throbber
IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
`FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA
`
`)
`)
`)
`) Civil Action No. 12-3824
`
`CONSOLIDATED
`
`))
`
`
`)
`)
`)
`)
`)
`)
`)
`
`__________________________________________
`
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS, INC., et al.,
`
`Plaintiffs,
`
`v.
`
`WARNER CHILCOTT PUBLIC LIMITED
`COMPANY, et al.,
`
`Defendants.
`__________________________________________
`
`FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION BRIEF AS AMICUS CURIAE
`
`RICHARD A. FEINSTEIN
`Director
`Bureau of Competition
`
`
`
`PETER J. LEVITAS
`Deputy Director
`Bureau of Competition
`
`DAVID C. SHONKA
`Acting General Counsel
`Federal Trade Commission
`
`MARKUS H. MEIER
`BRADLEY S. ALBERT
`HEATHER M. JOHNSON
`KARA LEE MONAHAN
`Attorneys for Amicus Curiae
`
`Federal Trade Commission
`600 Pennsylvania Avenue N.W.
`Washington, D.C. 20580
`Telephone: (202) 326-3759
`Facsimile: (202) 326-3384
`mmeier@ftc.gov
`
`Exhibit 1073
`ARGENTUM
`IPR2017-01053
`
`000001
`
`

`

`TABLE OF CONTENTS
`
`I. 
`II.
`III.
`IV.
`
`  Interest of the Federal Trade Commission .......................................................................... 2 
`Competition in the Pharmaceutical Industry ........................................................................ 4
`Pharmaceutical Product Redesigns Can Constitute Exclusionary Conduct ...................... 10
`Conclusion ......................................................................................................................... 14
`
`ii
`
`000002
`
`

`

`Cases 
`
`TABLE OF AUTHORITIES
`
`Abbott Labs v. Teva Pharms. USA, Inc., 432 F. Supp. 2d 408 (D. Del. 2006) ............................. 13
`
`Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Corp., 472 U.S. 585 (1985) .............................................. 11
`
`Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544 (2007) ........................................................................... 2
`
`Berkey Photo, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 603 F.2d 263 (2d Cir. 1979) ............................... 11, 12
`
`Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm Inc., 501 F.3d 297 (3d Cir. 2007) ............................................... 11
`
`C.R. Bard, Inc. v. M3 Sys., Inc., 157 F.3d 1340 (Fed. Cir. 1988) ................................................. 12
`
`Caraco Pharm. Labs., Ltd. v. Novo Nordisk A/S, — U.S. —, 132 S. Ct. 1670 (2012) .................. 3
`
`eBay Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 547 U.S. 388 (2006).............................................................. 3
`
`LePage’s Inc., v. 3M, 324 F.3d 141 (3d Cir. 2003) ................................................................ 10, 11
`
`Mannington Mills, Inc. v. Congoleum Indus., Inc., 610 F.2d 1059 (3d Cir. 1979) ...................... 11
`
`SmithKline Corp. v. Eli Lilly & Co., 575 F.2d 1056 (3d Cir. 1978) ............................................. 11
`
`United States v. Dentsply Int’l, Inc., 399 F.3d 181 (3d Cir. 2005) ............................................... 11
`
`United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563 (1966) .................................................................. 10
`
`United States v. Microsoft, 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001) .................................................. 2, 11, 12
`
`Va. State Bd. of Pharmacy v. Va. Citizens Consumer Council, Inc., 425 U.S. 748 (1976) ............ 4
`
`Xerox Corp. v. Media Scis. Int'l, Inc., 511 F. Supp. 2d 372 (S.D.N.Y 2007) ............................... 12
`
`Statutes 
`
`15 U.S.C. § 46 ................................................................................................................................. 3
`
`15 U.S.C.§§ 41-58 .......................................................................................................................... 2
`
`21 U.S.C. § 355 ............................................................................................................................... 5
`
`H.R. Rep. No. 98-857, Pt. 1, p. 14-17 (1984) ................................................................................. 5
`
`The Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act of 1984, Pub. L. No. 98-417 ....... 3
`
`Other Authorities 
`
`
`
`iii
`
`000003
`
`

`

`Allison Masson & Robert L. Steiner, FTC, Generic Substitution and Prescription Drug
`Prices: Economic Effects of State Drug Product Selection Laws (September 1985) ........... 4, 10
`
`Department of Justice & Federal Trade Commission, Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing
`of Intellectual Property (1995) ................................................................................................... 3
`
`Drug Product Selection, Staff Report to the FTC, Bureau of Consumer Protection
`(Jan. 1979)............................................................................................................................4, 6, 7
`
`FDA Center for Drug Evaluation and Research, Approved Drug Products with Therapeutic
`Equivalence Evaluations (32d ed.) ............................................................................................. 5
`
`FDA, Facts About Generic Drugs ................................................................................................... 7
`
`Federal Trade Commission, The Evolving IP Marketplace: Aligning Patent Notice and
`Remedies with Competition (2011) ............................................................................................. 3
`
`Federal Trade Commission, To Promote Innovation: The Proper Balance of Competition and
`Patent Law and Policy (2003) .................................................................................................... 3
`
`Fiona M. Scott Morton, Barriers to Entry, Brand Advertising, and Generic Entry in the US
`Pharmaceutical Industry, 18 Int’l J. Indus. Org. 1085 (2000) ................................................... 6
`
`FTC, Authorized Generic Drugs: Short-Term Effects and Long-Term Impact (2011) .......... 4, 7, 8
`
`FTC, Emerging Health Care Issues: Follow-on Biologic Drug Competition (June 2009) ............ 4
`
`FTC, Pay-For-Delay: How Drug Company Pay-offs Cost Consumers Billions (2010) ............ 4, 7
`
`G. Michael Allen et al., Physician Awareness of Drugs Cost: A Systematic Review, 4 PLOS
`Med. 1486 (2007)........................................................................................................................ 6
`
`Generic Pharmaceutical Association, Generic Drug Savings in the U.S. (4th ed. 2012) ............... 7
`
`Hovenkamp et al, IP and Antitrust, 2d. Ed. (2010) § 15.3 ....................................................... 9, 12
`
`KaiserEDU.org, Prescription Drug Costs ...................................................................................... 4
`
`Marc-André Gagnon, Joel Lexchin, The Cost of Pushing Pills: A New Estimate of
`Pharmaceutical Promotion Expenditures in the United States, 5 PLoS Med 32 (Jan. 2008) .... 9
`
`Michael A. Carrier, A Real-World Analysis of Pharmaceutical Settlements: The Missing
`Dimension of Product Hopping, 62 Fla. L. Rev. 1009 (Sept. 2010) ...................................... 5, 8
`
`Overview of FTC Antitrust Actions in Pharmaceutical Services and Products (June 2012) ......... 2
`
`Report of the American Bar Association Section of Antitrust Law Special Committee to Study
`the Role of the Federal Trade Commission, 58 Antitrust L.J. 43 (1989) .................................... 3
`
`
`
`iv
`
`000004
`
`

`

`The Use of Medicines in the United States: Review of 2010, IMS Institute for Healthcare
`Informatics (April 2011) ............................................................................................................. 8
`
`U.S. Department of Justice & Federal Trade Commission, Antitrust Enforcement and
`Intellectual Property Rights: Promoting Innovation and Competition (2007) ........................... 3
`
`William H. Shrank et al., The Consequences of Requesting “Dispense as Written,” 124 Am.
`J. Med. 309 (2011) ...................................................................................................................... 7
`
`
`
`v
`
`000005
`
`

`

`
`
`Competition from lower-priced generic drugs saves American consumers billions of
`
`dollars a year. These consumer savings, however, mean lower profits for brand drug companies.
`
`It is well-established that when generic entry occurs, the brand drug company suffers a rapid and
`
`steep decline in sales and profits. The threat of generic competition thus creates a powerful
`
`incentive for brand companies to protect their revenue streams. This incentive can prompt brand
`
`companies to create innovative new products that offer medical benefits to patients. But it may
`
`also drive brand companies to seek to obstruct generic drug competition by making modest
`
`product reformulations that offer patients little or no therapeutic advantages.
`
`Such tactics, often referred to as product-switching or product-hopping, can be an
`
`effective way to game the regulatory structure that governs the approval and sale of generic
`
`drugs, thereby frustrating the efforts of federal and state policymakers to facilitate price
`
`competition in pharmaceutical markets. As discussed below, a brand company can interfere with
`
`the mechanism by which generic drugs compete by making modest non-therapeutic changes to
`
`its product, and effectively prevent generic competition, not because the reformulated product is
`
`preferred by consumers, but simply because it is different.
`
`Plaintiffs allege that Warner Chilcott engaged in a pattern of product-switching,
`
`introducing three successive product reformulations that, according to their complaints, offered
`
`little or no apparent medical benefit to consumers. Each reformulation, plaintiffs allege, was
`
`designed to, and did, impede meaningful generic competition and preserve Warner Chilcott’s
`
`monopoly profits not on the merits of the reformulations, but by manipulating the pharmaceutical
`
`regulatory system. Warner Chilcott has moved to dismiss the complaints, asserting that the
`
`introduction of a new product is essentially per se legal. While courts are properly cautious
`
`when confronting antitrust challenges to new product introductions, “[j]udicial deference to
`
`
`
`
`
`000006
`
`

`

`
`
`product innovation. . . does not mean that a monopolist’s product design decisions are per se
`
`lawful.”1
`
`A key issue raised by Warner Chilcott’s motion to dismiss is whether plaintiffs have
`
`plausibly alleged exclusionary conduct sufficient to state a claim under Section 2 of the Sherman
`
`Act.2 Assessing the plausibility of these allegations requires an understanding of the history and
`
`context of the federal and state regulations affecting generic drug competition in the
`
`pharmaceutical industry.3 The Federal Trade Commission submits this brief as amicus curiae to
`
`assist the Court in this assessment. The Commission presents background and analysis on the
`
`role of generics in creating price competition in the pharmaceutical sector and the federal and
`
`state laws that promote generic competition. In addition, the Commission addresses the
`
`appropriate antitrust framework to apply when assessing allegations that a brand drug
`
`reformulation unlawfully delayed or inhibited generic competition.
`
`I.
`
`
`
`Interest of the Federal Trade Commission
`
`The FTC is an independent agency charged by Congress with protecting the interests of
`
`consumers by enforcing competition and consumer protection laws.4 It exercises primary
`
`responsibility over federal antitrust enforcement in the pharmaceutical industry.5 The
`
`Commission has substantial experience considering and analyzing the balance between antitrust
`
`1 United States v. Microsoft, 253 F.3d 34, 65 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (en banc).
`2 For purposes of this brief, we accept the allegations in Mylan’s complaint as true, as is
`appropriate for a motion to dismiss. The FTC takes no position on the merits of Mylan’s
`allegations.
`3 See Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 567 (2007) (considering the history and context
`of the highly regulated telecommunications industry in assessing the plausibility of a complaint).
`4 15 U.S.C.§§ 41-58.
`5 For a summary of the FTC’s antitrust actions in the pharmaceutical industry, see Overview of
`FTC Antitrust Actions in Pharmaceutical Services and Products (June 2012), available at
`http://www.ftc.gov/bc/healthcare/antitrust/rxupdate.pdf.
`
`
`
`2
`
`000007
`
`

`

`
`
`and intellectual property laws6 and the impact of the Hatch-Waxman Act on competition in the
`
`pharmaceutical industry.7
`
`In addition to its role as a law enforcement agency, the FTC has a congressionally-
`
`mandated role to conduct studies of industry-wide competition issues. To fulfill this role,
`
`Congress granted the agency broad authority to compel the production of data and information
`
`not directly related to any law enforcement investigation.8 As an American Bar Association
`
`report observed, this authority gives the agency a unique capacity to conduct “systematic,
`
`institutional stud[ies] of real-world industries and activities” that “modern academic research in
`
`industrial organization rarely undertakes.”9 Courts, including the Supreme Court, have relied on
`
`FTC studies when resolving legal and policy issues.10
`
`
`6 See, e.g., Federal Trade Commission, The Evolving IP Marketplace: Aligning Patent Notice
`and Remedies with Competition (2011) (http://www.ftc.gov/os/2011/03/110307patentreport.pdf);
`U.S. Department of Justice & Federal Trade Commission, Antitrust Enforcement and Intellectual
`Property Rights: Promoting Innovation and Competition (2007)(http://www.ftc.gov/reports/
`innovation/P040101PromotingInnovationandCompetitionrpt0704.pdf); Federal Trade
`Commission, To Promote Innovation: The Proper Balance of Competition and Patent Law and
`Policy (2003) (www.ftc.gov/os/2003/10/innovationrpt.pdf); U.S. Department of Justice &
`Federal Trade Commission, Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property
`(1995) (www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/0558.htm).
`7 The Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act of 1984, Pub. L. No. 98-417
`(codified at various sections of Titles 15, 21, and 35 of the U.S. Code).
`8 The FTC has authority “[t]o require, by general or special orders, persons, partnerships, and
`corporations, engaged in or whose business affects commerce . . . to file with the Commission in
`such form as the Commission may prescribe . . . reports or answers in writing to specific
`questions, furnishing to the Commission such information as it may require as to the
`organization, business, conduct, practices, management, and relation to other corporations,
`partnerships, and individuals.” 15 U.S.C. § 46(b).
`9 Report of the American Bar Association Section of Antitrust Law Special Committee to Study
`the Role of the Federal Trade Commission, 58 Antitrust L.J. 43, 103 (1989).
`10 See, e.g., Caraco Pharm. Labs., Ltd. v. Novo Nordisk A/S, — U.S. —, 132 S. Ct. 1670, 1678
`(2012) (citing an FTC study on generic pharmaceuticals); eBay Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C.,
`547 U.S. 388, 396 (2006) (Kennedy, J. concurring) (citing an FTC study on the proper balance
`between competition and patent law); Va. State Bd. of Pharmacy v. Va. Citizens Consumer
`3
`
`
`
`000008
`
`

`

`
`
`The Commission has conducted a variety of empirical studies covering the
`
`pharmaceutical industry generally and generic substitution for brand drug prescriptions in
`
`particular.11 The FTC’s 1979 “Drug Product Selection” report examined the effect of legislative
`
`barriers to generic market entry at the state level, which imposed significant costs on consumers
`
`by unnecessarily restricting pharmaceutical price competition.12 In 1985, the FTC published a
`
`comprehensive report analyzing the impact of state legislative initiatives designed to expand
`
`generic competition and drive down overall prescription drug prices.13 These reports reflect the
`
`Commission’s long-standing interest in and study of generic drug competition and the legislative
`
`measures designed to encourage it.
`
`
`
`II.
`
`Competition in the Pharmaceutical Industry
`
`Today, generic drugs play a crucial role in containing rising prescription drug costs by
`
`offering consumers therapeutically identical alternatives to brand drugs at a significantly reduced
`
`cost. 14 This was not always the case, however. In the late 1970s, two legal barriers limited
`
`
`
`Council, Inc., 425 U.S. 748, 754 n.11, 765 n.20 (1976) (referring to an FTC study concerning
`drug price advertising restrictions).
`11 FTC, Authorized Generic Drugs: Short-Term Effects and Long-Term Impact (2011), available
`at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2011/08/2011genericdrugreport.pdf (hereinafter AG Report); FTC,
`Pay-For-Delay: How Drug Company Pay-offs Cost Consumers Billions (2010), available at
`http://www.ftc.gov/os/2010/01/100112payfordelayrpt.pdf (hereinafter Pay for Delay); FTC,
`Emerging Health Care Issues: Follow-on Biologic Drug Competition (June 2009), available at
`http://www.ftc.gov/os/2009/06/P083901biologicsreport.pdf.
`12 Drug Product Selection, Staff Report to the FTC, Bureau of Consumer Protection (Jan. 1979)
`(hereinafter Drug Product Selection).
`13 Allison Masson & Robert L. Steiner, FTC, Generic Substitution and Prescription Drug Prices:
`Economic Effects of State Drug Product Selection Laws at 8-13 (September 1985) (hereinafter
`Masson & Steiner).
`14 See e.g., KaiserEDU.org, Prescription Drug Costs, available at http://www.kaiseredu.org
`/Issue-Modules/Prescription-Drug-Costs/Background-Brief.aspx (explaining that “increases in
`prescription drug costs have outpaced other categories of health care spending” in the past two
`4
`
`
`
`000009
`
`

`

`
`
`generic competition: (1) the costly and lengthy FDA approval process and (2) state anti-
`
`substitution laws that restricted generic sales.15 Congress remedied the first issue through the
`
`Hatch-Waxman Act; state legislatures remedied the second issue through drug substitution law
`
`reform.
`
`In 1984, Congress passed the Hatch-Waxman Act, which was designed to foster the entry
`
`of low-cost generic drugs without sacrificing the incentives for pharmaceutical companies to
`
`invest in developing new drugs.16 This Act provides for accelerated approval of generic drugs by
`
`the FDA through an Abbreviated New Drug Application (ANDA), upon a showing that the
`
`generic drug is bioequivalent to its brand drug counterpart. 21 U.S.C. § 355(j). A generic drug
`
`is considered bioequivalent or “AB-rated” if it contains the same active pharmaceutical
`
`ingredient as the brand drug, is the same dosage and form, and exhibits a similar rate and extent
`
`of absorption as the brand product.17 Allowing generic manufacturers to rely on brands’ safety
`
`and efficacy studies significantly reduced generic drug development costs and expedited the
`
`FDA approval process.18
`
`
`
`decades and that prescription drug costs are “projected to exceed the growth rates for hospital
`care and other professional services in 2010 and through 2019”) (last visited Nov. 14, 2012).
`15 In the early 1980s, 150 drugs whose patent terms had expired did not face generic competition.
`Michael A. Carrier, A Real-World Analysis of Pharmaceutical Settlements: The Missing
`Dimension of Product Hopping, 62 Fla. L. Rev. 1009, 1013 (Sept. 2010).
`16 H.R. Rep. No. 98-857, Pt. 1, p. 14-17 (1984). The Act safeguards brand patent rights by
`affording a patent holder the opportunity to trigger a 30-month stay on FDA approval of a
`generic drug so that it may attempt to enforce its patents through litigation. 21 U.S.C. §
`355(j)(5)(B)(iii).
`17 FDA Center for Drug Evaluation and Research, Approved Drug Products with Therapeutic
`Equivalence Evaluations (32d ed.), http://www.fda.gov/drugs/developmentapprovalprocess
`/ucm079068.htm (last visited October 11, 2012).
`18 21 U.S.C. §§ 355 (j)(2)(A)(ii), (iii), (iv).
`
`
`
`5
`
`000010
`
`

`

`
`
`As to the second barrier, anti-substitution laws in effect in most states in the 1970s
`
`prohibited pharmacists from substituting a generic version of a brand drug at the pharmacy
`
`counter. These laws reinforced an existing feature of prescription drug markets that already
`
`significantly limited price competition: The physician – who selects the drug product but does
`
`not pay for it – has little incentive to consider price when deciding which drug to prescribe. In
`
`its Drug Product Selection Report, the FTC explained this basic problem:
`
`[T]he forces of competition do not work well in a market where the consumer
`who pays does not choose, and the physician who chooses does not pay. Patients
`have little influence in determining which products they will buy and what prices
`they must pay for prescriptions.19
`
`Given this feature, it is not surprising that studies have consistently shown that physicians
`
`are not well-informed about the price of existing products or the availability of cheaper
`
`alternatives.20
`
`In 1979, the FTC and FDA published a model state drug substitution law to allow
`
`pharmacy substitution among bioequivalent products. State legislatures responded with legal
`
`reforms to promote access to generic drugs. Today, all states facilitate competition through laws
`
`that allow a pharmacist to substitute an AB-rated generic drug when presented with a
`
`prescription for its brand equivalent, unless a physician directs or the patient requests otherwise.
`
`These state substitution laws “foster price competition by allowing the only principals who have
`
`financial incentives to make price comparisons – the pharmacist and the patient – to select drug
`
`
`19 Drug Product Selection, supra note 12, at 2-3.
`20 Fiona M. Scott Morton, Barriers to Entry, Brand Advertising, and Generic Entry in the US
`Pharmaceutical Industry, 18 Int’l J. Indus. Org. 1085, 1086-87 (2000); see also, e.g., G. Michael
`Allen et al., Physician Awareness of Drugs Cost: A Systematic Review, 4 PLOS Med. 1486, 1486
`(2007) (reviewing studies over the last ten years and concluding the doctors overestimated prices
`of inexpensive products and underestimate the prices of expensive ones).
`
`
`
`6
`
`000011
`
`

`

`
`
`products on the basis of price.”21 Together, the Hatch-Waxman Act and the state substitution
`
`laws create a regulatory framework designed to reduce costs for consumers by lowering generic
`
`costs and increasing the role of price at the retail pharmacy counter. Whatever “free-riding”
`
`occurs (Defs. Br. Mot. Dismiss 23-24) is the intended result of the legislative framework of the
`
`Hatch-Waxman Act and the state substitution laws.
`
`The Hatch-Waxman Act and state substitution law reforms have been remarkably
`
`successful in facilitating generic competition and generating large savings for patients, health
`
`care plans, and federal and state governments. The first generic competitor’s product is typically
`
`offered at a 20% to 30% discount to the brand product.22 Subsequent generic entry creates
`
`greater price competition, with discounts of 85% or more off the price of the brand name drug.23
`
`A recent study of 5.6 million prescriptions revealed that patients and their insurance plans
`
`respectively paid an average of $17.90 and $26.67 for generic drugs and an average of $49.50
`
`and $158.25 for brand drugs where no generic existed. 24 In 2011 alone, the use of generic drugs
`
`generated $192 billion in total consumer savings.25
`
`While generic alternatives save consumers billions of dollars, these savings come at the
`
`expense of additional profits to brand companies. As a result of lower prices and ease of
`
`substitution, many consumers routinely switch from the brand drug to a bioequivalent generic
`
`
`21 Drug Product Selection, supra note 12, at 7.
`22 AG Report, supra note 11, at ii-iii.
`23 Pay for Delay, supra note 11, at 8 (“in a mature generic market, generic prices are, on average,
`85% lower than the pre-entry branded drug price”); see also FDA, Facts About Generic Drugs,
`http://www.fda.gov/Drugs/ResourcesForYou/Consumers/BuyingUsingMedicineSafely/Understa
`ndingGenericDrugs/ucm167991.htm (last visited Nov. 14, 2012).
`24 William H. Shrank et al., The Consequences of Requesting “Dispense as Written,” 124 Am. J.
`Med. 309, 311 (2011).
`25 Generic Pharmaceutical Association, Generic Drug Savings in the U.S. (4th ed. 2012) at 2.
`
`
`
`7
`
`000012
`
`

`

`
`
`drug upon its introduction. Consequently, bioequivalent generic drugs typically capture over
`
`80% of a brand drug’s sales within six months of market entry.26 As just one example, the brand
`
`osteoporosis drug Fosamax, which had over $1.5 billion in annual sales prior to generic entry,
`
`lost 84% of its retail market share just 30 days after generic entry.27
`
`The threat posed to existing brand drugs by generic competition can incentivize the brand
`
`company facing dramatic loss of sales to develop new and innovative drugs that benefit
`
`consumers. This threat can also incentivize the brand company to engage in a strategy known as
`
`“product switching,” or “product hopping” to impede generic substitution and thus meaningful
`
`generic competition. Product-hopping can work in the following way: first, the brand
`
`manufacturer makes minor non-therapeutic changes to the brand product, such as a dosage or
`
`form change. Next, prior to generic entry, it removes the original product from the marketplace,
`
`or accomplishes this indirectly, such as by recalling supply of the original product or raising the
`
`price of the original product by a meaningful amount above the reformulated one.28 Such
`
`conduct can push patients and physicians to abandon the original product. In this way, a brand
`
`manufacturer can convert existing market demand for the original product to its reformulated
`
`product – not because physicians and patients prefer it, but simply because the original product is
`
`no longer as available or is more costly.29 Once the original version of the brand product is less
`
`
`26 AG Report, supra note 11, Ch. 4, n. 6; see also The Use of Medicines in the United States:
`Review of 2010, IMS Institute for Healthcare Informatics, at 3 (April 2011), available at
`http://www.imshealth.com/imshealth/Global/Content/IMS%20Institute/Documents/IHII_UseOf
`Med_report%20.pdf.
`27 AG Report, supra note 11, Ch. 4, n.7.
`28 Carrier, supra note 15, at 1025-27, 1035.
`29 While it is true that physicians are typically uninformed about drug prices and do not price
`compare between products, they may be persuaded by the claim made by brand companies: that
`the reformulated product is equal to or better than the original version at a lower price to the
`consumer. See id.
`
`
`
`8
`
`000013
`
`

`

`
`
`available or more expensive, physicians will stop writing prescriptions for it. Because the
`
`prescription must contain, among other things, the same dosage and form as the generic for a
`
`pharmacist to substitute it for the brand, a product-switch will effectively eliminate substitution
`
`at the pharmacy counter and thus meaningful generic competition. As the author of the leading
`
`antitrust treatise put it: “Product-hopping seems clearly to be an effort to game the rather
`
`intricate FDA rules. . . . The patentee is making a product change with no technological benefit
`
`solely in order to delay competition.”30
`
`As a practical matter, if a generic cannot be substituted at the pharmacy counter, the
`
`economically meaningful market for the generic product disappears. Generic substitution is
`
`based, in part, on the premise that generic products will not be promoted like brand drugs. While
`
`the generic can attempt to market a non-substitutable generic product directly to prescribing
`
`physicians, such a costly undertaking undermines the ability of generic companies to offer the
`
`lower price benefits that the federal and state regulatory framework was intended to foster. 31
`
`Moreover, such marketing, even if effective in causing physicians to prescribe the particular
`
`company’s generic product, does not guarantee the sale of that product when the patient goes to
`
`the pharmacy. The pharmacy may stock a different company’s generic and unless the physician
`
`has ordered “dispense as written” the pharmacy can fill the prescription with the alternative
`
`generic. Indeed, a company that does not bear the cost of such marketing to physicians is likely
`
`
`30 Hovenkamp et al, IP and Antitrust, 2d. Ed. (2010) § 15.3 at 15-75.
`31 Indeed, the promotional budgets for brand pharmaceutical companies are large and can be
`double the research and development budgets. See e.g., Marc-André Gagnon, Joel Lexchin, The
`Cost of Pushing Pills: A New Estimate of Pharmaceutical Promotion Expenditures in the United
`States, 5 PLoS Med 32 (Jan. 2008).
`
`
`
`9
`
`000014
`
`

`

`
`
`to offer a lower-priced generic product.32 Thus, by definition and design generic drugs are
`
`lower-cost substitutes that do not compete with the promotional efforts of brand drug firms. If
`
`the brand manufacturer reformulates its product before a generic receives FDA approval, the
`
`generic’s only practical option is to go back to the drawing board and reformulate its own
`
`product to be bioequivalent to the brand reformulation and thus substitutable at the pharmacy.
`
`
`
`III.
`
`Pharmaceutical Product Redesigns Can Constitute Exclusionary Conduct
`
`Plaintiffs allege, among other things, that Warner Chilcott maintained its monopoly in the
`
`Doryx market by suppressing competition from lower-priced generic versions of the drug in
`
`violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act. A monopolization offense has two basic elements:
`
`“(1) the possession of monopoly power in the relevant market, and (2) the willful acquisition or
`
`maintenance of that power as distinguished from growth or development as a consequence of a
`
`superior product, business acumen, or historic accident.” United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384
`
`U.S. 563, 570-71 (1966). A central issue raised by Warner Chilcott’s motion to dismiss is
`
`whether plaintiffs have adequately alleged that Warner Chilcott maintained its monopoly power
`
`through exclusionary conduct.33
`
`Generally speaking, “[a] monopolist willfully acquires or maintains monopoly power
`
`when it competes on some basis other than the merits.” LePage’s Inc., v. 3M, 324 F.3d 141, 147
`
`(3d Cir. 2003). Specifically, exclusionary conduct involves “behavior that not only (1) tends to
`
`impair the opportunities of rivals, but also (2) either does not further competition on the merits or
`
`does so in an unnecessarily restrictive way.” Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Corp., 472
`
`32 Under the drug substitution laws, a pharmacy has the incentive to stock only the lowest priced
`generic drug to increase the pharmacy’s own margins. Masson & Steiner, supra note 13, at 7,
`35-39.
`33 The FTC does not address Warner Chilcott’s additional contention that plaintiffs have failed
`adequately to allege monopoly power.
`
`
`
`10
`
`000015
`
`

`

`
`
`U.S. 585, 605 n.32 (1985). Such conduct is condemned under Section 2 of the Sherman Act
`
`when its anticompetitive effects outweigh its procompetitive benefits. See United States v.
`
`Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 58-59 (D.C. Cir 2001) (en banc). Traditional Section 2 analysis
`
`therefore involves a balancing test that is inherently fact-intensive and depends on the specific
`
`context of the conduct involved. LePage’s, 324 F.3d at 152. It also must be guided by the
`
`“economic realities” of the industry at issue. United States v. Dentsply Int’l, Inc., 399 F.3d 181,
`
`189 (3d Cir. 2005). Applying this fact-intensive analysis, the Third Circuit has found a broad
`
`range of conduct to be unlawfully exclusionary.34
`
`The basic premise of Warner Chilcott’s motion to dismiss is that product changes or
`
`redesigns can never constitute exclusionary conduct. According to Warner Chilcott, “such
`
`conduct is either competition-enhancing (if the new version represented an improvement) or at
`
`worst competition-neutral because one version was replaced by another.” (Defs.’ Br. Mot.
`
`Dismiss 21.) To be sure, product changes are often procompetitive. As the Second Circuit
`
`explained in Berkey Photo, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., “a monopolist is permitted, and indeed
`
`encouraged . . . to compete aggressively on the merits, [and] any success that it may achieve
`
`th

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket