throbber
Pricing and Reimbursement in
`U.S. Pharmaceutical Markets
`Faculty Research Working Paper Series
`
`Ernst R. Berndt
`MIT Sloan School of Management and NBER
`
`Joseph P. Newhouse
`Harvard School of Public Health, Harvard Kennedy School,
`and NBER
`
`September 2010
`RWP10-039
`
`The views expressed in the HKS Faculty Research Working Paper
`Series are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of
`the John F. Kennedy School of Government or of Harvard University.
`Faculty Research Working Papers have not undergone formal review and
`approval. Such papers are included in this series to elicit feedback and
`to encourage debate on important public policy challenges. Copyright
`belongs to the author(s). Papers may be downloaded for personal use
`only.
`
`www.hks.harvard.edu
`Exhibit 1089
`ARGENTUM
`IPR2017-01053
`
`000001
`
`

`

`NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES
`
`PRICING AND REIMBURSEMENT IN U.S. PHARMACEUTICAL MARKETS
`
`Ernst R. Berndt
`Joseph P. Newhouse
`
`Working Paper 16297
`http://www.nber.org/papers/w16297
`
`NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
`1050 Massachusetts Avenue
`Cambridge, MA 02138
`August 2010
`
`Revised version to appear in Patricia M. Danzon and Sean Nicholson, eds., The Economics of the
`Biopharmaceutical Industry. The authors have benefited from discussions with Richard G. Frank and
`E. Mick Kolassa, but are solely responsible for the views expressed herein. This research was not
`sponsored. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views
`of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
`
`© 2010 by Ernst R. Berndt and Joseph P. Newhouse. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not
`to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including
`© notice, is given to the source.
`
`000002
`
`

`

`Pricing and Reimbursement in U.S. Pharmaceutical Markets
`Ernst R. Berndt and Joseph P. Newhouse
`NBER Working Paper No. 16297
`August 2010
`JEL No. D4,I11,I18,L11,L65
`
`ABSTRACT
`
`In this survey chapter on pricing and reimbursement in U.S. pharmaceutical markets, we first provide
`background information on important federal legislation, institutional details regarding distribution
`channel logistics, definitions of alternative price measures, related historical developments, and reasons
`why price discrimination is highly prevalent among branded pharmaceuticals. We then present a theoretical
`framework for the pricing of branded pharmaceuticals, without and then in the presence of prescription
`drug insurance, noting factors affecting the relative impacts of drug insurance on prices and on utilization.
`With this as background, we summarize major long-term trends in copayments and coinsurance rates
`for retail and mail order purchases, average percentage discounts off Average Whole Price paid by
`third party payers to pharmacy benefit managers as well as average dispensing fees, and generic penetration
`rates. We conclude with a summary of the evidence regarding the impact of the 2006 implementation
`of the Medicare Part D benefits on pharmaceutical prices and utilization, and comment on very recent
`developments concerning the entry of large retailers such as Wal-Mart into domains traditionally dominated
`by large retail chains and the "commoditization" of generic drugs.
`
`Ernst R. Berndt
`MIT Sloan School of Management
`100 Main Street, E62-518
`Cambridge, MA 02142
`and NBER
`eberndt@mit.edu
`
`Joseph P. Newhouse
`Division of Health Policy Research and Education
`Harvard University
`180 Longwood Avenue
`Boston, MA 02115-5899
`and NBER
`newhouse@hcp.med.harvard.edu
`
`000003
`
`

`

`I.
`
` Introduction
`
`
`
`
`The pricing and reimbursement of prescription drugs in the United States is
`
`important for at least two reasons. First, from the perspective of US consumers,
`
`prescription drugs constitute 12 percent of total U.S. health care spending (2008) or
`
`roughly two percent of GDP.1 Thirty-seven percent of this amount was tax financed, with
`
`the associated deadweight loss to finance that spending. 2 An additional 42 percent was
`
`financed through insurance, the bulk of which flowed through employer provided and
`
`subsidized insurance. The employer subsidies for this insurance cause distortions in the
`
`labor market with associated inefficiencies.3 Thus, the financing of pharmaceuticals in
`
`the U.S. is associated with various types of deadweight losses. Second, from the
`
`perspective of all consumers, the U.S. constitutes about 40 percent of the world
`
`pharmaceutical market. As a result, its pricing and regulatory policies materially
`
`influence world demand and hence the incentives of pharmaceutical firms to innovate.4
`
`
`
`In this survey chapter on pricing and reimbursement in U.S. pharmaceutical
`
`markets, we first provide background information on important federal legislation,
`
`institutional details regarding distribution channel logistics, definitions of alternative
`
`price measures, related historical developments, and reasons why price discrimination is
`
`highly prevalent among branded pharmaceuticals. We then present a theoretical
`
`framework for pricing of branded pharmaceuticals without and then in the presence of
`
`prescription drug insurance, noting factors affecting the relative impacts of insurance on
`
`prices and on utilization. With this as background, we summarize major long-term trends
`
`in copayments and coinsurance for retail and mail order purchases, average percentage
`
`discounts off Average Wholesale Price paid by third party payers to pharmacy benefit
`
`managers as well as average dispensing fees, and generic penetration rates, We conclude
`
`with a summary of the evidence regarding the impact of the 2006 implementation of the
`
`Medicare Part D benefits on pharmaceutical prices and utilization, and comment on very
`
`recent developments concerning the entry of large retailers such as Wal-Mart into
`
`domains traditionally dominated by large retail chains and the “commoditization” of
`
`generic drugs.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`000004
`
`

`

`Berndt and Newhouse “Draft Handbook Pricing Chapter”
`
`II.
`
`Background: Legislation, Institutions and Historical Developments
`
`
`
`We begin with a brief background section that focuses on important U.S.
`
`legislative developments. This lays the groundwork for our later discussion of the
`
`marketing and pricing of generic and brand prescription drugs in the U.S. For the most
`
`part the U.S. generic drug industry approximates competitive conditions with price
`
`approaching marginal costs. As a result, we employ traditional microeconomic tools to
`
`describe the structure and pricing of that industry. We defer discussion of brand pricing
`
`in the presence of market power to later in this chapter. Next we outline the structure and
`
`distribution logistics of U.S. markets for pharmaceuticals, distinguishing roles and prices
`
`faced by providers from those of payers. Then, since any researcher focusing on the
`
`pricing of branded and generic drugs in the U.S. cannot avoid encountering the critical
`
`functions played by the misnamed Average Wholesale Price (“AWP”, aka “Ain‟t What‟s
`
`Paid”), we digress to provide background on the origins, history and evolution of the very
`
`important and sometimes misunderstood central role played by AWP in various segments
`
`of the U.S. pharmaceutical industry. We conclude this section with a discussion
`
`highlighting the demand and cost conditions facing biopharmaceutical manufacturers that
`
`make third degree price discrimination an attractive and widespread practice.
`
`A. Important Legislative Developments Affecting Drug Pricing
`
`The pricing of branded and generic drugs has long been a focus of controversy.
`
`Although Congressional attention to pharmaceutical pricing dates back further, a good
`
`place to begin is with the Congressional hearings conducted by Senator Estes Kefauver‟s
`
`Anti-Trust and Monopoly subcommittee between 1959 and 1962. These hearings dealt
`
`not only with the thalidomide tragedy in which many children were born with birth
`
`defects as a result of their mothers taking thalidomide for morning sickness during
`
`pregnancy, but also with allegations of pharmaceutical companies engaging in various
`
`questionable practices to realize excess profits. One writer describes the hearings as
`
`follows:
`
`“Witnesses told of conflicts of interest for the AMA (whose Journal, for example,
`received millions of dollars in drug advertising and was, therefore, reluctant to
`challenge claims made by drug company ads)…The drug companies themselves
`were shown to be engaged in frenzied advertising campaigns designed to sell
`trade name versions of drugs that could otherwise be prescribed under generic
`names at a fraction of the cost; this competition, in turn, had led to the marketing
`
`Page 2
`
`
`
`
`
`000005
`
`

`

`Berndt and Newhouse “Draft Handbook Pricing Chapter”
`
`of new drugs that were no improvements on drugs already on the market but,
`nevertheless, heralded as dramatic breakthroughs without proper concern for
`either effectiveness or safety.”5
`
`
`
`Kefauver‟s hearings led to enactment of the Kefauver-Harris Drug Act in 1962,
`
`also known as the Kefauver-Harris Amendments to the 1938 Food, Drug and Cosmetic
`
`Act. Among its numerous important provisions were that sponsors of New Drug
`
`Applications needed to document evidence of both safety and efficacy (not just safety),
`
`that informed consent was required of patients participating in clinical trials, that the
`
`sponsor file an Investigational New Drug application with the Food and Drug
`
`Administration before initiating human testing, that drug advertising be required to
`
`disclose accurate information about side effects, and provisions that stopped inexpensive
`
`to manufacture generic drugs from being marketed as expensive drugs under new trade
`
`names as new breakthrough medications, and that prevented the use of generic names that
`
`were obscure and difficult to remember, a practice that manufacturers allegedly employed
`
`to diminish generic substitution. It also mandated that a Drug Efficacy Study
`
`Implementation be undertaken to classify all pre-1962 drugs that already were on the
`
`market as either effective, ineffective, or needing further study.6 For our purposes here,
`
`the Kefauver-Harris Drug Act Amendments of 1962 are notable for clarifying
`
`distinctions between brand and generic drugs and regulating their marketing.
`
`Another important development of the 1960s was the 1965 passage of
`
`Congressional legislation adding Titles XVIII (Medicare) and XIX (Medicaid) as
`
`Amendments to the Social Security Act, which took effect in July 1966. At that time,
`
`however, Medicare covered only prescription drugs taken by hospital inpatients under
`
`Part A and physician administered drugs (typically injections) under Part B. Part D of
`
`Medicare which covered outpatient drugs taken orally -- small molecule drugs -- would
`
`not take effect until 40 years later in 2006.
`
`Also in the mid 1960s drug wholesalers envisaged a potential growth in demand
`
`for generic drugs, and a number of them, such as McKesson vertically integrated into
`
`manufacturing operations and began marketing their own generics. Part of the
`
`wholesalers‟ incentive to integrate into generic manufacturing and marketing arose
`
`because wholesaler margins were traditionally keyed to the price at which the
`
`
`
`Page 3
`
`000006
`
`

`

`Berndt and Newhouse “Draft Handbook Pricing Chapter”
`
`manufacturer suggested the wholesaler should sell, and to the extent generics were lower
`
`priced than brands, the prospect of manufacturers shifting their prescription drug mix
`
`toward generics implied a reduced gross profit margin for wholesalers. Contemporary
`
`industry analysts opined that the generic manufacturing and marketing window for
`
`wholesalers would, however, likely be a temporary one, as new specialized generic
`
`manufacturers entered the prescription drug market and marketed directly to the retail and
`
`hospital sectors.7 We discuss changing dynamics in drug distribution channels,
`
`particularly the impacts of information and communication technologies, later on in this
`
`chapter.
`
`A subsequent important legislative development was the Hatch-Waxman Drug
`
`Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act of 1984. It established the
`
`Abbreviated New Drug Application (“ANDA”) pathway that required only establishing
`
`bioequivalence with the reference drug (eliminating the need to establish safety and
`
`efficacy anew) and compliance with Good Manufacturing Practices.8 It specified that
`
`when a generic manufacturer submitted an ANDA and successfully established
`
`bioequivalence with the originator drug and complied with Good Manufacturing
`
`Procedures, the Food and Drug Administration (“FDA”) was authorized to approve the
`
`ANDA. For oral solid small molecules, along with ANDA approval the FDA assigns the
`
`generic an A (therapeutically equivalent) or B (drug not considered therapeutically
`
`equivalent) rating with the pioneer, thereby enabling pharmacists to substitute a generic
`
`for the brand prescription.9 It is worth noting that the FDA‟s A rating essentially grants
`
`complete interchangeabilty between brand and generic, or what economists would call
`
`almost “perfect substitutability” of the brand and generic.10 A weaker form of
`
`substitutability between different molecules occurs when, for example, payers (not
`
`necessarily the FDA) term two different molecules as being “therapeutically
`
`substitutable.”
`
`B. Pricing of Generic Drugs
`
`As noted above, the traditional microeconomic theory toolkit is mostly sufficient
`
`for analyzing generic drug pricing. For the most part one can view generic drug
`
`manufacturers as operating in competitive markets, taking the price of generic drugs as
`
`given, and facing no buyer with monopsony power.
`
`
`
`Page 4
`
`000007
`
`

`

`Berndt and Newhouse “Draft Handbook Pricing Chapter”
`
`For most small molecule pharmaceuticals (i.e., most tablets or capsules), the
`
`process of undertaking clinical trials to establish bioequivalence and meet ANDA
`
`requirements is inexpensive relative to establishing efficacy; estimates range from $2-5
`
`million.11 With entry being relatively inexpensive and the regulatory pathway open and
`
`clear, one would expect extensive generic entry following patent expiration, with price
`
`eventually falling to marginal cost. Indeed, that is what numerous researchers have
`
`found. Frank and Salkever [1997], Reiffen and Ward [2005], Atanu, Grabowski,
`
`Birnbaum, Greenberg and Bizan [2006], and Berndt, Mortimer, Bhattacharjya, Parece
`
`and Tuttle [2007] all find that price and the extent of generic entry are jointly determined.
`
`Reiffen and Ward also report that generic price continues to fall as the number of generic
`
`entrants increases up to five or so, but thereafter levels off. A common finding from the
`
`literature is that the number of generic entrants increases with the size of the branded
`
`molecule market (measured in dollars) prior to the loss of patent protection; generic entry
`
`of oral solids tends to be more extensive than that of injectables. Scott Morton [1997,
`
`1999] considers various aspects of generic entry decisions in detail, and finds that generic
`
`firms tend to specialize in the therapeutic classes in which they have previous experience.
`
`Three notable exceptions to envisaging the generic drug industry as being
`
`competitive with price approximating marginal cost are worth noting, each involving
`
`some aspect of market power. First, under the terms of the Hatch-Waxman Act, before or
`
`after submitting its ANDA, a generic manufacturer who successfully prevails in
`
`challenging the brand innovator‟s patent claims can be granted 180 days of exclusivity
`
`during which time no other ANDA holder for that molecule/strength can market its
`
`product. This is typically called a Paragraph IV entry.
`
`With no further ANDA entry permitted for a period of 180 days, the market for
`
`that particular molecule/strength becomes a duopoly, with the branded and single generic
`
`as competitors. In such a duopoly environment, the price of generics is generally only
`
`10-20% below that of the brand.12 A variant of this occurs when the branded
`
`manufacturer enters into an agreement with a generic manufacturer (other than the
`
`successful Paragraph IV entrant) to market the molecule/strength under the branded
`
`product‟s original New Drug Application (not an ANDA). This has been dubbed
`
`“authorized generic entry”, and it enables the branded company to continue pricing its
`
`
`
`Page 5
`
`000008
`
`

`

`Berndt and Newhouse “Draft Handbook Pricing Chapter”
`
`branded product high after loss of patent protection, and rather than ceding all generic
`
`sales to the single successful Paragraph IV entrant, it can share generic revenues with its
`
`collaborating “authorized generic” entrant in a triopoly environment for up to 180 days.13
`
`Following the 180 day Paragraph IV exclusivity period, generic entry tends to be
`
`substantial, with generic prices falling sharply. The presence of authorized generic entry
`
`does not appear to adversely impact the extent of subsequent generic entry post-180 day
`
`exclusivity, although it might do so in cases where the size of the potential generic
`
`market is small.14
`
`A second exception involves what is called “branded generics”. For example, a
`
`common feature observed in antidepressant markets in the 1980s following loss of patent
`
`protection was primarily branded manufacturers other than the original patent holder
`
`entering with similar strength (or with the off-patent molecule in combination with other
`
`molecules) therapeutic formulations but branded with other than the generic name. 15
`
`Branded generics attempt to differentiate themselves from both the original branded
`
`patent holder and other generic entrants, and charge prices in between the generic and the
`
`original brand. While not particularly successful in the last few decades, branded
`
`generics may be rejuvenated in the context of biosimilars, as we discuss next.
`
`A third potential exception to generic or patent expiration follow-on markets
`
`being approximated as competitive with price close to marginal cost involves biologics,
`
`as distinct from small molecules. Prior to 2010 there was no procedure for generic entry
`
`of biologics, now dubbed “biosimilars.” Section 7002 of the 2010 health care reform
`
`legislation (the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act), however, established the
`
`authority for the licensure of biosimilars, which are intended to provide price competition
`
`for the original biologic; it granted the original biologic 12 years of market exclusivity.
`
`The term biosimilar rather than generic drug is used not only because biologics
`
`are considerably larger and more complex molecules than are synthesized small
`
`molecules, and tend to be more challenging and costly to manufacture,16 but also because
`
`their larger size and complexity implies possibilities of their surfaces folding in different
`
`ways, thereby not blocking receptor sites as uniformly as synthesized small molecules.
`
`Hence, characterizing them analytically and establishing bioequivalence between the
`
`original biologic and an attempted follow-on biologic entrant raises difficult scientific
`
`
`
`Page 6
`
`000009
`
`

`

`Berndt and Newhouse “Draft Handbook Pricing Chapter”
`
`issues and challenges with important economic implications. In particular, because of
`
`greater manufacturing costs and complexity, difficulties in establishing bioequivalence
`
`and meeting other regulatory requirements, it is widely anticipated that the extent of
`
`follow-on biologic entry subsequent to loss of patent protection will be considerably less
`
`than has historically been observed with chemically synthesized small molecules.17 A
`
`consequence of this is that biosimilars are unlikely to experience the same degree of price
`
`competition following loss of patent protection as brands that A or B-rated bioequivalent
`
`small molecules have encountered in the US.18 Instead, as the 2010 health care reform
`
`legislation is implemented, one will likely see competition from something akin to
`
`“branded generics,” products that are less than perfectly substitutable with the branded
`
`biologic pioneers, but nonetheless positioned to act as possible therapeutic equivalents.
`
`Hence, price declines of biologics following loss of patent protection are likely to be
`
`notably smaller than have occurred historically with generic small molecules.
`
`C. Distribution Channel Logistics and Pricing
`
`Before initiating our discussion of the supply prices of branded drugs, we believe
`
`it useful to outline several logistical and transactional aspects of biopharmaceuticals, both
`
`generic and brand, including use of a variety of distribution channels. Observed prices of
`
`even the same biopharmaceutical will differ in various transactions simply because the
`
`drug pathway involves distinct distribution channel transactions.
`
`It is important to distinguish consumers, providers and payers. We designate
`
`providers of pharmaceutical products as those entities that actually purchase and take
`
`both title and physical possession of biopharmaceutical products, either directly or
`
`indirectly providing them to consumers. Providers include retail and mail order
`
`pharmacies, various wholesalers, hospitals, and physician offices that administer
`
`medicines (typically by intravenous, infusion or injection). In comparison, payers such
`
`as health care plans, pharmaceutical benefit managers, most group purchasing
`
`organizations and employers, typically do not take title to and physical possession of drug
`
`products, but instead reimburse providers for the purchases they or their beneficiaries
`
`have made. Despite their name payers do not actually purchase drugs, and the prices
`
`involved in the transactions in which payers engage are not the purchase prices of drugs
`
`from manufacturers or wholesalers.
`
`
`
`Page 7
`
`000010
`
`

`

`Berndt and Newhouse “Draft Handbook Pricing Chapter”
`
`Brand manufacturers of small molecules sell their drugs primarily to certain
`
`providers, particularly wholesalers and chain warehouses, and have relatively limited
`
`direct sales to hospitals, retail and mail order pharmacies, and physician offices.19 The
`
`price at which brand manufacturers sell to wholesalers and chain warehouses is generally
`
`the Wholesale Acquisition Cost (WAC), a published list price, minus a few percent
`
`discount for prompt payment and other incentives. In turn, wholesalers sell branded small
`
`molecules to retail and mail order pharmacies, usually at the present time at a few percent
`
`above their WAC, and at a 15-20% or larger discount off of what is known as the
`
`misleadingly named Average Wholesale Price (“AWP”).20
`
`Wholesalers face different markets for branded and generic drugs. They can
`
`purchase branded drugs only from a single manufacturer, whereas they can purchase
`
`most generic drugs from many manufacturers. As a result, they can create price
`
`competition among the various generic manufacturers of a particular small molecule.
`
`Large retail chains also buy directly from generic manufacturers, pitting one generic
`
`manufacturer against others to obtain the lowest generic price. As a result, gross profit
`
`margins for both wholesalers and large retail chains are larger for generic than branded
`
`small molecules.21
`
`In contrast, many biologics are administered via injection or infusion by health
`
`care providers (i.e., physicians and nurses), rather than being patient self-administered
`
`oral tablets or capsules purchased from retail or mail order pharmacies. As a result,
`
`manufacturers of branded biologics sometimes sell directly to hospitals and physician
`
`offices rather than to the wholesalers to which the branded small molecule manufacturers
`
`usually sell. Firms known as “specialty pharmaceuticals,” however, often provide
`
`wholesaler-type intermediary services between biologic manufacturers and providers.
`
`Although the practice is not as firmly ingrained as it is with branded small molecules,
`
`biologic manufacturers generally sell products to the specialty pharmaceutical firms at a
`
`slightly discounted WAC, and often at slightly higher prices to the providers who are
`
`buying directly.
`
`Over the years a variety of intermediary services for all drugs have increasingly
`
`been provided by pharmaceutical benefit managers (“PBMs”). Services provided by
`
`PBMs include benefit design and contracting with manufacturers for third party payers
`
`
`
`Page 8
`
`000011
`
`

`

`Berndt and Newhouse “Draft Handbook Pricing Chapter”
`
`(insurers, employers, governments); pharmacy network formation; real time prescription
`
`benefit eligibility certification and claims processing; formulary management and rebate
`
`negotiations with manufacturers, payers and pharmacies; drug utilization screening and
`
`review; operation of mail order pharmacies, and other functions. Although PBMs are a
`
`critical component of the third party drug benefit system, in general they do not directly
`
`purchase prescription drugs from manufacturers, take title or physical possession of the
`
`product, or provide the drug product to the patient. Rather, they are best viewed as
`
`intermediary payers. If, however, the PBM owns a mail order pharmacy, as large PBMs
`
`do, then the PBM‟s mail order pharmacy may perform provider services directly to
`
`patients.
`
`Because of the multitude of agents involved in pharmaceutical transactions, a
`
`variety of ex post reconciliations and “true ups” occur. One of these is the chargeback.
`
`It arises because, as noted above, few brand manufacturers sell directly to providers,
`
`instead distributing their products primarily via wholesalers. Suppose that a
`
`manufacturer negotiates with a third party payer (“TPP”) or group purchasing
`
`organization (“GPO”), which does not take title to the product, a discounted price that is
`
`below the price the manufacturer charged the wholesaler. Pharmacies contracting with
`
`the TPP or members of the GPO purchase from the wholesaler at the contractually agreed
`
`on TPP/GPO price. The chargeback is the difference between the manufacturer‟s price
`
`charged the wholesaler and the manufacturer‟s contract price with the TPP/GPO and
`
`makes the wholesaler whole. Typically the wholesaler submits chargeback requests to
`
`the manufacturer on a regular basis, and the manufacturer transfers the invoiced
`
`chargeback to the wholesaler via electronic data interchange.
`
`In addition to chargebacks, various forms of rebates are common in
`
`pharmaceutical transactions. Manufacturers contracting with TPPs/GPOs and PBMs
`
`often have market share or absolute number/dollar provisions that provide financial
`
`incentives for the TPPs/GPOs/PBMs to meet certain targets. e.g., a 10% of WAC rebate
`
`if brand x attains 40% of all dispensed prescriptions in a given, well-defined therapeutic
`
`class, and 15% if it attains 50%. Depending on the extent to which targets are attained or
`
`exceeded, manufacturers pay these organizations rebates. Since whether such target
`
`thresholds have been reached can typically only be determined retrospectively, these
`
`
`
`Page 9
`
`000012
`
`

`

`Berndt and Newhouse “Draft Handbook Pricing Chapter”
`
`rebates (or at least a portion of them) are paid ex post at regular intervals. PBM contracts
`
`with network pharmacies often contain similar rebate provisions, as do PBM contracts
`
`with TPPs.22
`
`To this point we have not dealt with prices paid by consumers, be they completely
`
`cash paying uninsured or the much larger number of consumers whose insurance covers
`
`drugs. Regarding the latter, TPPs have attempted to constrain rising pharmaceutical
`
`expenditures by exerting financial pressures on the patient, altering cost-sharing
`
`provisions between the insurer and the insured consumer. Initially drug insurance
`
`involved the insured‟s paying a copayment (a fixed dollar amount, usually for a month‟s
`
`supply) or a coinsurance rate (a fixed percentage of the total cost) irrespective of the
`
`specific drug bought. Drug insurance also involved the insurer‟s establishing a
`
`formulary, which was simply a list of drugs covered by the insurer. Formularies could be
`
`open or closed. Open formularies essentially cover all drugs approved by the FDA,
`
`whereas closed formularies cover only a subset of FDA approved drugs; for those drugs
`
`not covered, the insured must pay the full pharmacy price.
`
`Drug benefit cost-sharing provisions have evolved over the last two decades, with
`
`the key innovation being to charge the customer different amounts for different drugs.
`
`When drug insurance was first introduced, the consumer typically paid the same
`
`coinsurance rate for any drug, but now the price paid by the customer depends on which
`
`“tier” the drug is placed. The first tiered plans typically had two tiers, but as we come to
`
`in Section IV, now there are usually three or even four. In such an arrangement, generic
`
`drugs will typically be on the lowest or cheapest (to the consumer) tier. When a customer
`
`brings a prescription for a generic drug on the first tier to the pharmacy, the customer
`
`pays the pharmacy a relatively small amount, say $10 for a 30-day prescription. The TPP
`
`or its PBM pays the pharmacy the remaining cost of the drug and a dispensing fee.
`
`Relatively few benefit plans have many branded drugs on their first tiers, although
`
`occasionally a formulary will have an off-patent brand on the first tier.
`
`Depending on the result of negotiations among the manufacturer and the PBM or
`
`TPP, for a given therapeutic class of drugs (e.g., anti-depressants) the insurer has one or
`
`more preferred brands on the second tier. A customer presenting a prescription to a
`
`
`
`Page 10
`
`000013
`
`

`

`Berndt and Newhouse “Draft Handbook Pricing Chapter”
`
`pharmacy for a branded drug on the second tier faces a larger copayment, say $25 for a
`
`30-day prescription, with the TPP or its PBM picking up the balance.
`
`Brands for which the TPP or PBM was unable to negotiate a favorable price (from
`
`its perspective) are placed on the third tier. To incentivize customers and their
`
`physicians to substitute away from these non-preferred brands, copayments for third tier
`
`brands are considerably higher than for the second tier, say, $50 for a 30-day
`
`prescription. Finally, certain very costly drugs, such as the oncology and rheumatoid
`
`arthritis biologics that can cost thousands of dollars per month, may be placed on a fourth
`
`tier. Even if the lower three tiers have increasingly higher copayments, the fourth tier, if
`
`the plan has four tiers, almost always has a coinsurance rate, perhaps 20-30%.
`
`A relatively recent innovation involves prescriptions for maintenance drugs
`
`(drugs used to treat chronic rather than acute or episodic conditions). TPPs and PBMs
`
`now incentivize customers to obtain such drugs via mail order in 90 day prescriptions by
`
`making the copayments for 90 day prescriptions less than three times the 30 day
`
`copayment, often twice the 30 day copayment.23 Another, even more recent innovation is
`
`to reduce cost sharing amounts for specific drugs (or specific classes of drugs) to
`
`encourage compliance and potentially reduce hospital and physician costs. We discuss
`
`this development below.
`
`D. The Long-Lived, Ubiquitous but Misnamed Average Wholesale Price
`
`In almost all brand drug transactions, reference is made to a “price” called the
`
`Average Wholesale Price (“AWP”). Although the role of AWP as a reference or
`
`benchmark price from which various discounts are taken is critical for contracting in
`
`these markets, the AWP is sometimes misunderstood, in part because it is neither an
`
`average nor a wholesale price.24
`
`D.1
`
`The Creation and Evolution of Average Wholesale Price
`
`We now digress, initially to discuss the creation and evolution of the Average
`
`Wholesale Price “AWP”) as a reference or benchmark for the pricing of numerous
`
`pharmaceutical transactions. Following Congressional passage of the federal Medicaid
`
`enabling legislation in 1965, the various states were required to develop beneficiary and
`
`reimbursement practices, subject to approval from the Health Care Financing
`
`Administration (“HCFA”, now the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services,
`
`
`
`Page 11
`
`000014
`
`

`

`Berndt and Newhouse “Draft Handbook Pricing Chapter”
`
`“CMS”). At that time, numerous small wholesalers ex

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket