve be II°( p), and
`
`
`
`
`
`
`assume both profit functions are globally
`
`
`strictly concave.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`‘
`In period 1, let 1_3 = V(l — 1-), and in later
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`,
`periods let 13 equal the lowest price previ-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ously charged. The demand curve for the ‘
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`pioneering brand then has the general shape
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of the solid kinked curve in Figure 1. If
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`p<£, some new buyers are reached, and
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`profits equal H°( p). If ng/(l— ’7'),
`the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`only buyers are those who have purchased
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the brand at least once before, and profits
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`are given by II(p). If I: <p < 1_’/(1-— 7),
`
`
`
`
`
`
`current profits could obviously be increased,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and no new customers are being informed, so
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`that prices in this range can never be opti-
`mal.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`If the pioneering brand adopts a monopoly
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Q-constant strategy, it maximizes profit sub-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ject to the constraint that it sell to the same
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`buyers in all periods. This constraint implies
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`that it charges a first-period price p0 and a
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price p in all later periods such that p0:
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`p(l - 1'). (See Figure l.) The optimal values
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of p and p0 can then be obtained by maxi-
`
`
`
`
`mizing {H°[p(1—T)1+<1/r)mp1}- This
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sort of
`low/high pricing sequence corre-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sponds roughly to what is called “penetra-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tion pricing” in the marketing and managerial
`economics literature.9 One can show that if
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`marginal production cost is positive, a mo-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`nopoly Q-constant policy yields an output
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`level below that which would be chosen by
`
`
`
`
`
`
`an ordinary monopolist with profit function
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`H( p) because of the extra marginal cost that
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the pioneering firm must incur in order to
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`persuade buyers (by means of a low price) to
`
`
`
`
`
`
`try its ex ante risky product.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`In Appendix A, it is shown that the mo-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`nopoly Q-constant strategy just described is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the best dynamic pricing policy for the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand, as long as no thought is given to
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`possible subsequent entry. In order to high-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`light those aspects of later entrants’ prob-
`9See Joel Dean for a brief discussion and a compari-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`son with the alternative high/low strategy usually called
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`“cream-skimming” and more commonly associated with
`
`
`
`
`
`
`durable goods.
`
`
`
`

`

`VOL. 72 N0. 3
`
`
`
`
`
`
`SCHMA LENSEE: PRODUCT DIFFERENTIA TION 0F BRANDS
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`353
`
`
`
`oE/u—rfl
`FIGURE 1. SINGLE PERIOD DEMAND FOR THE PIONEERING BRAND
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`lems that arise naturally, I assume away any
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`such thoughts on the part of the first brand.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Allowing the pioneering brand to price stra-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tegically could only strengthen the results
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`obtained below at a high cost in added com-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`plexity. On the other hand, little is gained by
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`confining the first brand to the monopoly
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Q-constant strategy defined above. It is thus
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`assumed below only that the first entrant
`
`
`
`
`
`follows some Q-constant policy, charging
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price P1(l - 'r) in the first period and P1 in
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`all periods thereafter, and selling Q( P1) in all
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`periods. Under any such policy, the levelized
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`per period equivalent
`to the first brand’s
`
`
`
`
`
`average revenue stream is simply
`
`i=[11r][P1(1~7>+P1/r1
`
`_
`_ ra-
`—P‘[1
`l+r]‘
`
`<4)
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`III. Demand Conditions Facing a Later Entrant
`
`
`
`Because the first brand has followed a
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Q-constant policy,
`the second brand faces
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`two and only two distinct
`types of con-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sumers. If the first brand’s price is P1, those
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`consumers with v < Pl have never tried the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`first brand. If the second brand then charges
`
`
`
`
`
`
`introductory price p, the condition for trial is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`again given by (2) with s = 0, as for the first
`brand:
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`(5a)
`
`v<P1 and p<v(1—r).
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Consumers with high 12’s are a second type
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of buyer, as they have already tried brand
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`one and found it to work. Because purchase
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of brand one yields a surplus of (v - P1), the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Copyright © 2001 All Rights Reserved
`
`
`
`

`

`354
`
`THEAMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW
`
`
`
`
`
`JUNE 1982
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`P,
`ngu-r)
`(PI —P§)/r
`v
`FIGURE 2. FIRST-PERIOD DEMAND PRICES FACING A LATER ENTRANT
`
`V
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`condition for trial is given by (2) with s = v
`
`_ P1210
`
`(5b)
`
`12>P1 and p<P1—'rv.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Condition (5b) shows that consumers with
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`large values of v are least likely to try brand
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`two, even though they were most likely to try
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand one. Their high valuation of brand
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`one, after they have made the investment of
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`trying it, gives them a high opportunity cost
`
`
`
`
`of trying brand two.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`The demand conditions facing brand two
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`in its first period are depicted in Figure 2.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Prior to the second brand’s appearance, the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`first brand (assumed to have completed the
`
`10One can derive condition (5b) more formally using
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the framework sketched in fn. 8, above. The difference
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`is that the alternative to trying the second brand yields
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`utility of u from this product class for certain at a price
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of P1.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`introductory phase of a Q-constant policy)
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`charges P1 and sells Q(P1). If the second
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand charges an introductory price of P20,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`its first-period customers are those with 12’s
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`between the two intersection points of the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`p = P20 line with the heavy kinked curve. As
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Figure 2 is drawn, the second brand sells
`
`
`
`
`Q[P2°/(1—T)]~Q[(P1—P2°)/T]
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`in its first period. This is less than the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand would have sold had it charged P20
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`during its introductory period. Only if P20 is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`less than (P1 —'rV) are the second brand’s
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`introductory sales equal
`to those the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand would have achieved at the same price.
`If the second brand undercuts the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand’s price sequence, P,(1—- 1-) for one
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`period and P1 thereafter, by an arbitrarily
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`small amount, it will sell only to those buyers
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`with v’s arbitrarily close to P1. Such a policy
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`would give the second brand a levelized aver—
`
`

`

`VOL. 72 N0. 3
`
`
`
`
`
`
`SCI-[MA LENSEE: PRODUCT DIFFERENTIA TION 0F BRANDS
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`355
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`age revenue equal to that of the first brand,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`E, but it would make essentially zero sales.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Under constant returns, entry will occur in
`
`
`
`
`
`
`spite of this disadvantage (though at arbi-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`trarily small scale) if P1 exceeds unit cost.11
`
`
`
`
`
`
`With fixed costs or other economies of scale,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`however, it should be clear that PI can be
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`above the first firm’s average cost (at output
`
`
`
`
`Q(P1)) without provoking entry.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`If the second brand charges any first-period
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price between Pl(1 - r) and P1 - 7V, it makes
`fewer sales than the first brand would have
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`made at the same introductory price. Since
`
`
`
`
`
`first-period sales
`translate into informed
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`buyers willing to pay more because they
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`know the brand works, this difference is the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`heart of the second brand’s disadvantage. If
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the first seller of fluoride toothpaste can
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`persuade those who care a lot about cavities
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`to try one tube, and if the taste is acceptable
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`to most consumers, the second brand of fluo-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ride toothpaste will find it much harder to
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`get a trial. It will be compared to a known,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`acceptable fluoride toothpaste, while the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand was compared only to “ordinary”
`
`toothpaste.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`If the second brand charges an introduc-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tory price less than Pl"”TV, which is dis—
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tinctly less than the first brand’s introduc-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tory price, it thereby persuades all those who
`would have tried the first brand at that same
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price to try it. (That is, as Figure 2 should
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`make clear, its first-period demand is given
`
`
`
`
`
`
`by Q[P2°/(l~r)],
`the same function that
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`held for the first brand at all prices.) It then
`
`
`
`
`
`
`has essentially the same second-period op-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tions the first brand would have had. (The
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`second brand cannot
`sell anything if it
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`charges a price above P], but
`this is not
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`likely to be a relevant alternative.) If the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand could have earned positive profit with
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`a Q-constant strategy beginning with a very
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`low first-period price, the second brand will
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`find entry of the same sort attractive. Even
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`with constant costs, however, it is obviously
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`possible for the first brand to be highly
`
`
`
`
`
`
`profitable but entry at drastically lower prices
`
`
`
`to be unprofitable.
`
`
`
`
`
`The preceding discussion establishes the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`existence of a barrier to entry. Profitable
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`entry deterrence can occur in this model
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`even though potential entrants have the ex-
`
`
`
`
`
`the
`ceptionally optimistic expectation that
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`first brand’s price will never change, even if
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`they steal all its customers. In order to in-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`vestigate the importance of this barrier in
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`general, it would be necessary to calculate
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the second brand’s optimal price policy and
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the consequences of following it. This turns
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`out to be very difficult. The argument in
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Appendix A establishing that the first brand’s
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`optimal policy involves only one price change
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`can be applied to the second brand also. The
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`problem is that it is not always optimal for
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the second brand to follow a Q-constant
`
`policy.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`The nature of the difficulty here can be
`
`
`
`
`
`
`understood by examining the second brand’s
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`demand curve for periods after the first, as
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`shown by the heavy kinked curve in Figure
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`3. As above, I_’ is the lowest price this brand
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`has ever previously charged, and P1 is the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`first brand’s price. Figure 3 is drawn assum-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ing I_’ > P1_ TV. The flat portion of the de-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`mand curve at price P1 corresponds to those
`consumers who have tried both brands and
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`know that both work. The segment AB re-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`flects those who have tried only the second
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand because they found the first too ex-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`pensive. A reduction in 13 increases the length
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of the flat segment (moves point A to the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`right) as well as that of the declining seg-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ment. If the optimal introductory price is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`above P1 —- TV, it may be optimal to follow a
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Q-constant policy and go to a point like B
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`thereafter. On the other hand, since a low
`
`
`
`
`
`
`introductory price increases the number of
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand one’s customers who engage in trial, it
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`may be optimal to set a low introductory
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price for this purpose and then move to a
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`point like A in Figure 3.12 Finally, since a
`
`”Note that if entry occurs at small scale, the pioneer-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ing brand loses only a few of its customers, so that the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`present value of its excess profits may still be positive.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Thus even without scale economies, entry may not drive
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the pioneering brand to a zero (discounted) profit posi-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tion. I am indebted to Dennis Carlton for this observa—
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tion.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`l2If the first brand has followed a monopoly Q—con-
`stant policy, P1 exceeds the static, perfect information
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`monopoly price, as Appendix A shows. Thus marginal
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`revenue just to the right of point A in Figure 3 exceeds
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the first brand’s equilibrium marginal cost. If the second
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand’s ma

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket