throbber
BRAND LOYALTY, ENTRY, AND PRICE
`COMPETITION IN PHARMACEUTICALS
`
`AFTER THE 1984 DRUG ACT*
`
`HENRY G. GRABOWSKI and JOHN M. VERNON
`Duke University
`
`IN 1984, Congress enacted a new law that greatly affected the economics
`of the pharmaceutical industry in the United States. It has been character-
`ized as the most important legislation affecting competition in the phar-
`maceutical industry since the 1962 Kefauver-Harris Amendments to the
`Food and Drug Act. This 1984 law, known as the Drug Price Competition
`and Patent Term Restoration Act (hereinafter the 1984 Act), facilitated
`the entry of generic drug products after patent expiration while it also
`restored part of the patent life lost during the premarket regulatory pro-
`cess for new introductions.‘
`
`Market entry by generics was relatively limited prior to 1984 because
`of costly Food and Drug Administration (FDA) requirements that had to
`be met by the imitative products. That is, generic drugs often would have
`to duplicate many of the pioneer’s tests to gain market approval after
`patent expiration. As a result of the 1984 law, generic products need only
`demonstrate bioequivalence to the pioneer’s brand, and generic entry has
`increased significantly. This has provided a body of very interesting data
`to analyze the pattern of entry and the pricing strategies followed by the
`entrants and incumbents.
`
`In this article, we make use of data covering the sales and prices of
`the pioneer and generic products for eighteen drug products, generally
`over the time period 1984—88. A number of issues are examined. First,
`
`" Earlier versions of this article were presented at the Second World Congress on Health
`Economics. the Applied Econometric Association Meetings. the American Economic Asso-
`ciation Meetings. and Workshops at Duke University and University of California. Los
`Angeles. We benefited from the comments from several participants at these meetings as
`well as those from an anonymous referee.
`' For an early analysis of this law, see Henry Grabowski & John Vernon. Longer Patents
`for Lower Imitation Barriers: The 1984 Drug Act, 76 Am. Econ. Rev. Papers & Proc. I95
`( 1986).
`
`[Journal of Law & Economics, vol. XXXV (October l992)]
`© [992 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0022—2186/92/3502-000650l50
`
`331
`
`000001
`
`Exhibit 1066
`
`ARGENTUM
`
`Exhibit 1066
`ARGENTUM
`IPR2017-01053
`
`IPR2017-01053
`
`000001
`
`

`

`332
`
`THE JOURNAL or LAW AND ECONOMICS ‘
`
`We characterize the typical pattern of generic prices over the early years
`postentry, the pricing responses by pioneers, and the resulting market
`shares of the two parties. The current strong interest in theoretical model—
`ing of entry-deterring strategies makes this empirical evidence particu-
`larly timely.
`Another issue that we examine through regression analysis is the rela-
`tionship between generic entry in a drug category and the perceived
`profitability of that category. In addition, we consider the structure of
`prices and market shares among generic firms in the initial period after
`entry to see whether the lowest-price firms capture the largest shares.
`The article is organized as follows. Section I provides some back-
`ground on the pharmaceutical industry. It also reports on the data that
`we gathered and describes and interprets the stylized facts of pricing
`patterns and market-share results. Section II examines the pioneer's pric-
`ing response to entry in greater detail. Section III is concerned with the
`determinants of generic entry and the general structure of generic prices
`and market shares. Section IV provides a brief summary and concluding
`comments .
`
`I.
`
`PRICE COMPETITION THROUGH GENERIC ENTRY
`
`A. Background
`
`Pharmaceuticals have often been cited in the literature as a particularly
`extreme example of first-mover pricing advantages. Theoretical models
`by Richard Schmalensee2 and Cecilia Conrad3 explain this phenomenon.
`and F. M. Scherer and David Ross4 have provided a recent survey of the
`empirical literature for the pharmaceutical industry. They conclude that,
`“under conditions like those found in pharmaceuticals, first movers have
`natural product differentiation advantages that permit them to charge high
`prices and retain substantial market shares.”5
`Historically, the strong brand loyalty in pharmaceuticals for innovative
`brands over generic competitors has been rooted in several institutional
`considerations. First, physicians generally gained experience with a new
`drug during its period of patent exclusivity. When patents expired and
`
`2 Richard Schmalensee. Product Differentiation Advantages of Pioneering Brands. 72
`Am. Econ. Rev. 349 (I982).
`’ Cecilia A. Conrad. The Advantages of Being First and Competition between Finns. I
`Int‘l. J. Indus. Org. 353 (I983).
`‘ F. M. Scherer & David Ross. Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance
`(3d ed. B90).
`5 Id. at 592.
`
`000002
`
`000002
`
`

`

`BRAND LOYALTY, ENTRY, AND COMPETITION
`
`333
`
`cheaper substitutes became available, many physicians were insensitive
`to the lower-price opportunities and continued to prescribe the brand
`name product. Furthermore, state antisubstitution laws instituted in the
`19505 and 19605 prohibited pharmacists from substituting the cheaper
`generic brands.‘5
`In addition, there were supply-side constraints on generic entry. Under
`the 1962 Kefauver-Harris Amendments, generic products could not rely
`on the safety and efficacy evidence submitted by pioneers for post-1962
`drug introductions. Unless the relevant data were publicly available in
`the scientific literature, a generic competitor had to duplicate many of
`the pioneer's tests to gain approval. Our earlier article found this had a
`major inhibiting effect on the speed and degree of entry by generic prod-
`ucts.7 An exception was in the antibiotics category, where entry did not
`require duplicative safety and efficacy testing. In contrast to other thera-
`peutic categories, antibiotics has been characterized by rapid entry, sig-
`nificant generic prescriptions, and. strong price competition.“
`An analysis by Meir Statman illustrates the historical brand-loyalty
`advantages possessed by pioneering brand vis-a-vis their generic en-
`trants.9 Statman examined twelve (nonantibiotic) drug compounds whose
`patents expired during the I970s. He found only marginal market-share
`gains by generic entrants, even several years after patent expiration. For
`example, the average pioneer's market share (in revenues) two years
`after patent expiration was 99 percent. (We should note that,
`in eight
`cases, the market share was 100 percent, indicating that no entry took
`place.) Similar results also emerged from other analyses. with only major
`antibiotic products systematically deviating from this observed pattern.
`Since the mid-1970s. however, there have been a number of institu-
`
`tional changes in pharmaceuticals that should increase the degree of price
`sensitivity. First, the state antisubstitution laws have been universally
`repealed. The new substitution laws allow pharmacists to dispense lower-
`priced generics in the place of prescribed brands (subject to physician
`override provisions that vary from state to state). In addition, third-party
`payers such as Medicaid have instituted requirements limiting reimburse—
`ments to generic levels. These programs have been imitated by many
`private insurers. The growth of managed health programs and health
`
`‘ See Henry Grabowski & John Vernon, Substitution Laws and Innovation in the Phar-
`maceutical Industry, 43 L. & Contemp. Probs. 43 (1979).
`7 Grabowski & Vernon, supra note 1, at 195.
`' David Schwartzman, Innovation in the Pharmaceutical Industry (1976).
`’ Meir Statman, The Effect of Patent Expiration on the Market Position of Drugs. in
`Dmgs and Health: Economic Issues and Policy Objectives (Robert B. Helms ed. 1981).
`
`000003
`
`000003
`
`

`

`334
`
`THE JOURNAL or LAW AND ECONOMICS
`
`maintenance organizations (HMOs) have also encouraged generic utili-
`zation.
`
`Alison Masson and Robert Steiner have performed an analysis of the
`initial period after the new state substitution laws.I0 They found that these
`new laws have indeed increased the market’s price sensitivity and the
`amount of generic usage. Nevertheless, they still observe a surprising
`degree of brand loyalty for pioneering brands. In their 1980 sample of
`forty-five drugs, they found that generics accounted for only 23.3 percent
`of prescriptions. Two recent related studies also _find that brand-name
`products retain large market shares relative to lower-priced genen'c en-
`trants.” Both provide an analysis of some of the factors underlying'this
`phenomenon.
`None of the existing literature, however, has focused on the post-1984
`period.'2 As noted above, the passage of the 1984 Drug Price Competition
`Act was a key event in facilitating the entry of generic-drug manufactur-
`ers into the marketplace. As a result of the 1984 Act, generic firms now
`enter the market much more rapidly after patent expiration and enter in
`abundant numbers. The entry situation for all pharmaceuticals now
`closely resembles what formerly held only for antibiotics. Hence, an anal-
`ysis of competition between pioneer and generic products in the post-1984
`period appears warranted.
`
`B. Data Samples
`
`In order to examine the effect of this entry on market prices and shares.
`we have assembled data for a sample of eighteen major products first
`
`to Alison Masson & Robert L. Steiner. Generic Substitution and Prescription Drug Prices:
`Economic Effects of State Drug Product Selection Laws (Stafi' report. Federal Trade Com-
`mission. Bureau of Economics [985).
`“ Mark A. Hurwitz & Richard E. Caves. Persuasion or Information? Promotion and the
`Shares of Brand Name and Generic Pharmaceuticals. 31 J. Law & Econ. 299 ([988); and
`Richard E. Caves. Michael D. Whinston. & Mark A. Hurwitz. Patent Expiration. Entry.
`and Competition in the US Pharmaceutical Industry: An Exploratory Analysis. Brookings
`Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics (1991).
`'2 The study by Caves, Whinston & Hurwitz. supra note ll. examined a sample of thirty
`drugs with patent expiration between [976 and 1987. There is a significant overlap with our
`sample. but several of the drugs in their sample experienced initial competition prior to the
`passage of the Drug Price Competition and Patent Restoration Act in September 1984. They
`also employ pooled samples throughout their analysis. thereby generally averaging the
`experiences of the 19705 and early l9805 chronicled by prior researchers (Statman, supra
`note 9; Masson & Steiner. supra note I0). Their very different findings on the post-I984
`period are reported below. There is no real attempt to isolate the effect of the I984 Act
`beyond a general trend variable that is utilized to capture various structural changes during
`the 19805. This variable is insignificant for the drug-store market where the lion's share of
`the sales for the drugs in our sample are made.
`
`000004
`
`000004
`
`

`

`BRAND LOYALTY, ENTRY, AND COMPETITION
`
`335
`
`exposed to generic competition over the period 1983-87. The criterion
`that we used to include a product on this list was fifty million dollars or
`more in sales at the time of patent expiration. Pharmaceutical sales are
`highly skewed in sales value.” Given this, generic competition will be
`directed especially toward the products that have achieved the largest
`markets.
`There were eighteen products that satisified the threshold criterion of
`fifty million dollars in sales at the time of patent eXpiration.” For each
`of the eighteen products, we identified the most popular dosage sizes from
`the data audits of IMS America Inc.” These data sources also provide an
`estimate of total sales of each dosage size by manufacturers and whole-
`salers to drugstore and hospital outlets. Sales are expressed in both dol-
`lars and physical units. Using this information, we computed prices at
`various time intervals for the pioneer products, the generic entrants, and
`the overall market. All of these prices represent the average cost per unit
`paid by drugstores and hospitals for the most frequently consumed dos-
`age size of each product. We also computed market shares for the pioneer
`and generic products in units at the same points in time after entry.
`
`C. Descriptive Statistics
`
`The general pattern is that generic products enter at a significant dis-
`count to the pioneering product with which they compete. Moreover, in
`generic prices, there is a strong downward price dynamic over time. By
`contrast. the prices of the pioneering brands remain higher than their
`generic competitors and actually increase in nominal terms in the time
`period after entry. Average market price,“ however, decreases over time
`as the lower-priced generic products achieve significant gains in market
`share.
`
`Table l provides a summary of our findings for the eighteen drugs. The
`first row indicates that the average market price declined by a little more
`than 10 percent per year in the first two years after generic entry. The
`second row shows that the average pioneer price index rose 7 percent in
`the first year after entry and an additional 4 percent in the second year
`
`'3 Henry Grabowski & John Vernon, A New Look at the Returns and Risks to Pharma-
`ceutical R&D. 36 Mgmt. Sci. 804 (1990).
`" For a list of the products and the date of generic entry, see Table Al in. the Appendix.
`As also shown in Table 1. drugs with patent expiration afier 1984 had entry within the same
`year as or the year immediately after the patent expiration.
`" lMS America Inc.. U.S. Drug Store and Hospital Sales (1983—87) (hereinaner IMS).
`" Average market price refers to total dollars for pioneers and generics divided by total
`units.
`
`000005
`
`000005
`
`

`

`336
`
`THE JOURNAL or LAW AND ECONOMICS
`
`TABLE 1
`
`SUMMARY or GENERIC DRUG FINDINGS
`
`
`Two Years
`One Year
`At Date
`
`of Entry after Entry after Entry
`
`
`Average market price index
`
`Average pioneer price index
`
`Average generic price index
`
`1.0
`
`1.0
`
`1.0
`
`.89
`(.10)
`1.07
`(.07)
`.78
`(.15)
`
`.79
`(.12)
`1.11
`(.10)
`.65
`(.16)
`
`Average ratio of generic price to pioneer
`price
`
`Average generic market share in units
`
`.37
`.46
`.61
`(.13)
`(.14)
`(.11)
`.49
`.35
`.09
`(.11)
`(.12)
`(.09)
`‘ 25.1
`17.2
`N.A.
`Average number of generic suppliers
`
`(3.8) (6.8)
`
`Nora—Each value is an unweighted average of the values for the eighteen drug categories. The price
`indexes take the date-of-entry price as unity. Hence, for example, the average category price two years
`postentry is 79 percent of its value at the date of entry. The market price equals total dollars of sales
`for the leader and generics divided by total units. No attempt has been made to deflate prices for inflation.
`Average generic market share in units at date of entry is the share during the first month of generic
`marketing. Population standard deviations are given in parentheses; N. A. = not applicable.
`
`after entry. At the same time, generic prices fell to 78 percent of their
`initial value at the end of the first year and 65 percent at the end of the
`second year. This steep price decline together with the growing market
`share obtained by the generics is what causes overall market prices to
`decline.
`
`The different behavioral responses of pioneering and generic firms
`causes the gulf in prices between them to increase significantly over time.
`As shown in Table l, generic prices averaged 61 percent of the leader
`price during the first month after entry, and this declined to 46 percent
`one year after entry and then to 37 percent two years after entry.
`The last row in Table 1 shows the movement over time in average
`market share (in units) achieved by the generics. This increases from 9
`percent in the first month after entry to 35 percent one year after entry
`and to 49 percent two years after entry. Furthermore, two years after
`entry, these products average seventeen and twenty-five separate generic
`suppliers, respectively.'7 This is a dramatically higher rate of generic
`
`'7 This refers to the average number of firms supplying products at the wholesale level
`as reflected in the data audits of [MS (r'd.). It should be noted that the average number of
`Abbreviated New Drug Applications (ANDAs) approved by the FDA for these products is
`less than the number of firms marketing the product, so that some firms rely on the ANDAs
`of other firms. This issue is considered further below.
`
`000006
`
`000006
`
`

`

`BRAND LOYALTY, ENTRY, AND COMPETITION
`
`337
`
`penetration than observed by Statman in his study of the 19705.“ As
`noted above, Statman found only marginal gains by the generic entrants
`even several years after patent expiration.
`The results reported in Table 1
`indicate that average market prices
`decline as a result of the significant increase in usage of lower-priced
`generics. In this regard, we computed a descriptive regression of the
`market price index on generic market share, each measured two years
`after generic entry. Letting LMP represent the log of the market price
`index and LGS represent the log of generic market share, the equation
`15
`
`LMP= —.70
`(—11.10)
`
`-—
`
`.6ILGS,
`(—7.54)
`
`where the adjusted R2 = .78, n = l7, and the I-statistics are in paren-
`theses.
`
`The statistical results are strong. There is a negative relationship that
`states that the higher generic penetration is, the lower the market price
`will be. Each 10 percent market-share gain by generics is associated with
`a market-price decline of 6.1 percent two years after entry.
`
`II. THE EFFECT OF GENERIC ENTRY 0N PIONEER PRICES
`
`In this section, we examine the effect of generic entry on the pricing
`pattern of pioneers. The descriptive statistics in Table 1 indicate merely
`that pioneer prices in current dollars rose, on average, by 11 percent
`in the twenty-four months immediately after entry by the first generic
`competitor. Here, we first examine how pioneer prices were changing
`before entry and estimate statistically whether the pattern changed after
`entry. We then compare these results with the patterns for the Producer
`Price Index (PPI) of the therapeutic category to which each of these
`products belongs.
`The data base used for this analysis consists of annual. prices of the
`eighteen pioneer products in drugstores from 1980 to 1990..9 In order to
`have at least five years in the preentry period for all products, the series
`
`" Statman, supra note 9.
`" This analysis focuses on drugstore prices; hospital prices are omitted. Since hospital
`prices are governed by a difl'erent process (contractual bidding), they can follow a difi'erent
`trend line than drugstore prices. Moreover. the observed trend in overall drug prices will
`be influenced by changes in the composition of a firm’s hospital and drugstore sales over
`time. In order to prevent this from confounding changes in the trends associated with
`generic entry. we focus only on the drugstore sector. The dominant component of sales‘for
`the drugs in our sample is through retail pharmacies.
`
`000007
`
`000007
`
`

`

`338
`
`THE JOURNAL or LAW AND ECONOMICS
`
`began in 1978 for one product and in 1979 for four products. We also
`obtained the PPI for the relevant therapeutic categories for this period.20
`
`A . Regression Analysis
`
`We first estimated regressions of each product's price on time and
`allowed for a sl0pe change in the postentry period. Nominal prices were
`deflated by the gross national product implicit price defiator. The specifi-
`cation is given below:
`
`log(Pricc) = a0 + (II Time + azDumT.
`
`Time is the year; DumT is (time — T") if Time is greater than T" and
`zero otherwise; 1* is the year in which generic entry occurs. The variable
`DumT is constructed to insure that the time-trend segments join in T".
`Hence, the annual rate of price change is al in the preentry period and
`(al + (12) in the postentry period.
`The estimated coefficient for the rate of price increase, (1., is positive
`and statistically significant for seventeen of the eighteen products.“ The
`other product’s estimated coefficient for al is negative but not statistically
`significant. The average rate of price increases across all products derived
`from these regressions is 8.4 percent.
`The prevailing pattern for the slope-change coefficient in the postentry
`period is negative. In particular, the estimated coefficient for a2 takes on
`this negative sign for fourteen of the eighteen products.22 Only two of
`these negative coefficients, however, are statistically significant at 10 per-
`cent confidence intervals or better. Hence, the conclusion at this stage is
`that only two products (Haldol and Keflex) qualify as possible cases in
`which generic entry moderates the pioneer’s rate of price increase.
`The next step is to compare the patterns for these two products with
`the pattern for the relevant therapeutic category’s PPI. The comparison
`
`I” The study by Caves, Whinston. & Hurwitz, supra note ll. used a pooled sample
`spanning both the pre- and post-1984 period to estimate the effects of entry on the prices
`of brand-name pioneers. They found a small but statistically significant negative effect. They
`did not attempt to look at differences across products or differentiate between behavior in
`the pre- and post-I984 Act.
`2' While we do not report the actual eighteen regressions here, interested readers can
`obtain tables of the regressions from the authors. We should note that the one case with a
`negative coeflicient was Motrin, which experienced competition from the introduction of
`an over-the-counter version during this period.
`21 Two of the four products with positive coefficients were also statistically significant
`indicating that these products actually showed a price-rate increase in the postentry period.
`These products, however. increased their prices from a base-period rate in the preentry
`period that was well below the mean for the average rate of increase in their therapeutic
`class. Hence. this increase is subject to alternative interpretations.
`
`000008
`
`000008
`
`

`

`BRAND LOYALTY, ENTRY, AND COMPETITION
`
`339
`
`is necessary since a reduced rate of price increase in the postentry period
`may be due to a general competitive change affecting the therapeutic
`category as a whole, and it is desirable to try to distinguish this possibility
`from the specific generic-entry effect.
`For each product, a regression for the therapeutic category PPI (with
`T" corresponding to the product) was estimated. Haldol‘s rate of increase
`was [4.5 percent, falling to 2.5 percent postentry. The deflated PPI for
`psychotherapeutics had rates of 10.8 percent preentry and 9.0 percent
`postentry. Since Haldol's relative decline was substantially greater than
`its therapeutic category, we concluded that generic entry led to the mod-
`eration in Haldol‘s rate of price increase. We concluded the same for
`Keflex. Its rate of price increase was 6.6 percent preentry and only 4.4
`percent postentry. By comparison,
`its
`therapeutic category (anti-
`infectives) had a rate of price increase of 4.3 percent both pre- and post-
`entry.
`
`Overall, the effect of generic entry on pioneer pricing is not very sig-
`nificant in economic terms. There is no indication, for example, that any
`pioneers decreased their nominal prices in response to the much-lower
`generic prices or attempted any kind of entry-deterring price strategies.
`Recall from Table 1 that the ratio of generic to pioneer price averages
`.37 two years postentry. Furthermore, the highest ratio for any drug in
`the sample is only .58. Also, the two products that exhibited a statistically
`significant decrease from prior trends continued to increase their real
`prices by at least 2.5 percent per year.
`
`B.
`
`Interpretation of Findings
`
`Rather than attempting to match the prices of the lower-priced gener~
`ics, the originators have continued to increase prices at an average rate
`that exceeds general inflation. It may seem surprising that, in the face of
`the high rates of generic entry, these firms have generally chosen not to
`decrease prices. The literature contains some examples of incumbent
`firms that respond to entry by cutting prices and other examples where
`they keep prices unchanged. It is, perhaps, the most common view, how-
`ever, that the incumbents will be forced to lower their prices if entrants '
`enter with especially low prices.
`The rationality of pharmaceutical companies not matching lower ge-
`neric prices can be understood in terms of a segmented-market model.23
`
`21 A recent theoretical analysis using a segmented market model of pharmaceutical pricing
`is presented in Richard G. Frank & David Salkever, Pricing, Patent Loss, and the Market
`for Pharmaceuticals (Working Paper No. 3803, Nat'l Bur. Economic Research, August
`I991).
`
`000009
`
`000009
`
`

`

`340
`
`THE JOURNAL or LAW AND ECONOMICS
`
`In particular. it is reasonable to assume that the market is segmented
`between two groups—a price-sensitive group and a group that has strong
`brand loyalties to the incumbent. The strength of brand loyalties is dem-
`onstrated by the fact that, on average, pioneers keep about half their
`market in units despite the fact that generics are roughly one-third the
`price of pioneers (measured two years after entry).24 If the pioneer can
`keep half the market at the unchanged price as opposed to keeping the
`whole market by lowering the price to one-third its original level, simple
`calculations show the wisdom of choosing the unchanged-price strategy.”
`One qualification to these results should be noted: our eighteen drug
`products are all oral prescription drugs sold primarily through retail phar-
`macies to outpatients rather than to hospitals or other institutions. As
`part of a case involving a contested patent, one of the authors examined
`the data on pricing patterns for a few injectable products first experienc-
`ing generic competition in the period 1986-88. Injectables are sold almost
`exclusively to hospitals where the degree of brand loyalty is considerably
`less. In this case, it was found that the more prevalent pattern is for the
`incumbent firm to cut prices in the face of generic competition, although
`not to the lowest level of the generic entrants.26 These contrasting pat-
`terns for outpatient and inpatient drugs show that pricing policies will be
`influenced by the relative sizes of the different market segments. If the
`price-sensitive segment of the outpatient market were to continue to ex-
`pand in relative terms in the case of future patent expirations, then the
`
`2‘ Here. of course, we are referring to the ratio of the wholesale price of generics to
`pioneers—as reported in Table I. In fact, the relevant price ratio to the ultimate consumer
`is the retail—drug-store ratio. For our sample. the retail price ratio of generics to pioneers
`averages 65 percent compared to 45 percent at the wholesale level (measured one year
`postentry). This suggests that drugstores have higher markups for generics than on the
`pioneers. In a companion paper that we are in the process of writing. we have analyzed the
`margins for the generic and pioneer products at retail drugstores. Absolute margins for
`generics are higher than for pioneers, despite their lower cost to the drugstores. This means
`that price reductions at the manufacturer level stimulated by the I984 Act are not fully
`passed on to the ultimate consumers.
`2’ Using our average estimate of marginal cost at the date of entry as 25 percent of price
`(from Section III) and assuming that overall market demand is perfectly inelastic, profits
`will fall by 89 percent with price cutting and by only 50 percent with the price unchanged.
`Of course. this type of calculation is meant merely to illustrate the strong incentives for
`incumbents with significant brand loyalty to pursue a "market-harvesting" rather than a
`price-cutting strategy. A more extensive analysis would examine the effect of the pioneer‘s
`pricing policies on the rate of generic entry. Some results on this issue are presented in
`Section III.
`
`as The selection criteria for this admittedly small sample involved products with annual
`sales of at least ten million dollars (at the time of entry) and no close substitute or modified
`version of the product with patent protection. It was found that four of the five incumbent
`firms decreased their price in the period after generic entry. The average price decline for
`these branded products was 14 percent one year after initial entry. The sample of products
`was calcium leucorovinm, cytarabine, vancomycin, clindamycin. and methlydopa.
`
`000010
`
`000010
`
`

`

`BRAND LOYALTY, ENTRY, AND COMPETITION
`
`34]
`
`pricing policies for incumbent brands are likely to move in the direction
`of those observed for the hospital market.
`Finally,
`it
`is important
`to observe that firms can employ product-
`differentiation strategies to thwart genen‘c competition. In at least four
`cases (Catapres, Inderal, Calan/Isoptin, and Indocin), a significant vari-
`ant of the original product was introduced around the date of generic
`entry. The most successful variation was a “slow—release" dosage form
`of Calan/Isoptin, introduced in December 1986. Within two years. the
`slow-release version accounted for 81 percent of pioneer sales. Hence,
`shifting patients from the original formulation, subject to severe price
`competition, to a new formulation, insulated from price competition, is
`apparently an important strategy that can be employed at least in some
`instances.27 This is an issue that warrants further research.
`
`III.
`
`THE DETERMINANTS OF GENERIC ENTRY AND PRICES
`
`As observed above, generic prices in our sample move on a rapid
`downward dynamic path over time. These markets have apparently been
`characterized by easy entry conditions, at least since 1984. Furthermore,
`over the long run. one could reasonably expect that entry and competition
`would push generic drugs prices down to a level approaching the marginal
`cost of production.
`
`A. Determinants of Entry
`
`In this section, we will examine the factors influencing generic entry
`and prices. In a number of economic models in which a dominant firm
`experiences entry from a competitive fringe, it is assumed that the rate
`of entry will be a function of the difference between the dominant firm's
`price and the potential entrants minimum unit cost.” In other words, the
`rate of entry will increase with the entrant's profit opportunities, but it
`also can be retarded by barriers producing brand loyalty for the dominant
`firm's product.
`We will test whether the degree of entry by the generic firms in our
`eighteen-drug sample can be explained by such a relationship. In particu-
`lar, we estimate the following equation:
`
`Xl,l=l = flflu=0v ELit-=0),
`
`(I)
`
`17 All four modified versions of these products obtained patent protection utilizing the
`new mode of delivery as the basis. In addition. some obtained parallel market-exclusivity
`rights as a new dosage form under the I984 Act. See the US. Food and Drug Administration
`Approved Product List (annual) ("the Orange Book").
`2' See. for example. Darius W. Gaskins. Jr., Dynamic Limit Pricing: Optimal Pricing
`under Threat of Entry. 3 J. Econ. Theory 306 (197]).
`
`000011
`
`000011
`
`

`

`342
`
`where
`
`THE JOURNAL or LAW AND ECONOMICS
`
`X“.1 = number of generic suppliers for product i at the end of first
`year, I = I;
`11“,,0 = profitability to generics of entering the market for product
`i at time of initial entry, t = 0; and
`Film) = a set of brand loyalty entry barrier variables for product i
`at time of initial entry.
`
`is further defined as the percentage
`The profitability variable, 11,._,,0,
`markup of pioneer price over marginal cost at the point of initial entry.
`In symbolic terms one has
`
`1'l'r.i=o = (PPi,r=o " Mci)/PPI,I=Or
`
`(2)
`
`where
`
`PP,"=0 = pioneer's price at time I = 0; and
`MC,- = marginal cost of production for product i.
`
`A key issue is how to measure the marginal cost of each drug (MC) in
`order to compute their profitability. Our basic procedure was to make
`the assumption that competition would eventually force the generic price
`down to marginal cost and to estimate marginal cost as the asymptote
`toward which the generic price was falling?9
`Figure 1 illustrates our approach by plotting the trend in generic prices
`for the drug Lorazepam. Generics began competing with Lorazepam in
`September I985. The average generic-price data is plotted at six-month
`intervals'running from 1985 through mid-1988. Figure 1 also shows a
`regression of the generic price for Lorazepam on the reciprocal of time.
`The estimated equation is
`
`GP, = 5.34 + 175.3 (1/1),
`(2.89)
`(3.91)
`
`(3)
`
`where the adjusted R2 = 0.74. Hence, for Lorazepam, the intercept indi-
`cated a long-run marginal cost of 5.34 cents per pill. This is the value
`that we used for MC for this product.” This estimated value for marginal
`cost is 21 percent of the pioneer’s price at initial entry.
`
`1’ In order to utilize this approach, one needs s

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket