throbber
Volume 92 | Issue 1
`
`11-2016
`
`Notre Dame Law Review
`
`Article 4
`
`Product Hopping: A New Framework
`
`Michael A. Carrier
`Rutgers Law School
`
`Steve D. Shadowen
`Hilliard & Shadowen LLP
`
`Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.law.nd.edu/ndlr
`Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, and the Intellectual Property Law
`Commons
`
`Recommended Citation
`92 Notre Dame L. Rev. 167
`
`This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Notre Dame Law Review at NDLScholarship. It has been accepted for inclusion in Notre
`Dame Law Review by an authorized editor of NDLScholarship. For more information, please contact lawdr@nd.edu.
`
`Exhibit 1068
`ARGENTUM
`IPR2017-01053
`
`000001
`
`

`

`\\jciprod01\productn\N\NDL\92-1\NDL104.txt
`
`unknown
`
`Seq: 1
`
`30-NOV-16
`
`8:35
`
`PRODUCT HOPPING: A NEW FRAMEWORK
`
`Michael A. Carrier* & Steve D. Shadowen**
`
`ABSTRACT
`
`One of the most misunderstood and anticompetitive business behaviors in today’s economy
`is “product hopping,” which occurs when a brand-name pharmaceutical company switches from
`one version of a drug to another. These switches, benign in appearance but not necessarily in
`effect, can significantly decrease consumer welfare, impairing competition from generic drugs to
`an extent that greatly exceeds any gains from the “improved” branded product.
`The antitrust analysis of product hopping is nuanced. It implicates the intersection of
`antitrust law, patent law, the Hatch-Waxman Act, and state drug product selection laws. In
`fact, the behavior is even more complex because it occurs in uniquely complicated markets charac-
`terized by doctors who choose the product but don’t pay for it, and consumers who buy the product
`but don’t choose it.
`It is thus unsurprising that courts have offered inconsistent approaches to product hopping.
`They have paid varying levels of attention to the regulatory structure, offered a simplistic analysis
`of consumer choice, adopted an underinclusive antitrust standard based on coercion, and
`focused on whether the brand firm removed the original drug from the market.
`Entering this morass, we offer a new framework that courts, government enforcers, plain-
`tiffs, and manufacturers can employ to analyze product hopping. This rigorous and balanced
`framework is the first to incorporate the economic characteristics of the pharmaceutical industry.
`For starters, it defines a “product hop” to include only those instances in which the brand manu-
`facturer (1) reformulates the product in a way that makes the generic non-substitutable and (2)
`encourages doctors to write prescriptions for the reformulated product rather than the original.
`The test also offers two safe harbors, which are more deferential than current caselaw, to ensure
`that the vast majority of reformulations will not be subject to antitrust scrutiny.
`The analysis then examines whether a brand’s product hop passes the “no-economic-sense”
`test. In other words, would the reformulation make economic sense for the brand if it did not
`have the effect of impairing generic competition? Merely introducing new products would pass
`the test. Encouraging doctors to write prescriptions for the reformulated rather than the original
`product—“cannibalizing” the brand’s own sales—might not. Imposing antitrust liability on
`behavior that does not make business sense other than through its impairment of generic competi-
`
`© 2016 Michael A. Carrier & Steve D. Shadowen. Individuals and nonprofit
`institutions may reproduce and distribute copies of this Article in any format at or below
`cost, for educational purposes, so long as each copy identifies the author, provides a
`citation to the Notre Dame Law Review, and includes this provision in the copyright notice.
`* Distinguished Professor, Rutgers Law School.
`**
`Founding partner of Hilliard & Shadowen LLP. Counsel for direct-purchaser
`plaintiffs in the TriCor, Walgreens, and Doryx cases and counsel for end-payor plaintiffs in
`the Suboxone case. We thank Kent Bernard, Scott Hemphill, Herb Hovenkamp, Mark
`Lemley, Christopher Leslie, David Sorensen, and participants in the Michigan Law School
`Intellectual Property Workshop for helpful comments.
`
`167
`
`000002
`
`

`

`\\jciprod01\productn\N\NDL\92-1\NDL104.txt
`
`unknown
`
`Seq: 2
`
`30-NOV-16
`
`8:35
`
`168
`
`notre dame law review
`
`[vol. 92:1
`
`tion offers a conservative approach and minimizes “false positives” in which courts erroneously
`find liability. Showing just how far the courts have veered from justified economic analysis, the
`test would recommend a different analysis than that used in each of the five product-hopping
`cases that have been litigated to date, and a different outcome in two of them.
`By carefully considering the regulatory environment, practicalities of prescription drug mar-
`kets, manufacturers’ desire for clear-cut rules, and consumers’ needs for a rule that promotes price
`competition without deterring valued innovations, the framework promises to improve and stand-
`ardize the antitrust analysis of product hopping.
`
`INTRODUCTION
`
`One of the most misunderstood and anticompetitive business behaviors
`in today’s economy is “product hopping.” A brand-name pharmaceutical
`company switches from one version of a drug (say, capsule) to another (say,
`tablet). The concern with this conduct is that some of these switches can
`significantly decrease consumer welfare, impairing competition from generic
`drugs to an extent that greatly exceeds any gains from the “improved”
`branded product.
`The antitrust analysis of product hopping is nuanced. It implicates the
`intersection of antitrust law, patent law, the Hatch-Waxman Act, and state
`drug product selection laws. In fact, the behavior is even more complex
`because it involves uniquely complicated markets characterized by buyers
`(insurance companies, patients) who are different from the decisionmakers
`(physicians).
`It thus should not be a surprise that courts have offered inconsistent
`approaches to product hopping. Some have emphasized the regulatory
`structure while others have ignored it. Some have offered a simplistic analy-
`sis of consumer choice, while others have adopted an underinclusive test
`based on coercion. Nearly all have focused on whether the brand firm
`removed the original drug from the market (a “hard switch”) or left it on the
`market (a “soft switch”).
`Entering this morass, we offer a new framework that courts, government
`enforcers, plaintiffs, and manufacturers can employ to analyze product hop-
`ping. The framework, which is balanced and rigorous, is the first to incorpo-
`rate the characteristics of the pharmaceutical industry. For starters, it defines
`a “product hop” to include only those instances in which the brand
`manufacturer:
`(1) reformulates the product in a way that makes the generic non-substi-
`tutable; and
`(2) encourages doctors to write prescriptions for the reformulated
`product rather than the original.
`This definition excludes many product reformulations, such as those in
`which the brand manufacturer does not “cannibalize”1 sales of the original
`
`1 “Cannibalize” is an industry term loosely defined as the brand manufacturer’s mar-
`keting against its own original product to encourage doctors to switch their prescriptions
`to the reformulated product. See Steve D. Shadowen et al., Anticompetitive Product Changes
`in the Pharmaceutical Industry, 41 RUTGERS L.J. 1, 44–45 (2009).
`
`000003
`
`

`

`\\jciprod01\productn\N\NDL\92-1\NDL104.txt
`
`unknown
`
`Seq: 3
`
`30-NOV-16
`
`8:35
`
`2016]
`
`product hopping
`
`169
`
`product. It also avoids targeting brand reformulations designed to improve
`the product by competing with other brands or growing the market, reserv-
`ing its focus for the switching of the market in order to stifle generic
`competition.
`Where the brand’s conduct does not satisfy both elements of a product
`hop, it is not subject to antitrust scrutiny. And when the conduct does meet
`both elements, our framework offers two stages of analysis. First, we propose
`two safe harbors that are more deferential than current caselaw and that
`ensure that the vast majority of reformulations will not face antitrust review.
`And second, for reformulations that are product hops and are outside
`the safe harbors, the framework examines whether the hop passes the “no-
`economic-sense” test. In other words, would the product hop make eco-
`nomic sense for the brand if the hop did not have the effect of impairing
`generic competition? Merely introducing new products would pass the test
`(indeed, would not even constitute a product hop). Encouraging doctors to
`write prescriptions for the reformulated rather than the original product—
`cannibalizing the brand’s own sales—might not. Imposing antitrust liability
`on behavior that does not make business sense—other than through its
`impairment of generic competition—offers a conservative approach and
`minimizes “false positives” in which courts erroneously find liability. In fact,
`our framework offers manufacturers three opportunities to sidestep antitrust
`liability: (1) avoid our definition of “product hop”; (2) be covered by one of
`the safe harbors; or (3) undertake conduct that makes economic sense.
`Showing just how far the courts have veered from justified economic analysis,
`the test would recommend a different analysis than that used in each of the
`five product-hopping cases that have been litigated to date, and a different
`outcome in two of them.
`By carefully considering the regulatory environment, realities of pre-
`scription drug markets, manufacturers’ desire for clear-cut rules, and con-
`sumers’ needs for a rule that promotes price competition without deterring
`valued innovations, the framework promises to improve the antitrust analysis
`of product hopping.
`Part I offers a background on product hopping. Section A categorizes
`various types of reformulations. Sections B and C address the relevant regu-
`lations: the Hatch-Waxman Act and state substitution laws. Section D then
`focuses on the crucial element of timing, explaining how generic entry
`before a brand reformulates a drug dramatically reduces price.
`Part II highlights the market failure that is unique to the pharmaceutical
`industry. Section A describes the “price disconnect” that distinguishes pre-
`scription drugs from other products and that separates the consumer’s
`price/quality determination that is unified in other markets. Section B ana-
`lyzes drug patents, emphasizing the limited role of the patent system and, in
`particular, the lack of a requirement of a medical improvement over earlier
`versions. Part C then provides several indicia of market failure based on
`medical evidence, the price of patented drugs in Mexico, U.S. prices before
`prescriptions were required, and lower prices in countries that have solved
`
`000004
`
`

`

`\\jciprod01\productn\N\NDL\92-1\NDL104.txt
`
`unknown
`
`Seq: 4
`
`30-NOV-16
`
`8:35
`
`170
`
`notre dame law review
`
`[vol. 92:1
`
`the price disconnect. Given the absence of these measures in the United
`States, Part D highlights the importance of antitrust law.
`Part III examines the five judicial analyses of product hopping. Section
`A begins with TriCor, in which the court offered a nuanced analysis, albeit
`one that some later courts limited to “hard switches,” i.e., those in which the
`brand withdraws the original product from the market. Section B covers the
`Walgreens case, which offered a simplistic analysis of consumer choice in the
`context of a “soft switch” in which the brand did not withdraw the original
`product from the market. The first two product-hopping decisions, TriCor
`and Walgreens, framed the analysis for later decisions, with some courts
`assuming that hard switches could violate the antitrust laws but soft switches
`could not.
`The Suboxone case addressed in Section C revealed aspects of both hard
`and soft switches, with the court offering a nuanced understanding of the
`regulatory regime. The Doryx case covered in Section D, in contrast, is an
`outlier that neglected the regime altogether. Section E then focuses on
`Namenda, which considered the regulatory regime in the context of hard
`switches, offering an underinclusive framework based on coercion. While
`the courts generally have considered the regulatory regime, Section F dis-
`cusses the recent work of scholars that have paid less attention to this impor-
`tant issue.
`Part IV then presents a new framework for courts to analyze the antitrust
`implications of product hopping. Section A begins with two safe harbors that
`brand firms can use if they implement the product hop (1) outside a
`“Generic Window” in which generic entry is expected or (2) after a generic
`version of the original drug has entered the market. If the product hop
`occurs during one of these windows, it will be immune from antitrust liability.
`For product hops subject to antitrust scrutiny, Section B introduces a test
`based on whether the hop would make business sense for the brand manu-
`facturer if it did not have the effect of impairing generic competition. Courts
`and commentators have advocated a no-economic-sense test in other areas,
`but the test remarkably has not been employed in a setting tailor-made for it.
`If a brand acquires or maintains monopoly power by engaging in product
`hopping that fails the no-economic-sense test, courts should find it liable for
`illegal monopolization since the behavior makes no sense other than by sti-
`fling generic competition.
`Through the application of the no-economic-sense test, we show the
`errors of courts that have treated as outcome-determinative the distinction
`between hard and soft switches. In particular, a brand might be anticompeti-
`tively undertaking actions that make no economic sense not only when it
`makes a hard switch and withdraws the original product from the market, but
`also when it makes a soft switch, leaving the original drug on the market but
`reformulating the product and “cannibalizing” it (switching sales to the new
`version), for example by denigrating, misrepresenting features of, increasing
`the price of, or pulling the marketing and promotion from, its original
`product.
`
`000005
`
`

`

`\\jciprod01\productn\N\NDL\92-1\NDL104.txt
`
`unknown
`
`Seq: 5
`
`30-NOV-16
`
`8:35
`
`2016]
`
`product hopping
`
`171
`
`Part V then applies the new framework to the five product-hopping cases
`presented in Part III. It supports the conclusions of potential liability in
`TriCor, Suboxone, and Namenda, albeit on the different ground of the no-eco-
`nomic-sense test. And it suggests a different outcome from that in the Wal-
`greens and Doryx cases on the ground, again, that the product hop lacked
`economic sense except for its impairment of generic competition. The fact
`that judicial analysis would be so different under the defendant-friendly no-
`economic-sense test shows just how far the courts have veered from justified
`economic analysis.
`
`I. PRODUCT HOPPING
`
`Product hopping, which is also known as “evergreening” or “line exten-
`sion,” refers to “a drug company’s reformulation of its product”2 and encour-
`agement of doctors to prescribe the reformulated, rather than original,
`product. Under our definition, a brand manufacturer engages in a “product
`hop” by combining two actions:
`(1) reformulating the product in a way that makes a generic version of
`the original product not substitutable; and
`(2) encouraging doctors to write prescriptions for the reformulated
`rather than the original product, i.e., switching the prescription base from
`the original to the reformulated product.
`This definition of product hopping does not include any instance in
`which the manufacturer promotes the original and reformulated products
`equally and without encouraging doctors to switch to the reformulated prod-
`uct. For example, brands often, without reducing their promotion of the
`original version, introduce modestly adjusted versions of their products to fill
`out a product line or satisfy demand for a particular formulation or delivery
`mechanism. In contrast, our definition of a product hop is limited to the
`brand’s switch of the prescription base to a reformulated product for which
`the generic is not substitutable. Limiting potential antitrust liability to
`instances in which the brand switches the prescription base is crucial: our test
`does not target rational brand efforts to expand the prescription base by com-
`peting with other branded products or growing the market. The test instead
`identifies and targets a brand’s efforts to migrate the base in order to impair
`generic competition.3
`
`2 Michael A. Carrier, A Real-World Analysis of Pharmaceutical Settlements: The Missing
`Dimension of Product Hopping, 62 FLA. L. REV. 1009, 1016 (2010).
`3 The generic-impairing product switches are particularly concerning given the “price
`disconnect” between buyers and decisionmakers discussed below. See infra Section II.A
`and text preceding Section IV.A. From a policy and regulatory perspective, the act of
`switching the prescription base raises anticompetitive concerns in threatening the generic-
`promoting goals of the Hatch-Waxman Act and state drug product substitution laws, see
`infra Sections I.B, I.C, through a switch to a reformulation for which a generic cannot be
`substituted. And that conduct lacks any innovation-based justifications because the brand
`does not build up the prescription base by competing with other brands or expanding the
`market, but merely leverages already-gained power solely by blocking generic entry.
`
`000006
`
`

`

`\\jciprod01\productn\N\NDL\92-1\NDL104.txt
`
`unknown
`
`Seq: 6
`
`30-NOV-16
`
`8:35
`
`172
`
`notre dame law review
`
`[vol. 92:1
`
`There are several types of reformulations, which Section A catalogs. Sec-
`tions B and C introduce the foundations of the regulatory regime: the Hatch-
`Waxman Act and state substitution laws. Section D then focuses on a crucial
`element of pharmaceutical competition: the timing of the brand’s reformula-
`tion in relation to generic entry.
`
`A.
`
`Forms of Product Hopping
`
`Product hopping occurs through one (or more than one) of several
`types of reformulations. One category involves new forms, which consist of
`switches from a capsule, tablet, injectable, solution, suspension, or syrup to
`another form, such as any of the above, as well as extended-release capsules
`or tablets, orally dissolving tablets, and chewable tablets.4 For example, the
`makers of antidepressant Prozac and cholesterol treatment TriCor switched
`from capsule to tablet form, while anxiety-treating Buspar was switched from
`tablet to capsule.5
`A second type of reformulation involves changing molecule parts
`(known as “moieties”) by adding or removing compounds. More technically,
`a manufacturer can switch from a mix of two enantiomers (one of a pair of
`chemical compounds that has a mirror image6) to a single enantiomer. For
`example, and foreshadowing the change discussed below from heartburn-
`treating Prilosec to Nexium, a manufacturer can “switch from a chemical
`compound that is an equal mixture of each enantiomer, only one of which
`contains the active ingredient, to a compound that includes only the enanti-
`omer that contains the active ingredient.”7 Chemical changes also explain
`the switches from allergy medication Claritin to Clarinex, antidepressant
`Celexa to Lexapro, and heartburn medication Prevacid to Kapidex.8
`A third category of reformulation involves a combination of two or more
`drug compositions that had previously been marketed separately.9 Combina-
`tions have involved migraine-treatment Treximet (combining Imitrex and
`Naproxen Sodium) and high-blood-pressure medications Azor (Norvasc and
`Benicar), Caduet (Norvasc and Lipitor), and Exforge (Norvasc and
`Diovan).10
`
`4 Shadowen et al., supra note 1, at 24.
`Id. at 37.
`5
`6 Enantiomer, MERRIAM-WEBSTER, http://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/enan-
`tiomer (last visited Oct. 22, 2016).
`7 Shadowen et al., supra note 1, at 24; see also id. at 25 (also including changes to
`molecules already on the market resulting in “new esters, new salts, or other non-covalent
`derivatives”); infra Section III.B.
`8 Shadowen et al., supra note 1, at 38.
`Id. at 25.
`9
`Id. at 38–41.
`10
`
`000007
`
`

`

`\\jciprod01\productn\N\NDL\92-1\NDL104.txt
`
`unknown
`
`Seq: 7
`
`30-NOV-16
`
`8:35
`
`2016]
`
`product hopping
`
`173
`
`B. Hatch-Waxman Act
`
`A crucial element of the regulatory framework forming the backdrop of
`product hopping is the Hatch-Waxman Act, enacted by Congress in 1984 to
`increase generic competition and foster innovation in the pharmaceutical
`industry.11
`The Act promoted generic competition by creating a new process for
`obtaining U.S. Food and Drug Administration (FDA) approval, encouraging
`generics to challenge invalid or noninfringed patents by introducing a 180-
`day period of marketing exclusivity for the first generic to do so, and resusci-
`tating a defense that allowed generics to experiment on a brand drug during
`the patent term.12 The drafters of the Act sought to ensure the provision of
`“low-cost, generic drugs for millions of Americans”13 and recognized that
`generic competition would save consumers, as well as the federal govern-
`ment, millions of dollars each year.14
`One central goal of the Act was to expedite generic competition.15
`Generic drugs are very similar to patented brand drugs, having the same
`active
`ingredients, dosage, administration, performance, and safety.16
`Despite this equivalence, however, generic manufacturers were required,
`before the Act, to demonstrate safety and effectiveness by engaging in
`lengthy and expensive trials. They could not begin the process during the
`patent term since the FDA approval process took several years17 and the
`required tests constituted infringement.18 Generics thus waited until the end
`of the term to begin these activities. As a result, they were not able to enter
`the market until two or three years after the patent’s expiration. At the time
`of the Hatch-Waxman Act, there were roughly 150 drugs for which the patent
`term had lapsed but there was no generic on the market.19
`In the Act, Congress encouraged competition through several mecha-
`nisms. First, it allowed generics to experiment on the drug during the patent
`
`11 Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act of 1984, Pub. L. No. 98-
`417, 98 Stat. 1585 (codified as amended in scattered sections of 15, 21, 28, 35 U.S.C.).
`12 Michael A. Carrier, Unsettling Drug Patent Settlements: A Framework for Presumptive Ille-
`gality, 108 MICH. L. REV. 37, 42–43 (2009).
`13 130 CONG. REC. 24,410, 24,427 (1984) (statement of Rep. Waxman).
`Id. at 24,456 (statement of Rep. Minish).
`14
`15 For an overview of the mechanisms employed to carry out the other primary goal,
`fostering innovation, see Carrier, supra note 12, at 43–45 (discussing patent term exten-
`sions, non-patent market exclusivity, and an automatic 30-month stay of FDA approval of
`generics).
`16 Generic Drugs: Questions and Answers, FOOD & DRUG ADMIN., http://www.fda.gov/
`Drugs/ResourcesForYou/Consumers/QuestionsAnswers/ucm100100.htm (last updated
`Jan. 7, 2015).
`17 CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, HOW INCREASED COMPETITION FROM GENERIC DRUGS HAS
`AFFECTED PRICES AND RETURNS IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 38 (1998).
`Id. at 3.
`18
`See H.R. REP. NO. 98-857, pt. 1, at 17 (1984), as reprinted in 1984 U.S.C.C.A.N. 2647,
`19
`2650.
`
`000008
`
`

`

`\\jciprod01\productn\N\NDL\92-1\NDL104.txt
`
`unknown
`
`Seq: 8
`
`30-NOV-16
`
`8:35
`
`174
`
`notre dame law review
`
`[vol. 92:1
`
`term.20 Along these lines, the legislature exempted from infringement the
`manufacturing, use, or sale of a patented invention for uses “reasonably
`related to the development and submission of information” under a federal
`law regulating drugs’ manufacture, use, or sale.21
`Second, the Act provided 180 days of marketing exclusivity to the first
`generic to challenge a brand’s patent or claim that it did not infringe the
`patent.22 This exclusivity “was reserved for the first generic firm—known as a
`‘Paragraph IV filer’—that sought to enter during the patent term.”23 During
`the 180-day period, which begins after the drug’s first commercial marketing,
`the FDA is not able to approve other generic applications for the same
`product.24
`Third, and most relevant for our purposes, Congress created a new pro-
`cess for generics to obtain FDA approval. Before the Act, generic firms that
`offered identical products to approved drugs were required to prove safety
`and efficacy.25 In fact, one reason that generics decided not to bring drugs
`to the market after the expiration of a patent was the time and expense
`involved in replicating clinical studies.26 The Act created a new type of drug
`application, called an Abbreviated New Drug Application (ANDA), through
`which generics could rely on brands’ safety and effectiveness studies, thereby
`avoiding the need to engage in lengthy and expensive preclinical or clinical
`studies.27
`In short, faced with the problem of insufficient generic entry and high
`drug prices, Congress enacted legislation that introduced several industry-
`shaping mechanisms to encourage generic entry.
`
`20 35 U.S.C. § 271(e)(1) (2012).
`Id. For an elaboration on this discussion, see Carrier, supra note 2, at 1013, from
`21
`which this passage draws.
`22 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv) (2012). Three other patent certifications apply if the
`drug is not patented, the patent has expired, or the generic agrees it will not seek approval
`until the patent expires. 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(2)(A)(vii).
`23 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv).
`24 Carrier, supra note 2, at 1014; see also FED. TRADE COMM’N, GENERIC DRUG ENTRY
`PRIOR TO PATENT EXPIRATION: AN FTC STUDY 7 (2002) [hereinafter FTC, GENERIC DRUG
`STUDY], https://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/reports/generic-drug-entry-
`prior-patent-expiration-ftc-study/genericdrugstudy_0.pdf. Until amended in 2003, the
`Hatch-Waxman Act included as a second trigger for the 180-day period a court decision
`finding invalidity or lack of infringement. Colleen Kelly, Note, The Balance Between Innova-
`tion and Competition: The Hatch-Waxman Act, the 2003 Amendments, and Beyond, 66 FOOD &
`DRUG L.J. 417, 439–40 (2011).
`25 Elizabeth Stotland Weiswasser & Scott D. Danzis, The Hatch-Waxman Act: History,
`Structure, and Legacy, 71 ANTITRUST L.J. 585, 588 (2003).
`See id.
`26
`27 FTC, GENERIC DRUG STUDY, supra note 24, at 5. For an elaboration on this discus-
`sion, see Carrier, supra note 2, at 1013, from which this passage draws.
`
`000009
`
`

`

`\\jciprod01\productn\N\NDL\92-1\NDL104.txt
`
`unknown
`
`Seq: 9
`
`30-NOV-16
`
`8:35
`
`2016]
`
`product hopping
`
`175
`
`C.
`
`State Drug Product Selection Laws
`
`States have also made it easier for generics to reach the market through
`their enactment of drug product selection (DPS) laws. Such laws, in effect in
`all fifty states today, are designed to lower consumer prices.28 The laws allow
`(and in some cases require) pharmacists—absent a doctor’s contrary instruc-
`tions—to fill prescriptions for brand-name drugs with generic versions.29
`States enacted DPS laws to address the price disconnect in the industry,
`described in detail below,30 between doctors, who prescribe a drug but are
`not directly responsive to drug pricing, and insurers and consumers, who pay
`but do not directly select a prescribed drug.31 In particular, the laws ensure
`an important role for pharmacists, who are more price-sensitive than doc-
`tors.32 Doctors are subject to “a vast array of drug promotion, which includes
`detailing (sales calls to doctor’s offices), direct mailings, free drug samples,
`medical journal advertising, sponsored continuing medical education pro-
`grams, and media advertising.”33 Pharmacists, in contrast, make greater mar-
`gins on generics and recommend them to consumers,34 competing with
`other pharmacies on price.35
`The DPS laws “typically allow pharmacists to substitute generic versions
`of brand drugs only if they are ‘AB-rated’ by the FDA.”36 This is solely a
`safety regulation, unconcerned with and unresponsive to the requirement’s
`effect on competition. For a generic drug to receive an AB rating, it must be
`“therapeutically equivalent” to the brand drug, which means that it “has the
`same active ingredient, form, dosage, strength, and safety and efficacy pro-
`file.”37 The drug also must be “bioequivalent,” which means “the rate and
`extent of absorption in the body is roughly equivalent to the brand drug.”38
`
`See, e.g., Norman V. Carroll et al., The Effects of Differences in State Drug Product Selection
`28
`Laws on Pharmacists’ Substitution Behavior, 25 MED. CARE 1069 (1987).
`29 Carrier, supra note 2, at 1017.
`See infra Section II.A.
`30
`31 BUREAU OF CONSUMER PROT., DRUG PRODUCT SELECTION: STAFF REPORT TO THE FED-
`ERAL TRADE COMMISSION 2–3 (1979); see also In re Schering-Plough Corp., 136 F.T.C. 956,
`985 (2003) (“The underlying premise of these [DPS] laws . . . is that generic competition
`has the potential to lower prices,” and “these regulations need to be accepted as real mar-
`ket factors in an antitrust analysis.”).
`32 ALISON MASSON & ROBERT L. STEINER, GENERIC SUBSTITUTION AND PRESCRIPTION
`DRUG PRICES: ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF STATE DRUG PRODUCT SELECTION LAWS 7 (1985).
`33 STUART O. SCHWEITZER, PHARMACEUTICAL ECONOMICS AND POLICY 87–93 (2d ed.
`2007). For an elaboration on this discussion, see Carrier, supra note 2, at 1017, from which
`this passage draws.
`34 Shadowen et al., supra note 1, at 16.
`35 MASSON & STEINER, supra note 32, at 7; see generally Carrier, supra note 2, at 1017–18.
`36 Carrier, supra note 2, at 1018.
`37 Orange Book Preface: Approved Drug Products with Therapeutic Equivalence Evaluations,
`CTR. FOR DRUG EVALUATION & RESEARCH, FOOD & DRUG ADMIN., http://www.fda.gov/
`drugs/developmentapprovalprocess/ucm079068.htm (36th ed. last updated June 10,
`2016).
`See id. For an elaboration on this discussion, see Carrier, supra note 2, at 1018, from
`38
`which this passage draws.
`
`000010
`
`

`

`\\jciprod01\productn\N\NDL\92-1\NDL104.txt
`
`unknown
`
`Seq: 10
`
`30-NOV-16
`
`8:35
`
`176
`
`notre dame law review
`
`[vol. 92:1
`
`Product-hopping schemes exploit this regulation. By making minor
`changes to the original product—for example, switching from a capsule to a
`tablet, or from a 10-mg to a 12-mg dose—the brand can prevent the generic
`from obtaining the AB rating the generic needs to be substituted for the
`brand. After the brand’s reformulation, the generic cannot be substituted
`for the new version. To become substitutable it must start the FDA approval
`process all over again. And while the generic may eventually obtain an AB
`rating to the reformulated product, such a showing likely will not occur for
`years as the generic reformulates its product, seeks FDA approval, and typi-
`cally files a Paragraph-IV certification, which tends to be “followed by the
`brand firm’s automatic ‘thirty month stay’ of FDA approval and additional
`delays from patent litigation.”39 All of these delays prevent the effective
`operation of the DPS laws, removing the role of pharmacists and depriving
`consumers of the practical opportunity to consider a lower-priced generic
`version of the drug.
`
`D. Timing of Generic Entry
`
`A seminal event in the lifecycle of a prescription drug is generic entry.
`When multiple generics enter the market, the price falls to a fraction of the
`brand price.40 Brand firms thus have every incentive to delay the entry of
`generic competition as long as possible. The dramatic effects of generic
`entry explain the crucial role played by the Hatch-Waxman Act and state DPS
`laws. And they shed light on the essential characteristic, in the product-hop-
`ping context, of the timing of generic entry.
`Put simply, the brand firm will be much more successful in forestalling
`generic competition if it can switch the market to the reformulated drug
`before a generic of the original product enters the market.41 Without a
`generic on the market, the brand’s heavy promotion and marketing artillery
`can convince doctors to prescribe the reformulated drug. If the brand suc-
`cessfully switches the market to the reformulated product before the generic
`enters, the generic entry is of no practical significance: there are few or no
`prescriptions for the original product for which the generic can be
`substituted.42
`Several examples demonstrate the crucial role of timing, in particular
`the brand’s recognition of its dramatically higher success if it can switch the
`
`39 Carrier, supra note 2, at 1018.
`40 Generic Competition and Drug Prices, FOOD & DRUG ADMIN., http://www.fda.gov/
`AboutFDA/CentersOffices/OfficeofMedicalProductsandTobacco/CDER/ucm129385.htm
`(last updated May 13, 2015); see generally Fiona Scott Morton & Margaret Kyle, Markets for
`Pharmaceutical Products, in 2 HANDBOOK OF HEALTH ECONOMICS 763, 792–93 (Mark V. Pauly
`et al. eds., 2012) (summarizing recent studies on generic penetration rates and price

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket