throbber
I -
`
`THINKING
`ECONO:MICALLY
`ABOUT
`COM:MERCIAL
`~UCCESS
`
`BY R. DEFOREST MCDUFF,
`RYAN C. ANDREWS, AND MATT D. BRUNDAGE
`
`E conomic experts frequently evaluate commercial success as a secondary consideration
`
`of the obviousness of a patented invention. 1 While other common economic inquiries
`are often based on widely recognized methodologies (e.g., the Panduit factors for lost
`profits, the Georgia-Pacific factors for reasonable royalties), expe11s often base analysis of com(cid:173)
`mercial success on a layperson's notion of "success," without appreciation of its purpose. For
`example, an expert may conclude that a product is a commercial success because sales and profits
`are "large" or "substantial," appealing to preconceived notions of success in other contexts ("sales
`of $100 million a year? ... sounds like a success to me!").
`We should be wary of such simplistic approaches to evaluating commercial success,
`which often fail to ask a fundamental economic question : success compared to what? Just
`as one individual's success in life may differ from another's, commercial success for one
`product in a particular context may differ from commercial success for another product in
`another context. Improper analysis of commercial success can be particularly problematic in
`pharmaceuticals, for example, which often require billions of dollars in sales for economic
`incentives to have existed for others to bring the product to market sooner. Evaluations of
`commercial success without proper context (or, for some experts, without any context at all)
`are unhelpful to the role of commercial success in patent litigation.
`Recent case law has clarified the purpose of commercial success and what it is intended to
`demonstrate. For example, the Federal Circuit stated in Merck v. Teva that commercial suc(cid:173)
`cess is relevant "because the law presumes an idea would successfully have been brought to
`market sooner, in response to market forces, had the idea been obvious to persons skilled in
`the art."2 This makes sense, from an economic perspective, because other parties would have
`economic incentives to commercialize obvious inventions if there were economic incentives
`to do so. However, based on our experience evaluating dozens of expert reports on com(cid:173)
`mercial success, all too often experts fail to provide relevant context and/or tie any alleged
`success back to the fundamental purpose outlined by the courts.
`This article summarizes challenges and shortcomings with common approaches to evalu(cid:173)
`ating commercial success, and offers guidance for providing appropriate economic analysis.
`We draw upon numerous expert evaluations of commercial success, with a focus in phar(cid:173)
`maceuticals and electronics, to provide practical insights on commercial success for both
`plaintiffs and defendants.
`
`Exhibit 1063
`ARGENTUM
`IPR2017-01053
`March/Apri l 20 17 • LANDSLIDE 37
`
`000001
`
`

`

`Overly Simplistic Analysis of Commercial Success
`Overly simplistic evaluations of commercial success frequently
`fail to provide sufficient information and analysis to conclude
`that economic incentives existed to bring the product to mar(cid:173)
`ket sooner. Such analysis often simply tabulates sa es, profi ts,
`and market shares, followeOby some grand conclusion on
`whether those constitute commercial success. Very little is said
`for whether sales are sufficient to compensate for the economic
`costs needed to develop the product and bring it to market.
`Experts often fail to compare sales and profits from the product
`in question to other comparable products in the industry, even
`though millions of dollars in one market might be successful in
`one industry and an utter failure in another.
`In our experience, this kind of analysis is too often set
`forth as alleged ev idence of commercial success. This overly
`simplistic approach to evaluating commercial success often
`misses the economic purpose of commercial success in
`informi ng on obviousness. Analyses rooted in a layperson's
`notion of success are not necessarily unscientific or false(cid:173)
`rather, they simply fail to connect with the purpose of the
`commercial success es tablished by the courts.
`Over time, courts have clarified the purpose of commer(cid:173)
`cial success in evaluating a patent's obviousness. Dating
`back to Smith v. Goodyear Dental (1876), the Supreme Court
`grappled with how to determine whether a new product was
`a legitimately novel invention.3 The Court indicated what
`might be learned from one product displacing others previ(cid:173)
`ously used for the same purpose, establishing the relevance
`of a product's market performance, but provided no clear
`economic standard for what kind of di splacement would be
`informative.4 The Supreme Court later identifi ed commer-
`cial success as a secondary consideration for nonobviousness
`in Graham v. John Deere (1966),5 a role that was strength(cid:173)
`ened upon establishment of the Federal Circuit in 1982. 6 One
`scholar suggested that commercial success was transformed
`"from a tiebreaker to a virtual trump card."7 Most recently,
`the Federal Circuit stated in Merck v. Teva (2005) (citi ng to
`Graham v. John Deere) that "[c]ommercial success is relevant
`because the law presumes an idea would successfully have
`been brought to market sooner, in response to market forces,
`had the idea been obvious to persons skilled in the art."8
`ere y reporting sales or market shares in a vacuum misses
`the point of a commercial-Success analysiJ> as explained by the
`courts. Net sales or market shares in isolation tell us very little
`-about whether market forces would have existed for other compa(cid:173)
`nies to have responded by bringing the product to market sooner.
`As one author noted: "For commercial success to be persuasive,
`a patentee must do more than show sales or market share data for
`her patented product. Although, under some older cases, this was
`enough)."9 Rather. commercial success should inform on whether
`
`sales--and profits provide objective evidence on whether material
`economic incentives (i.e., "market forces") would have incen(cid:173)
`tivized others to b1ing the product to market, had the invention
`been obvious. Other economists and scholars agree that this is, in
`essence, the fundamental purpose of commercial success analy(cid:173)
`sis. 10 Said another way, ideas are brought to market when there is
`a profit oppmtunity, not merely when sales or market shares are
`"high" or "substantial" in some abstract sense.
`
`Economic Analysis of Commercial Success
`A better approach to evaluating commercial success focuses
`on factors that are economically relevant for its purpose. While
`each analysis will be unique and specific to the facts of the par(cid:173)
`ticular case, some principles can provide guidance to improve
`putting forth or rebutting evidence of commercial success. This
`section elaborates on several such factors: (1) comparisons to
`relevant benchmarks, (2) comparisons to commercialization
`costs, (3) evaluation of market shares, and (4) evaluation of the
`inferential li mitations of any alleged commercial success.
`
`Com arisons to Relevant Benchmarks
`One useful measure in evaluating commercial success is a
`comparison of sales to relevant benchmarks in the industry(cid:173)
`for exam__Q)e: averag
`roduct sales, sales of competitors, and
`projections of potential sales. This provides guidance on what
`level of sales or revenues in the fie ld are typical, sought, and
`expected, and would yield an economic profit for a particular
`industry at a particular point in ti me.
`In the pharmaceutical industry, for example, economic lit(cid:173)
`erature provides context on the range of drug sales by drug type
`(e.g., cardiovascular, neurologic, etc.) and time period. For drugs
`launched from 1990 to 1994, anesthetic drugs earned $556 mil(cid:173)
`lion over the product life cycle, on average, compared to more
`than $2 billion for anti-infective drugs and more than $3 billion
`for cardiovascular drugs. 11 Economic research examining drugs
`by decile (i.e., lst decile from 90th percentile to 99th percentile,
`2nd decile from 80th percentile to 89th percentile) often pro(cid:173)
`vides additional context for where a drug fits into the broader
`industry.12 Notably, research indicates that only the top three
`deciles of drugs tend to be economically profitable, and that an
`average drug tends to yield close to break-even or even negative
`profits.13 All else equal, it is unlikely that a drug with sales below
`an average drug would be a commercial success. 14
`All too often, experts assert that sales are "high" in some
`abstract sense (even with little or no profi t), without evaluat(cid:173)
`ing what sales might have been expected or what sales have
`been earned by competitor products. By adding comparisons
`to the types of benchmarks described herei n, sales can be
`evaluated in proper context and better inform whether mate(cid:173)
`rial economic incentives for development existed.
`
`R. Deforest McDuff, PhD, is a partner at Insight Economics; he is an expert in applied business economics and provides expert witness testimony on
`intellectual property and other areas. Ryan C.Andrews is a former senior associate at Intensity; he has extensive experience evaluating lost profits,
`reasonable royalties, commercial success, and other areas. He is currently pursuing his MBA at The Wharton School at the University of Pennsylvania.
`Matt D. Brundage is an analyst at Intensity; his experience includes economic research and analysis for commercial success, reasonable royalties, and
`other economic damages. They may be reached, respectively, at deforest@insighteconomics.com, ryanandr@wharton.upenn.edu, and matt.brundage@
`intensity.com.The opinions expressed are those of the author(s) and may not reflect the views of their employers, clients, or any of their respective
`affil iates. This article is for general information purposes and is not intended to be and should not be taken as legal advice.
`
`38 LANDSLIDE • March/April201 7
`
`-
`
`000002
`
`

`

`Comparisons to Commercialization Costs
`Another useful but often overlooked measure in evaluating
`com mercial success is a comparison to commercialization
`costs for a product. Properly evaluated, including economic
`costs associated with actual expenditures, costs of capital,
`risk, and uncertainties, comparisons to commercialization
`costs can provide information for whether sales and profits
`are sufficient to generate an economic return on investment(cid:173)
`in other words, a material economic incentive for others to
`bring the product to market. For example, some economists
`argue that "commercial success could in principle be defined
`by a single criterion: Does the patented invention earn a
`positive net return risk-adjustea) on investea capital after
`accounting for all relevant costs associated with developing
`and commerciali zing the patent as well as any alternatives
`available to the patent holderT 15 echniques such as net pres(cid:173)
`ent value analysis can be helpful for comparing sales over
`time with costs associated with commercialization.
`In the pharmaceutical industry, a number of authors have
`determined that the cost of bringing a new pharmaceutical
`product to market exceeds $ 1 billion (and more than $2 bil(cid:173)
`lion based on estimates for more recent products). 16 These
`costs include out-of-pocket expenses of development and
`clinical trials, the cost of capital over time, and the ri sk
`of nonapproval (in which case all expenditures would be
`wasted), all of which are expected and considered when eval(cid:173)
`uating products in the pharmaceutical industry.17 If a drug
`product does not earn revenues and profits that sufficiently
`compensate pharmaceutical companies for significant eco(cid:173)
`nomic costs in bringing a product to market, that product will
`tend not to be a commercial success, all else being equal. 18
`Despite the economic foundation and connection to material
`economic incentives, expe1ts frequently fail to take into account
`the costs of development and commercialization when evaluat(cid:173)
`ing commercial success. 19 By adding comparisons to potential
`costs of commercialization described herein, sales and profits
`can be evaluated relative to the expense and investment required
`to bring the product to market, providing fmther evidence on
`material economic incentives for commercialization.
`
`Evaluation of Market Shares
`Market shares are a factor frequently considered by experts in
`evaluating commercial success, because they provide implicit
`comparisons to competitor products. However, the interpre(cid:173)
`tation of market shares can be difficult. For example, experts
`are often pressed at deposition to define what market share
`would provide a global cutoff for a commercially success-
`ful product (e.g., "Is it 5 percent? 10 percent? 25 percent? 50
`percent?"). The answer, because of how market shares are
`defined, is often: it depends.
`For example, a 5 percent share of one market might be com(cid:173)
`mercially successful , whereas a 20 percent share of another
`market might not be. The former market might be significant
`and commercialization costs may be low, whereas the second
`market might be smaller and commercialization costs may be
`high. As another example, a product may have a very high rev(cid:173)
`enue share but a very low quantity share due to factors like
`patent protection of competitors (e.g., branded versus generic
`
`pharmaceuticals). Trying to define an absolute cutoff for what
`market share, in the abstract, denotes a commercial success is
`a futile exercise. 20 Experts often disagree about market defi(cid:173)
`nition-i.e., which products define competition and which do
`not-yet the market definition and market share are inteiTe(cid:173)
`lated. It is the overall context, rather than a particular market
`share per se, that defines whether market shares are interpreted
`as persuasive evidence of commercial success.
`Unlike the other economic factors desc1ibed thus far, market
`shares are less directly connected to whether material economic
`incentives existed to bring the product to market sooner. Yet they
`can, at times, provide insight on the market opportunity for an
`invention and, in that sense, may inform on incentives to bring a
`product to market sooner when other information is less concrete.
`
`Economic Relevance of Commercial Success
`Finally, a thoughtful analysis of commercial success may
`consider whether any alleged success, if it exists, is relevant
`for evaluating the existence of material economic incentives
`to bring a product to market sooner. There are circumstances
`where even sales and profits that might normally be sufficient
`to generate economic interest in the product (e.g., a potential
`commercial opportunity) might not be informative on obvi(cid:173)
`ousness at the time of the invention because of other factors.
`For example, the presence of blocking patents or regu(cid:173)
`latory exclusivity often limits the economic relevance of
`commercial success. In this case, incentives for development
`may only exist for the party with that exclusivity and not
`for the market more generally. In Merck v. Teva, the plaintiff
`argued that Fosamax, the patented product in question , was
`commercially successfuJ.2 1 The Federal Circuit agreed, but
`found that Merck's earlier patent (a so-called "blocking pat(cid:173)
`ent" that blocked others from commercializing a Fosamax
`product) limited the economic relevance of commercial suc(cid:173)
`cess because other parties in the market could be blocked
`from bringing the product to market. 22 The court stated:
`"Because market entry by others was precluded on those
`bases, the inference of non-obviousness . . . from evidence of
`commercial success, is weak."23
`As another example, there may be contemporaneous evi(cid:173)
`dence around the time of the invention that shows a lack of
`commercial interest, even if the product later turns out to be
`commercially successful. In such a situation, sales and profits
`may provide limited evidence on whether material economic
`incentives existed to bring the product to market sooner,
`above and beyond the contemporaneous evidence already
`demonstrating this directly.
`In summary, experts can often benefit from asking whether
`commercial success, even if it exists, is relevant in evaluating
`the existence of material economic incentives around the time
`of the invention and, in turn , in evaluating obviousness of a
`particular patent at issue.
`
`Conclusion
`While the purpose of commercial success has been established
`for some time, too often we see basic principles being misap(cid:173)
`plied, misunderstood, or not acknowledged at all. Evaluating
`" uccess" in a vacuum, without proper context or benchmarks
`
`March/April 2017 • LANDSLIDE 39
`
`000003
`
`

`

`for compruison, can result in a flawed and misguided analysis.
`There is, of course, no single set of factors that are disposi-
`tive on commercial success in every situation, but providing
`additional context relating to the purpose of commercial suc(cid:173)
`cess (i.e., whether sales and profits demonstrate material
`economic incentives existed to have brought the product to
`market sooner) appears to be a step in the right direction. Suc(cid:173)
`cess, both in business and in life, requires an understanding and
`appreciation for what is meant to be achieved. •
`
`Endnotes
`1. Commercial success is one of several secondary consider(cid:173)
`ations intended to inform on whether a particular technology is
`obvious-
`i.e. , whether it differs enough from prior art in order to
`qualify as a patentable invention- which are often evaluated when
`defendants challenge a patent's validity in patent litigation. Because
`obviousness is the most common basis for finding that a pat-
`ent is invalid, commercial success can play an important role. For
`discussion and references, see Andrew Blair-Stanek, Profits as Com(cid:173)
`mercial Success , 117 YALE L.J. 642, 646 (2008); and Rebecca S.
`Eisenberg, Obvious to Whom? Evaluating Inventions from the Per(cid:173)
`spective of PHOSITA , 19 B ERKELEY TECH. L.J. 885, 885 (2004) .
`2. Merck & Co. v. Teva Pharm . USA, Inc., 395 F.3d 1364, 1376
`(Fed . Cir. 2005).
`3. Smith v. Goodyear Dental Vulcanite Co. , 93 U.S. 486, 495 (1876).
`4. !d. at 495- 96, cited in Blair-Stanek, supra note I , at 647.
`5. Graham v. John Deere Co., 383 U.S. 1, 17- 18 (1966) ("Such
`secondary considerations as commercial success, long felt but
`unsolved needs, failure of others, etc., might be utilized to give light
`to the circumstances surrounding the origin of the subject matter
`sought to be patented. As indicia of obviousness or nonobviousness,
`these inquiries may have relevancy.").
`6. Blair-Stanek, supra note I, at 647--48; see Graham, 383 U.S. at 11.
`7. Robe11 P. Merges, Commercial Success and Patent Standards:
`Economic Perspectives on Innovation, 76 CAL. L. REv. 803, 827 (1988).
`8. Merck & Co. v. Teva Pharm . USA, Inc. , 395 F.3d 1364, 1376
`(Fed. Cir. 2005).
`9. Merges, supra note 7, at 823.
`10. Jesse David & Marion B. Stewart, Commercial Success: Eco(cid:173)
`nomic Principles App/led to Patent Litigation. in ECONOMIC APPROACH ES
`TO I TELLECTlTA PROPERTY: OLICY, LITIGATION, AND MANAGEMENT
`196-99 (Gregory K. Leonard & Lau(en J. Stiroh eds .. 2005) ("A patented
`invention should be considered a commercial success if it can be shown
`to have earned, or can reasonably be expected toe, 11
`positive net ren1m
`oninvested capital after accounting-for all relevant costs associated with
`development and commercialization ... . ");J31air-Stanek, !!upra note
`, at
`649 ('The potential for commercial success presumably provides incen(cid:173)
`tives for others to try to perfect the invention, and the failure of others to
`do so suggests nonobviousness. Put most simply, the classical theory(cid:173)
`based argument goes, 'if an invention is both obvious and lucrative, why
`wasn't it thought of earlier?"'); Rahul Guha et al., The Economics of
`Commercial Success in Phannaceutical Patent Litigation, 1 LANDSLIDE,
`no. 5, May/June 2009, at 8 ("From an economic perspective, commercial
`success supports a conclusion of nonobviousness because it suggests that
`an economic incentive existed to produce the invention.").
`11. Joseph DiMasi et al. , R&D Costs and Returns by Therapeutic
`Category, 38 DRUG INFO. J. 211, 219 (2004).
`
`12. Henry Grabowski et al., Returns on Research and Develop(cid:173)
`ment fo r 1990s New Drug Introductions, 20 PHARMACOECONOMICS
`11, 17,22 (Supp. 3 2002).
`13. !d. at 17, 23; Ernst R. Berndt et al., Decline in Economic
`Returns from New Drugs Raises Questions about Sustaining Innova(cid:173)
`tions, 34 HEALTH AFF. 245, 245 , 252 (20 15).
`14. Skeptics might question why so many unprofitable drugs are
`brought to market. Reasons may vary, of course, but one impactful
`factor is the uncertain process of clinical trials and FDA approval
`occurring over many years. Once a company incurs sunk costs of
`development and clinical trials, it may be worthwhile to proceed to
`the market, even if the product never recoups all of those sunk costs .
`15. David & Stewart, supra note 10, at 196.
`16. For sources and discussion, see Joseph DiMasi et al., Innova(cid:173)
`tion in the Pharmaceutical Industry: New Estimates of R&D Costs,
`47 J. HEALTH EcoN. 20 (20 16). For a variety of other sources and ref(cid:173)
`erences over time, see JORGE MESTRE-FERRANDIZ ET AL. , OFFICE OF
`HEALTH EcoN., THE R&D CosT oF A NEw MEDICINE 1-86 (20 12);
`Joseph A. DiMasi & Henry G. Grabowski , R&D Costs and Returns to
`New Drug Development: A Review of the Evidence, in THE OXFORD
`HANDBOOK OF THE ECONOMICS OF THE BIOPHARMACEUTICA L I DUS(cid:173)
`TRY 29 (Patricia M. Danzon & Sean Nicholson eds., 2010); Joseph A.
`DiMasi et al., The Price of Innovation: New Estimates of Drug Devel(cid:173)
`opment Costs, 22 J. HEALTH ECON. !51 , !51 (2003); Joseph A.
`DiMasi & Henry G. Grabowski, The Cost of Biopharmaceutical
`R&D: Is Biotech Different?, 28 MANAGERIAL & DECISION ECON. 469,
`477 (2007); and Grabowski et al., supra note 12.
`17. See MEsTRE-FERRAND!Z ET AL., supra note 16; DiMasi eta!.,
`Innovation in the Phannaceutical/ndustry, supra note 16; DiMasi et al.,
`The Price of Innovation, supra note 16; Grabowski et al., supra note 12.
`18. Interestingly, some authors have argued that pharmaceuti-
`cal products may be commercially successful even when they do
`not generate a positive return on investment, because there may still
`be some therapeutic value associated with their use. See, e.g., Guha
`et al., supra note 10, at 11-12 n.10 ("[A] lack of positive return on
`capital investment should not necessarily undermine a conclusion of
`commercial success. A few 'blockbuster' drugs generate the major(cid:173)
`ity of profits for the drug companies. That means the majority of
`smaller drugs may not be profitable in the sense of recouping all the
`costs of their discovery and development, even if they have proven
`therapeutic value."). However, products may be therapeutically
`valuable or desirable without being commercially successful and
`sufficient to provide incentives to bring products to market sooner.
`19. While the costs of commercialization are often not available
`in historical records, either due to the passage of time or non(cid:173)
`specific attribution of costs to a particular product, we have had
`success linking the facts and circumstances of a particular product
`to peer-reviewed published literature on commercialization costs,
`accounting for time of launch , therapeutic category, and the actual
`duration of clinical costs.
`20. See, e.g., David & Stewart, supra note 10, at 196 ("However,
`under certain circumstances, rapid sales growth and gains in market
`share will not necessarily reflect a profitable underlying invention.").
`21. Merck & Co. v. Teva Pharm. USA, Inc. , 395 F.3d 1364, 1376
`(Fed. Cir. 2005).
`22. !d. at 1376- 77.
`23. !d. at 1377.
`
`40 LANDSLIDE • March/April2017
`
`000004
`
`

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket