`
`By RICHARD SCHMALENSEE*
`
`This essay presents and explores a rela-
`tively simple market model in which rational
`buyer behavior in the face of imperfect infor-
`mation about product quality can give long—
`lived advantages to pioneering brands. The
`analysis has some implications for the varia-
`tion in the strength of such advantages across
`markets with different basic conditions. Twe
`sorts of evidence provide the motivation for
`this research.
`First, Joe Bain’s seminal empirical study
`of conditions of entry led him to conclude
`that “the advantage to established sellers
`accruing from buyer preferences for their
`products as opposed to potential entrant
`products is on average larger and more fre—
`quent in occurrence at large values than any
`other barrier to entry” (p. 216). Treating
`advertising as a proxy for product differenti-
`ation, a large literature has attempted to test
`this assertion by relating advertising to prof~
`itability in cross section.1 It is interesting to
`note, however,
`that Bain concluded that
`advertising was not the main force at work:
`
`seem to
`these things might
`All of
`the existence of fundamental
`suggest
`technical considerations,
`institutional
`developments, and more or less funda-
`mental consumer
`traits which make
`possible or even very probable the de—
`velopment of strong and stable prod-
`uct—preference patterns. They may also
`
`*Professor of applied economics, Sloan School of
`Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology. I
`am grateful to the US. Federal Trade Commission for
`its support of this research. I am also grateful for helpful
`comments to Steven Salop, a referee,
`the managing
`editor, and seminar audiences at MIT, Chicago, Harvard,
`Princeton, Rochester,
`the Department of Justice,
`the
`Federal Trade Commission, and the Santa Barbara and
`San Diego campuses of the University of California.
`Naturally, only I can be held accountable for this essay’s
`shortcomings and the opinions it expresses.
`1William S. Comanor and Thomas A. Wilson and
`Harold Demsetz provide interesting overviews of this
`literature; see also my forthcoming essay, especially
`Section 3.
`
`suggest that advertising per se is not
`necessarily the main or even the most
`important key to the product differ-
`entiation problem.
`[p. 143]
`
`Bain did not explicitly describe any mecha-
`nism by which product differentiation ad-
`vantages might be created, but a number of
`his remarks pointed toward buyer uncer-
`tainty about product quality as centrally
`involved.2
`Second, conventional wisdom in market—
`ing and scattered recent empirical research
`support the notion that there are important
`advantages to being the first entrant in some
`sorts of markets. Marketers usually predict
`little success for “me too” brands,
`those
`claiming to be identical to established brands
`but selling at a lower price.3 The success of
`generic and private—label brands of some
`consumer products makes it clear that the
`strength of any handicap under which such
`brands operate must vary considerably across
`markets of different sorts. Ronald Bond and
`
`David Lean (1977, 1979) find that important
`and long-lived advantages are enjoyed by
`pioneering brands of prescription drugs,
`advantages that can be overcome by later
`entrants only if
`they offer distinct
`ther-
`apeutic benefits, not just lower prices. Ira
`Whittin’s study of cigarette market segments
`points in this same direction, as do the
`cross-section analysis of marketing costs by
`Robert Buzzell and Paul Farris, and the study
`of order-of—entry effects reported by Glen
`Urban and his associates.
`
`The next section describes the assumptions
`and notation employed and outlines the
`analysis of Sections II—V. Buyer learning
`about quality takes place over time, so that
`buyers and sellers generally face dynamic
`decision problems when quality information
`
`2See pp. 116, 140, and 142, as well as other discus-
`sions in ch. 4.
`3For typical statements, see Kenneth Runyon, p. 214,
`or J. O. Peckharn.
`
`349
`
`
`
`Copyright © 2001 All Rights Reserved
`
`Argentum Pharm. LLC V. Alcon Research, Ltd.
`Case IPR2017-01053
`
`ALCON 2068
`
`
`
`350
`
`
`
`THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW
`
`
`
`
`
`JUNE 1982
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`is incomplete. In order to render those prob-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`lems more or less tractable, a number of
`
`
`
`
`
`rather drastic simplifying assumptions are
`made. Like most exercises in economic the-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ory, this analysis should thus be thought of
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`as a parable illustrating a general principle,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`not as a literal description of any particular
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`piece of reality.4 The findings and some of
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`their implications for research and for public
`
`
`
`
`
`
`policy are summarized in Section VI.
`
`
`
`
`1. Assumptions and Notation
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Consider a narrowly defined product class,
`like freeze-dried instant coffee or stainless
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`steel razor blades, such that individual con-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sumers can be sensibly modeled as using at
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`most one brand in the class at any instant. It
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`is assumed for simplicity that brands in this
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`class either “wor ” or “don’t work”;
`they
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`either perform as a brand in this class should,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`or they fail to perform acceptably. This makes
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`it possible to describe uncertainty about the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`quality of a new brand by a single parame-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ter, the subjective probability that it won’t
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`work. It is assumed that these products are
`
`
`
`
`
`
`what Phillip Nelson (1970) christened “expe-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`rience goods,” so that the only way a con-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sumer can resolve uncertainty about quality
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`is to purchase a brand and try it. One trial is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`both necessary and sufficient to determine
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`whether or not any single brand works.
`Consumers differ in their valuation of
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`products in this class. Let the function Q(v),
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`0 < v < V, give the number of consumers
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`willing to pay at least 1) for a brand in this
`class that is certain to work. Each consumer
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`values a unit that doesn’t work at —- qbo, with
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`<1) a nonnegative constant. (One might have
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`<1) > 0 for a bleach that could ruin clothes, for
`
`
`
`
`
`instance.) Consumers are perfectly informed
`
`4A number of related works deserve mention here.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Christian von Weizsacher, ch. 5, considers a basically
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`competitive model of this sort of situation. The Bond
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and Lean (1979) model of first-entrant advantages relies
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`heavily on assumptions about buyers’ response to ad-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`vertising. Cecelia Conrad presents a dynamic model
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`resembling mine in some aspects, but she neglects the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`first brand’s problems of getting buyers to learn about
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`it. The development here traces its ancestry to the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`simple model in the Appendix of my 1979 article. Carl
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Shapiro’s recent work has a number of formal similari-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ties to mine.
`
`
`
`
`1
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`except about product quality, so that neither
`
`
`
`
`informative nor persuasive advertising oc-
`curs.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`The time between purchases is assumed
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`constant and equal to one period, so that
`trial of a new brand consumes the entire
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`normal interpurchase time. This assumption
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`can be altered without changing the basic
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`results, as long as the cost of learning about
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`a new brand’s quality is not made negligible
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`relative to current and expected future unit
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price. Let the one-period discount rate, as-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sumed the same for all consumers, be r. All
`
`
`
`
`
`
`else equal, more frequent purchase implies a
`smaller value of r. Consumers are assumed
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`to be risk neutral, to have infinite horizons,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and to behave rationally in a sense to be
`
`
`
`made precise shortly.
`
`
`
`
`
`The analysis below considers a two-stage
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`scenario. In the first stage, a pioneering brand
`
`
`
`
`
`
`enters the market and attains steady-state
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`equilibrium. I have in mind here the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`appearance of a distinctly new product, like
`stainless steel razor blades. It is assumed that
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the first brand actually works for all buyers.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`If buyers knew enough about the costs of
`
`
`
`
`
`producing working and nonworking brands,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`they
`and if they were very sophisticated,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`might attempt to infer the pioneering brand’s
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`quality from its price or simply from its ‘
`
`
`
`
`
`existence. It avoids serious game-theoretic
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`problems and does little violence to reality,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`especially in the case of new products, to
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`assume that buyers do not have enough in— .
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`formation to behave in this fashion.5 Instead,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`it is simply assumed that prior to the intro-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`duction of the first brand, all consumers ‘
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`have subjective probability 7 that it will not
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`work, and all act to maximize the discounted
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`value of expected utility. Trial of a new .
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand of unknown quality yields both an
`
`
`
`
`
`immediate utility payoff and information,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the value of which depends on future prices
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of the brand. Section II analyzes the first
`
`.
`
`5My 1978 article defends neglect of such signalling
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`considerations in this general context. This assumption
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and the assumption that information sources such as
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`word-of—mouth do not exist seem most plausible when
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`quality is subjective, so that consumers can disagree
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`about whether a brand actually works. In the interests
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of simplicity, I have not attempted to incorporate this
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sort of preference heterogeneity explicitly.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`.
`
`
`
`VOL. 72 N0. 3
`
`
`
`
`
`
`SCHMALENSEE: PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION 0F BRANDS
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`351
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand’s pricing problem under the extreme
`
`
`
`
`
`assumption that buyers have static expecta-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tions about prices. Section IV examines the
`
`
`
`
`
`implications of the polar opposite extreme
`
`
`
`
`
`assumption of perfect foresight. Neither as-
`
`
`
`
`
`sumption is especially attractive, but
`to-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`gether they should at
`least bound actual
`
`
`buyer expectations.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`In the second stage of the scenario consid-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ered here, a second, objectively identical
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand appears on the market. Innovation is
`ruled out in order to focus on the effects of
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`order of entry and on related barriers to
`imitation. The second brand is also assumed
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`to have exactly the same cost structure as the
`
`
`
`
`
`first. Two additional simplifying assump—
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tions are made. First, it is initially assumed
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`that the second brand is subjectively identi-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`cal to the first at the introductory stage, so
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`It
`that
`the same value of
`7r applies.
`is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`straightforward to relax this assumption, and
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`this is done in Section V. Second, it is as—
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sumed that the first brand does not change
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`prices in response to entry and that the sec-
`ond brand knows this in advance. This is a
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`much more passive response to new competi-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tion than is usually considered plausible.6 In
`
`
`
`
`
`an undifferentiated world,
`this behavior
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`would permit the second brand to undercut
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the first by an arbitrarily small amount, steal
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`all the first brand’s customers, and duplicate
`
`
`
`
`
`
`its profit performance. Regardless of cost
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`conditions, it would thus make it impossible
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`for the first brand to earn positive profits
`
`
`
`
`
`
`without attracting new entry. Despite this
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`assumption, it is shown below that the addi-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tion of uncertainty about quality can make a
`
`
`
`
`
`
`profitable pioneering brand immune to sub-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sequent entry. This assumption permits us to
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`avoid (at least in this essay) modeling the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`complicated dynamic game between the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and second brands that would be played
`
`
`
`
`after the latter’s entry.7
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Section III analyzes the second brand’s
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`pricing problem for the case of static expec-
`tations and demonstrates that brand’s order—
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`GSee, for instance, Avinash Dixit and the references
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`he cites.
`
`
`7Conrad’s paper illustrates the seriousness of these
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`complications. It may be necessary to make basic changes
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`in the model presented here in order to obtain a tracta—
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ble post-entry game.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of—entry disadvantage. Section IV shows that
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`our basic conclusions are equally valid in the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`polar opposite extreme case of perfect buyer
`
`
`
`
`
`
`foresight. The consequences of relaxing the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`assumptions that buyers assign the same ini-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tial probability of inadequacy to both first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and second brands, that they know for cer-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tain the value to them of a working brand,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and that purchase is necessary to get infor-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`mation about quality are explored in Sec-
`tion V.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`In my forthcoming essay, this basic setup
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`is analyzed under the assumption that buyers
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`correctly expect sellers never to change price.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`This very ad hoc pricing restriction drasti-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`cally simplifies the model and turns out not
`to alter the basic nature of its conclusions.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Since both brands actually work, each sells
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`forever to those consumers who try it when it
`is introduced and to no others. Both brands
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`then have well—defined demand curves, with
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the second brand’s curve depending on the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`first brand’s price. It is shown that the sec-
`ond brand’s demand curve has the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand’s price as its intercept. It coincides
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`with the first brand’s demand curve only for
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`prices distinctly below the first brand’s price.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`This means that with economies of scale, the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`(common) long—run average cost schedule can
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`lie everywhere above the second brand’s de-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`mand schedule even though the first brand is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`earning positive profits. The analysis below
`
`
`
`
`
`
`obtains essentially the same results without
`
`
`
`
`
`
`restricting price changes. Since the second
`brand’s demand curve turns out not to be
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`easily defined in general, however, there does
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`not seem to be a simple graphical description
`
`
`
`
`
`of the second brand’s disadvantage.
`
`
`
`
`
`II. Pricing the Pioneering Brand
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`In this section and the next, buyers have
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`static expectations;
`they expect the most re-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`cently observed price to hold forever, even if
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price has changed in the past. Suppose that
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`in order to try a new brand, a consumer
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ceases for the trial period to use a substitute
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`that yields a nonnegative surplus, s. Assum-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ing away income effects and indivisibilities,
`one can take s = 0 for the first brand.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`If a consumer would be willing to pay 0
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`for a working brand in this class, immediate
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Copyright © 2001 All Rights Reserved
`
`
`
`352
`
`
`
`THEAMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW
`
`
`
`
`
`JUNE 1982
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`trial of a new brand selling at price p is
`
`
`
`
`
`rational if and only if the following inequal-
`
`
`
`ity is satisfied:8
`
`
`
`
`(1) 7T[(—<;>v—IJ)+(S/r)l+(1—w)
`
`
`
`
`
`
`><[(v—p)(l+r)/r] >s(l+r)/r.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`The first bracketed term on the left gives
`
`
`
`
`
`
`discounted surplus if the new brand is tried,
`
`
`
`
`
`doesn’t work, and the consumer switches
`back to the substitute. The second term on
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the left capitalizes the stream of surplus asso-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ciated with buying a brand that works at
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price p forever, and the term on the right
`
`
`
`
`
`
`gives the capitalized benefit of continuing to
`
`
`
`purchase the substitute.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Inequality (1) can be rewritten simply as
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`(2)
`
`p<v(1~r)*s,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`where the important quantity 1- is defined by
`
`
`
`
`
`r=7rr(l+<j>)/(l+r*w).
`(3)
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`If 1- = 0, condition (2) indicates that the new
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand will be purchased if and only if its net
`
`
`
`
`
`
`surplus, o — p, exceeds s. Larger values of 1-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`always discourage trial of a new brand. As
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`one would expect, a- is increasing in both 7r
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and n1), as these contribute to the expected
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`cost of trial. Larger values of r, which corre-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`spond to lower purchase frequency, also in-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`crease r. The lower is purchase frequency,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the more important is any single purchase
`relative to the entire future stream of
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`purchases. This makes the risk associated
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`with trying a new brand loom larger relative
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`to the alternative of sticking forever with the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`substitute. If 7?], condition (2) shows that
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`is so subjectively risky that it never
`trial
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`occurs at positive p. To rule this out, let us
`
`assume 0 < ‘1‘ <1 in all that follows.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`If the first brand on the market charges
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price p, and all buyers with v> p are sure
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`that it works, its sales equal Q( 17). Let 11(1))
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`be the per period profit function correspond-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ing to this demand curve. When the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand initially appears on the market, nobody
`
`8One can derive condition (1) with s = 0 more rigor-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ously by letting buyer utility be the sum of utility from
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`this product class (either zero, 0, or — 9512) and income
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`left over to spend on other goods. It is then straightfor-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ward to show that
`trial of the pioneering brand is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`optimal if and only if (1) holds with s = 0.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`is sure that it works, and condition (2), with
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`s=0, implies that a price 12 will produce ‘
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sales of Q[ p /(1 - 1-)]. Let the profit function
`
`
`
`
`
`corresponding to this less-attractive intro-
`‘
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ductory—period demand curve be II°( p), and
`
`
`
`
`
`
`assume both profit functions are globally
`
`
`strictly concave.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`‘
`In period 1, let 1_3 = V(l — 1-), and in later
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`,
`periods let 13 equal the lowest price previ-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ously charged. The demand curve for the ‘
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`pioneering brand then has the general shape
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of the solid kinked curve in Figure 1. If
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`p<£, some new buyers are reached, and
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`profits equal H°( p). If ng/(l— ’7'),
`the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`only buyers are those who have purchased
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the brand at least once before, and profits
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`are given by II(p). If I: <p < 1_’/(1-— 7),
`
`
`
`
`
`
`current profits could obviously be increased,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and no new customers are being informed, so
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`that prices in this range can never be opti-
`mal.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`If the pioneering brand adopts a monopoly
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Q-constant strategy, it maximizes profit sub-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ject to the constraint that it sell to the same
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`buyers in all periods. This constraint implies
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`that it charges a first-period price p0 and a
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price p in all later periods such that p0:
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`p(l - 1'). (See Figure l.) The optimal values
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of p and p0 can then be obtained by maxi-
`
`
`
`
`mizing {H°[p(1—T)1+<1/r)mp1}- This
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sort of
`low/high pricing sequence corre-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sponds roughly to what is called “penetra-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tion pricing” in the marketing and managerial
`economics literature.9 One can show that if
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`marginal production cost is positive, a mo-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`nopoly Q-constant policy yields an output
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`level below that which would be chosen by
`
`
`
`
`
`
`an ordinary monopolist with profit function
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`H( p) because of the extra marginal cost that
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the pioneering firm must incur in order to
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`persuade buyers (by means of a low price) to
`
`
`
`
`
`
`try its ex ante risky product.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`In Appendix A, it is shown that the mo-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`nopoly Q-constant strategy just described is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the best dynamic pricing policy for the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand, as long as no thought is given to
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`possible subsequent entry. In order to high-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`light those aspects of later entrants’ prob-
`9See Joel Dean for a brief discussion and a compari-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`son with the alternative high/low strategy usually called
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`“cream-skimming” and more commonly associated with
`
`
`
`
`
`
`durable goods.
`
`
`
`
`
`VOL. 72 N0. 3
`
`
`
`
`
`
`SCHMA LENSEE: PRODUCT DIFFERENTIA TION 0F BRANDS
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`353
`
`
`
`oE/u—rfl
`FIGURE 1. SINGLE PERIOD DEMAND FOR THE PIONEERING BRAND
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`lems that arise naturally, I assume away any
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`such thoughts on the part of the first brand.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Allowing the pioneering brand to price stra-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tegically could only strengthen the results
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`obtained below at a high cost in added com-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`plexity. On the other hand, little is gained by
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`confining the first brand to the monopoly
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Q-constant strategy defined above. It is thus
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`assumed below only that the first entrant
`
`
`
`
`
`follows some Q-constant policy, charging
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price P1(l - 'r) in the first period and P1 in
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`all periods thereafter, and selling Q( P1) in all
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`periods. Under any such policy, the levelized
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`per period equivalent
`to the first brand’s
`
`
`
`
`
`average revenue stream is simply
`
`i=[11r][P1(1~7>+P1/r1
`
`_
`_ ra-
`—P‘[1
`l+r]‘
`
`<4)
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`III. Demand Conditions Facing a Later Entrant
`
`
`
`Because the first brand has followed a
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Q-constant policy,
`the second brand faces
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`two and only two distinct
`types of con-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`sumers. If the first brand’s price is P1, those
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`consumers with v < Pl have never tried the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`first brand. If the second brand then charges
`
`
`
`
`
`
`introductory price p, the condition for trial is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`again given by (2) with s = 0, as for the first
`brand:
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`(5a)
`
`v<P1 and p<v(1—r).
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Consumers with high 12’s are a second type
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of buyer, as they have already tried brand
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`one and found it to work. Because purchase
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of brand one yields a surplus of (v - P1), the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Copyright © 2001 All Rights Reserved
`
`
`
`
`
`354
`
`THEAMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW
`
`
`
`
`
`JUNE 1982
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`P,
`ngu-r)
`(PI —P§)/r
`v
`FIGURE 2. FIRST-PERIOD DEMAND PRICES FACING A LATER ENTRANT
`
`V
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`condition for trial is given by (2) with s = v
`
`_ P1210
`
`(5b)
`
`12>P1 and p<P1—'rv.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Condition (5b) shows that consumers with
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`large values of v are least likely to try brand
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`two, even though they were most likely to try
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand one. Their high valuation of brand
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`one, after they have made the investment of
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`trying it, gives them a high opportunity cost
`
`
`
`
`of trying brand two.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`The demand conditions facing brand two
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`in its first period are depicted in Figure 2.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Prior to the second brand’s appearance, the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`first brand (assumed to have completed the
`
`10One can derive condition (5b) more formally using
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the framework sketched in fn. 8, above. The difference
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`is that the alternative to trying the second brand yields
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`utility of u from this product class for certain at a price
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of P1.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`introductory phase of a Q-constant policy)
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`charges P1 and sells Q(P1). If the second
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand charges an introductory price of P20,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`its first-period customers are those with 12’s
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`between the two intersection points of the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`p = P20 line with the heavy kinked curve. As
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Figure 2 is drawn, the second brand sells
`
`
`
`
`Q[P2°/(1—T)]~Q[(P1—P2°)/T]
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`in its first period. This is less than the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand would have sold had it charged P20
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`during its introductory period. Only if P20 is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`less than (P1 —'rV) are the second brand’s
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`introductory sales equal
`to those the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand would have achieved at the same price.
`If the second brand undercuts the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand’s price sequence, P,(1—- 1-) for one
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`period and P1 thereafter, by an arbitrarily
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`small amount, it will sell only to those buyers
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`with v’s arbitrarily close to P1. Such a policy
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`would give the second brand a levelized aver—
`
`
`
`VOL. 72 N0. 3
`
`
`
`
`
`
`SCI-[MA LENSEE: PRODUCT DIFFERENTIA TION 0F BRANDS
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`355
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`age revenue equal to that of the first brand,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`E, but it would make essentially zero sales.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Under constant returns, entry will occur in
`
`
`
`
`
`
`spite of this disadvantage (though at arbi-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`trarily small scale) if P1 exceeds unit cost.11
`
`
`
`
`
`
`With fixed costs or other economies of scale,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`however, it should be clear that PI can be
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`above the first firm’s average cost (at output
`
`
`
`
`Q(P1)) without provoking entry.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`If the second brand charges any first-period
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price between Pl(1 - r) and P1 - 7V, it makes
`fewer sales than the first brand would have
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`made at the same introductory price. Since
`
`
`
`
`
`first-period sales
`translate into informed
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`buyers willing to pay more because they
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`know the brand works, this difference is the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`heart of the second brand’s disadvantage. If
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the first seller of fluoride toothpaste can
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`persuade those who care a lot about cavities
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`to try one tube, and if the taste is acceptable
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`to most consumers, the second brand of fluo-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ride toothpaste will find it much harder to
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`get a trial. It will be compared to a known,
`
`
`
`
`
`
`acceptable fluoride toothpaste, while the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand was compared only to “ordinary”
`
`toothpaste.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`If the second brand charges an introduc-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tory price less than Pl"”TV, which is dis—
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tinctly less than the first brand’s introduc-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tory price, it thereby persuades all those who
`would have tried the first brand at that same
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price to try it. (That is, as Figure 2 should
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`make clear, its first-period demand is given
`
`
`
`
`
`
`by Q[P2°/(l~r)],
`the same function that
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`held for the first brand at all prices.) It then
`
`
`
`
`
`
`has essentially the same second-period op-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tions the first brand would have had. (The
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`second brand cannot
`sell anything if it
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`charges a price above P], but
`this is not
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`likely to be a relevant alternative.) If the first
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand could have earned positive profit with
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`a Q-constant strategy beginning with a very
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`low first-period price, the second brand will
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`find entry of the same sort attractive. Even
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`with constant costs, however, it is obviously
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`possible for the first brand to be highly
`
`
`
`
`
`
`profitable but entry at drastically lower prices
`
`
`
`to be unprofitable.
`
`
`
`
`
`The preceding discussion establishes the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`existence of a barrier to entry. Profitable
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`entry deterrence can occur in this model
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`even though potential entrants have the ex-
`
`
`
`
`
`the
`ceptionally optimistic expectation that
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`first brand’s price will never change, even if
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`they steal all its customers. In order to in-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`vestigate the importance of this barrier in
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`general, it would be necessary to calculate
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the second brand’s optimal price policy and
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the consequences of following it. This turns
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`out to be very difficult. The argument in
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Appendix A establishing that the first brand’s
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`optimal policy involves only one price change
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`can be applied to the second brand also. The
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`problem is that it is not always optimal for
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the second brand to follow a Q-constant
`
`policy.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`The nature of the difficulty here can be
`
`
`
`
`
`
`understood by examining the second brand’s
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`demand curve for periods after the first, as
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`shown by the heavy kinked curve in Figure
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`3. As above, I_’ is the lowest price this brand
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`has ever previously charged, and P1 is the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`first brand’s price. Figure 3 is drawn assum-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ing I_’ > P1_ TV. The flat portion of the de-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`mand curve at price P1 corresponds to those
`consumers who have tried both brands and
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`know that both work. The segment AB re-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`flects those who have tried only the second
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand because they found the first too ex-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`pensive. A reduction in 13 increases the length
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`of the flat segment (moves point A to the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`right) as well as that of the declining seg-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ment. If the optimal introductory price is
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`above P1 —- TV, it may be optimal to follow a
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Q-constant policy and go to a point like B
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`thereafter. On the other hand, since a low
`
`
`
`
`
`
`introductory price increases the number of
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand one’s customers who engage in trial, it
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`may be optimal to set a low introductory
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`price for this purpose and then move to a
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`point like A in Figure 3.12 Finally, since a
`
`”Note that if entry occurs at small scale, the pioneer-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`ing brand loses only a few of its customers, so that the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`present value of its excess profits may still be positive.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Thus even without scale economies, entry may not drive
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the pioneering brand to a zero (discounted) profit posi-
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tion. I am indebted to Dennis Carlton for this observa—
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`tion.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`l2If the first brand has followed a monopoly Q—con-
`stant policy, P1 exceeds the static, perfect information
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`monopoly price, as Appendix A shows. Thus marginal
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`revenue just to the right of point A in Figure 3 exceeds
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the first brand’s equilibrium marginal cost. If the second
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`brand’s ma