throbber
Measuring the Informative and Persuasive Roles of
`
`Detailing on Prescribing Decisions*
`
`Andrew Chingt
`Masakazu Ishihara
`Rotman School of Management
`University of Toronto
`
`First draft: May 5, 2008
`This draft: April 27, 2010
`
`*We thank Abe Dunn, A vi Goldfarb, Nitin Mehta, and seminar participants at the University of Toronto,
`
`Conference on Health Economics and the Pharmaceutical Industry in Toulouse, 2008 IIOC Conference, 2008
`
`North American Econometric Society Summer Meeting, 2009 AEA Annual Meeting, 2009 CEA Annual Confer(cid:173)
`
`ence, and 2009 Marketing Science Conference for their helpful comments. All remaining errors are ours. We are
`
`grateful to CurrentPartnering for sharing their report on co-marketing agreement with us. We also acknowledge
`
`the financial support provided by the Michael Lee-Chin Family Institute for Corporate Citizenship at Rotman
`
`School of Management.
`
`tPlease direct all correspondence to: Andrew Ching, Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto,
`
`105 St. George Street, Toronto, ON, CANADA M5S 3E6. Phone: 416-946-0728. Fax: 416-978-5433. Email:
`
`andrew.ching@rotman.utoronto.ca.
`
`PLAINTIFFS'
`TRIAL EXHIBIT
`PTX0433
`
`MEDA_APTX03502998
`
`PTX0433-0000 1
`
`1
`
`CIP2097
`Argentum Pharmaceuticals LLC v. Cipla Ltd.
`IPR2017-00807
`
`

`

`Measuring the Informative and Persuasive Roles of Detailing on
`
`Prescribing Decisions
`
`Abstract
`
`In the pharmaceutical industry, measuring the importance of informative and persuasive
`
`roles of detailing is crucial for both drug manufacturers and policy makers. However, little
`
`progress has been made in disentangling the informative and persuasive roles of detailing in
`
`empirical research. In this paper, we provide a new identification strategy to separately identify
`
`these two roles. Our key identification assumption is that the informative component of detailing
`
`is chemical specific while the persuasive component is brand specific. Our strategy is to focus
`
`on markets where some drug manufacturers engage in a co-marketing agreement. Under a
`
`co-marketing agreement, two companies market the same chemical using two different brand(cid:173)
`
`names. With our identification assumption, the variations in the relative market share of these
`
`two brands, together with their brand specific detailing efforts, would allow us to measure the
`
`persuasive component of detailing. The variations in the market share of chemicals, and the
`
`detailing efforts summed across brands made of the same chemical, would allow us to measure
`
`the informative component of detailing. Using the data from the Canadian market for ACE(cid:173)
`
`inhibitor with diuretic, we find evidence that our identification strategy could outperform the
`
`traditional way of identifying these two effects. We find that both the informative and persuasive
`
`components are strong in this market. We also find that patients could be worse off if the
`
`government bans detailing for ACE-inhibitor with diuretic.
`
`Keywords: Detailing, Informative Role, Persuasive Role, Prescription Drugs, Decisions Under
`
`Uncertainty, Diffusion
`
`MEDA_APTX03502999
`
`PTX0433-00002
`
`2
`
`

`

`1
`
`Introduction
`
`In the pharmaceutical industry, measuring the importance of informative and persuasive roles of
`
`detailing is crucial for both drug manufacturers and policy makers. Understanding the relative
`
`importance of these two roles could help drug manufacturers allocate resources to detailing more
`
`efficiently. If the persuasive role is important, firms could create artificial product differentiation
`
`by increasing their detailing efforts. On the contrary, if detailing is mainly informative and its
`
`persuasive role is weak, the effectiveness of detailing intensity will highly depend on the actual
`
`quality of drugs (i.e., side-effects and efficacy profiles). Among policy debates, many people
`
`believe that detailing is mainly persuasive and consumers will be better off if the industry
`
`reduces their detailing budget. Consequently, there are frequent calls for the industry to restrict
`
`detailing activities. However, if detailing is mainly informative in nature, putting restrictions
`
`on it might slow down the adoption rate of new innovative drugs. Consequently, this would
`
`not only hurt manufacturers' profits and their incentives to innovate, but also lower consumer
`
`welfare.
`
`Despite its importance, little progress has been made in disentangling the informative and
`
`persuasive roles of detailing. The main difficulty is that both effects would likely have positive
`
`impacts on the demand for prescription drugs. If one only observes sales and detailing efforts
`
`over time, it is hard to disentangle these two roles. In this paper, we provide a new identification
`
`strategy to separately identify the persuasive and informative roles of detailing. Our key identi(cid:173)
`
`fication assumption is that the informative component of detailing is chemical specific while the
`
`persuasive component is brand specific. Our strategy is to focus on a market where some drug
`
`manufacturers engage in a co-marketing agreement. Under such an agreement, two companies
`
`market the same chemical under two different brand-names. With our identification assump(cid:173)
`
`tion, the variation in the relative market share of these two brands, together with their brand
`
`specific detailing efforts, would allow us to measure the persuasive component of detailing. After
`
`controlling for the persuasive effect, the variation in the market share of chemicals, and the cor(cid:173)
`
`responding chemical specific detailing efforts summed across brands made of the same chemical,
`
`would allow us to measure the informative component of detailing. For instance, if detailing
`
`does not play any persuasive role at all, our assumptions would imply that the market shares
`
`1
`
`MEDA_APTX03503000
`
`PTX0433-00003
`
`3
`
`

`

`for two brand-name drugs made of the same chemical should be roughly the same over time
`
`even if the det ailing efforts are different across these two brands (assuming other marketing-mix
`
`variables are about the same across brands).
`
`More specifically, t o model persuasive det ailing, we follow the previous literature (e.g.,
`
`Nerlove and Arrow 1962) and allow a brand specific persuasive det ailing goodwill st ock t o enter
`
`physicians' utility functions. To model informative det ailing, we consider two alternative models
`
`of informative det ailing that have been used in the literature. The first model follows Ching and
`
`Ishihara (2010), which models informative det ailing as a means t o build/ maintain the measure
`
`of physicians who know the most updated information about drugs. The second model follows
`
`Narayanan et al. (2005), in which detailing conveys noisy signals about the true quality of drugs
`
`to physicians.
`
`Our identification strategy applies to both product level data and individual level data.
`
`As an application, we apply it to the product level data from the market of ACE-inhibitor
`
`with diuretic in Canada. 1 This market has three brand-name drugs: Vaseretic, Zestoretic, and
`
`Prinzide. Zestoretic and Prinzide are made of the same chemicals, but are co-marketed by two
`
`different companies. To demonstrate the usefulness of our identification strat egy, in addition
`
`t o estimating the full model with all three brands, we also estimat e two versions with only
`
`two brands: Zestoretic and Prinzide, assuming that in one version, we treat the two brands as
`
`the same 1 chemical (i.e., we use our co-marketing identification argument), and in the other
`
`version, we treat the two brands as different two chemicals (i.e., we do not use the co-marketing
`
`identification argument). We argue that the identification of the informative and persuasive
`
`effects in the 2-chemical version relies more heavily on the functional form assumption.
`
`In
`
`particular, we find that the estimation results are counterintuitive in the 2-chemical version -
`
`the persuasive effect of detailing is negative and insignificant. On the contrary, the estimation
`
`results from the 1-chemical version are much more sensible - the persuasive effect is positive
`
`and significant, regardless of the way we model the informative det ailing.
`
`1 Although we use product level data to illustrate our identification strategy, it should be emphasized that
`
`the argument applies to individual level data as well. The basic identification ideas are the same except that we
`
`will need to set up individual level likelihood when estimating the parameters.
`
`2
`
`MEDA_APTX03503001
`
`PTX0433-00004
`
`4
`
`

`

`Based on the parameter estimates from the full model with three brands, we investigate
`
`the importance of informative and persuasive detailing by simulating our model in the case
`
`of ACE-inhibitor with diuretic. We find that both informative and persuasive components
`
`are important. In particular, the informative component is mainly responsible for the growth
`
`of the demand for chemicals, and the persuasive component mainly influences brand choice.
`
`Furthermore, to examine the overall impact of detailing on patient welfare, we use compensating
`
`variation to measure changes in the patient's welfare over time from banning detailing activities.
`
`Our simulation results suggest that banning detailing could cost a patient as large as $160 per
`
`prescription during our sample period in the Canadian ACE-inhibitor with diuretic market.
`
`The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the literature and discusses
`
`the background of the co-marketing agreement. Section 3 describes the demand models. Section
`
`4 describes the data. Section 5 discusses the results. Section 6 is the conclusion.
`
`2 Literature Review and Co-marketing Agreement
`
`2.1 Previous Literature on Persuasive Detailing
`
`How does detailing affect physicians' prescribing decisions? Leffler (1981) argues that detailing
`
`plays both informative and persuasive roles. He finds that newly introduced drugs tend to
`
`receive more detailing than older drugs, and interprets this as evidence that supports informative
`
`detailing. He argues that physicians are relatively unfamiliar with new drugs and hence if
`
`detailing provides information about drug's benefits and side-effects, drug manufacturers would
`
`spend more detailing efforts for newer drugs. However, he also finds that drug companies
`
`still spend significant amount of detailing efforts on old drugs and target older physicians. He
`
`interprets this as evidence for its persuasive role, assuming that older physicians have already
`
`known the older drugs' efficacy and side-effect profiles.
`
`Hurwitz and Caves (1988) find that pre-patent expiration cumulative detailing efforts slow
`
`down the decline in post-patent expiry market shares of brand-name drugs. They interpret
`
`3
`
`MEDA_APTX03503002
`
`PTX0433-00005
`
`5
`
`

`

`this as evidence for its persuasive role. Rizzo (1999) also finds evidence that detailing lowers
`
`the price elasticity of demand and argues that it supports persuasive detailing. However, it
`
`should be pointed out that the results from Hurwitz and Caves (1988) and Rizzo (1999) are
`
`also consistent with informative detailing. As argued by Leffler (1981), informative detailing
`
`reduces the uncertainty about drug qualities, and hence could also achieve similar empirical
`
`implications.
`
`Narayanan et al. (2005) is the first paper that structurally estimates the informative and
`
`persuasive roles of detailing in the pharmaceutical market. They extend the framework of Erdem
`
`and Keane (1996). Their identification argument builds on Leffler (1981) - they assume that
`
`drug companies know the true quality of their products when launching them, and informative
`
`detailing provides physicians with noisy signals about their products' true qualities. With this
`
`assumption, physicians will eventually learn the true quality of the drugs and detailing no longer
`
`plays any informative role in the long-run. As a result, the long-run correlation between sales
`
`and cumulative detailing efforts will identify the parameters that capture the persuasive role of
`
`detailing. The product diffusion paths then identify the parameters that capture the informative
`
`role. It should be emphasized that in their framework, in order to separately identify the
`
`informative and persuasive roles of detailing, it is crucial that: (i) one assumes detailing does
`
`not play any informative role in the long-run; (ii) the data set needs to be long enough so that
`
`it captures part of the product lifecycle after learning is complete. 2 In contrast, this modeling
`
`assumption and data requirement are not necessary for our identification strategy.
`
`Another related paper is by Ackerberg (2001). He argues that one can empirically dis(cid:173)
`
`tinguish informative and persuasive effects of advertising by examining consumers' purchase
`
`behavior conditional on whether they have tried the product before. His insight is that ad(cid:173)
`
`vertisements that give consumers product information should primarily affect consumers who
`
`have never tried the brand, whereas persuasive advertisements should affect both inexperienced
`
`and experienced consumers. His identification argument requires one to observe individual level
`
`2 Anand and Shachar (2005), Byzalov and Shachar (2004), Chan et al. (2007), Mehta et al. (2008), Narayanan
`
`and Manchanda (2009) rely on similar identification arguments to estimate the informative and persuasive roles
`
`of advertising using individual level data.
`
`4
`
`MEDA_APTX03503003
`
`PTX0433-00006
`
`6
`
`

`

`panel data, while our identification strategy applies as long as one observes product level panel
`
`dat a.
`
`2.2 Co-marketing Agreement
`
`Co-marketing in the pharmaceutical industry is a marketing practice where a company in ad(cid:173)
`
`dition t o its own, uses another company's sales force t o promot e the same product , and allow
`
`anot her company to use a different brand name.3 According to CurrentPartnering (2009), the
`
`t ot al number of co-marketing deals announced in the United States between 2000 and 2008 is
`
`208, and the yearly number has remained at fairly steady levels. One reason why a company
`
`that develops the drug is willing to partner with another company could be because it requires
`
`high fixed costs to build a sales force. The sales force in the pharmaceutical industry requires
`
`extensive training because they are required to know the clinical trials results of not only the
`
`drug being promoted, but also their rivals' drugs. Instead of paying such a high fixed cost, a
`
`company which is short in their sales force of promoting a certain category of drugs (say a high
`
`blood pressure drug) might find it worthwhile to sign a co-marketing agreement with another
`
`company, and charge its part ner a royalty fee.
`
`This type of marketing agreement has also appeared in the automobile industry (Sullivan
`
`1998; Lado et al. 2003). Furthermore, for industrial products, it is common that different firms
`
`market essentially identical products using their own brand-names (Saunders and Watt 1979;
`
`Bernitz 1981). In some countries, firms also market generic drugs with a brand name (Birkett
`
`2003). Under these environments, we expect that our identification arguments could also be
`
`applied.
`
`3There is another type of related arrangement which is called co-promotion agreement where two or more
`
`firms market the same drug under one brand-name.
`
`5
`
`MEDA_APTX03503004
`
`PTX0433-00007
`
`7
`
`

`

`3 Model
`
`We now turn to describe the models that will be used to implement our new identification
`
`strategy for informative and persuasive detailing. We consider two structural models that have
`
`been developed in the literature. They differ in terms of how to model the role of informative
`
`detailing. The first model (Model CI) extends Ching and Ishihara (2010) . They model infor(cid:173)
`
`mative detailing as a means to build/maintain the measure of physicians who know the most
`
`updated information about drugs. The second model (Model NMC) follows Narayanan et al.
`
`(2005), who model detailing as a way of conveying noisy signals about the true quality of drugs
`
`to physicians. In both models, we model the persuasive role of detailing by including a detailing
`
`goodwill stock in the utility function for physicians. These two models allow us to capture the
`
`role of informative detailing under different environments. For example, when manufacturers
`
`know the true quality of their drugs from the beginning of the product lifecycle, Model NMC
`
`is particularly relevant. When manufacturers do not know the true quality and use detailing
`
`to inform or remind physicians of the most updated information, Model CI is more appropri(cid:173)
`
`ate. Since these two models generate different empirical implications, it is of our interest to
`
`investigate how our identification strategy performs regardless of the way we model informative
`
`detailing.
`
`The following basic setup is common in both models. We consider a set of brand-name
`drugs, which treat the same illness using similar chemical mechanisms. Let j = 1, ... , J indexes
`brands, j = 0 denotes an outside alternative, which represents other close substitutes. Some
`
`of the brands may be marketed under a co-marketing agreement and are made of the same
`chemical. Let k = 1, ... , K indexes for chemicals, where K :=::; J. Let Ak be the set of brands
`
`that are made of chemical k. We assume that each brand is made of one of K chemicals. The
`
`characteristics of brand j E Ak are given by Pj and qk, where Pj is the price of product j, and qk
`
`is the mean quality level of chemical k. Physicians are imperfectly informed about the chemical's
`mean quality level, qk. Let I(t) = (I1(t), ... ,IK(t)) be a vector of public information sets that
`describe the most updated belief about q = ( q1, ... , qK) at time t.
`
`6
`
`MEDA_APTX03503005
`
`PTX0433-00008
`
`8
`
`

`

`As we mentioned, CI and NMC differ in terms of how they model informative detailing.
`
`Model CI assumes that J(t) is updated by a representative opinion leader based on past patients'
`
`experiences with the chemical. 4 This is the only role that he/she plays. For each chemical k, a
`
`physician either knows Ik(t), or Ik, which is the initial prior that physicians have when a drug
`made of chemical k is first introduced. 5 Let Mkt be the measure of physicians who know h(t).
`
`In CI, Mkt depends on the cumulative detailing efforts at time t. The learning process for J(t)
`
`is similar in NMC; however, they assume that detailing does not influence Mkt· More precisely,
`they assume Mkt = 1, Vk, t. Moreover, other than consumption experience signals, detailing also
`provides noisy signals about the true quality of the chemicals for updating the I(t).
`
`Our key identification assumptions are: 1) informative detailing is chemical-specific; and
`
`2) persuasive detailing is brand-specific. The first assumption implies: (a) h(t) is updated based
`
`on past patients' experiences for all products made of chemical k; (b) in Model CI, Mkt depends
`
`on the sum of the cumulative detailing efforts for all drugs made of chemical k; and (c) in Model
`
`NMC, in addition to past patients' drug experiences, h(t) are also updated based on the sum
`
`of the detailing signals for all drugs made of chemical k. The second assumption implies that
`
`the persuasive detailing goodwill stock for brand j is built based only on the detailing efforts
`
`for brand j. In what follows, we will describe Model CI first, and then Model NMC.
`
`3.1 Model CI (Ching and Ishihara 2010)
`
`3.1.1 Updating of the Information Set
`
`A drug is an experienced good. Consumption of a drug provides information about its quality.
`
`It is assumed that physicians and patients in the model can measure drug qualities according to
`
`4 A representative opinion leader captures the following intuition. The medical continuing education litera(cid:173)
`
`ture finds that opinion leaders are an important source of information for general physicians (e.g., Haug 1997,
`
`Thompson 1997). In Medicine, opinion leaders are physicians who specialize in doing research in a particular
`
`field (e.g., cardiovascular). The research focus of their career requires them to be much more updated about the
`
`current evidence about the drugs used in the field.
`
`5For simplicity, we assume that physicians and the representative opinion leader share the same initial prior
`
`belief. In general, we can allow them to be different.
`
`7
`
`MEDA_APTX03503006
`
`PTX0433-00009
`
`9
`
`

`

`a fixed scale. For example, a patient can measure quality in terms of how long he/she needs to
`
`wait before the drug becomes effective to relieve his/her symptoms, how long his/her symptoms
`
`would be suppressed after taking the drug, or how long the side-effects would last.6
`
`Each patient i's experience with the quality of a drug made of chemical k at timet (fjikt)
`
`may differ from its mean quality level qk. As argued in Ching (2000; 2010; 2011), the difference
`
`between fiikt and qk could be due to the idiosyncratic differences of human bodies in reacting to
`
`drugs. An experience signal may be expressed as,
`
`(1)
`
`where 8ikt is the signal noise. We assume that 8ikt is an i.i.d. normally distributed random
`
`variable with zero mean, and the representative opinion leader's initial prior on qk (lk) is also
`
`normally distributed:
`
`(2)
`
`The representative opinion leader updates the public information set at the end of each period
`
`using the experience signals that are revealed to the public. The updating is done in a Bayesian
`
`fashion . In each period, we assume that the number of experience signals revealed is a random
`
`subsample of the entire set of experience signals. This captures the idea that not every patient
`
`revisits and discusses his/her experiences with physicians, and not every physician shares his/her
`
`patients' experiences with others.
`
`According to the Bayesian rule (DeGroot 1970), the expected quality is updated as follows:
`
`(3)
`
`where iikt is the sample mean of all the experience signals that are revealed in period t; ik(t) is a
`
`Kalman gain coefficient, which assigns the updating weight to iikt· Note that both ik(t) and the
`perception variance, O"~(t + 1), are functions of the variance of the signal noise (O"~), perceived
`
`6 0bviously, drug qualities are multi-dimensional. Following Ching (2010), we implicitly assume patients are
`
`able to use a scoring rule to map all measurable qualities to a one-dimensional index. It is the value of this
`
`one-dimensional index that enters the utility function.
`
`8
`
`MEDA_APTX03503007
`
`PTX0433-0001 0
`
`10
`
`

`

`variance (O"~(t)), the quantities sold at timet for all drugs made of chemical k (n~), 7 and the
`proportion of experience signals revealed to the public (i'l:). They can be expressed as:
`
`and
`
`(4)
`
`The above expressions imply: ( i) "k ( t) increases with O"~ ( t); ( ii) after observing a sufficiently
`
`large number of experience signals for a product , the representative opinion leader will learn
`
`about qk, at any arbitrarily precise way (i.e., O"k(t) ---* 0 and E[qkii(t)] ---* qk as the number of
`
`signals received grows large).
`
`3.1.2 Detailing and Measure of Well-Informed Physicians
`
`There is a continuum of physicians with measure one. They are heterogeneous in their informa(cid:173)
`
`tion sets. A physician is either well-informed or uninformed about chemical k. A well-informed
`
`physician knows the current information set maintained by the representative opinion leader,
`
`i.e., h(t). An uninformed physician only knows the initial prior, i.e., l_k. This implies that the
`
`number of physician types is 2K . 8
`
`The measure of well-informed physicians for chemical k at time t , Mkt , is a function of
`
`Mkt- 1 and Dlt, ... , DJt· For simplicity, we assume that this function only depends on Mkt- 1
`and D~ = EjEAk Djt, i.e., Mkt = f(Mkt-1, D~). We assume that f(Mkt-1, .) is monotonically
`increasing in Df. To capture the idea that physicians may forget, we assume that f(M, 0) ::::;
`
`M,'VM.
`
`Following Ching and Ishihara (2010), in our econometric model, we capture the relationship
`
`between Mkt and (Mkt-1, Df) by introducing a detailing goodwill stock, Gfn which accumulates
`
`as follows:
`
`7 nf is the total quantity prescribed for chemical k at time t, including free samples measured in number of
`prescriptions.
`
`8For justifications of this modeling assumption, see Ching and Ishihara (2010).
`
`(5)
`
`9
`
`MEDA_APTX03503008
`
`PTX0433-00011
`
`11
`
`

`

`where cjy1 E [0, 1] is the depreciation rate. We specify the relationship between Mkt and Gkt as:
`exp(f3o + /31 G{t)
`(
`1 + exp f3o + f31Gkt
`
`(6)
`
`M _
`kt -
`
`I ) ·
`
`3.1.3 Prescribing Decisions
`
`Now we turn to discuss how physicians make their prescribing decisions. Each physician t akes
`
`the current expect ed utility of his/her patients into account when making prescribing decisions.
`
`Physician h's objective is to choose dhij (t) t o maximize the current period expected utility for
`
`his/her patients:
`
`E[ L Uijt . dhij ( t) IIh ( t)],
`
`jE{O,l, ... ,J}
`
`(7)
`
`where dhij(t) = 1 indicates that alternative j is chosen by physician h for patient i at time t,
`and dhij(t) = 0 indicates otherwise. We assume that Ej dhij(t) = 1. The demand system is
`
`obtained by aggregating this discrete choice model of an individual physician's behavior.
`
`We assume that a patient's utility of consuming a drug can be adequately approximated
`
`by a quasilinear utility specification, additively separable in a concave subutility function of
`
`drug return, and a linear t erm in price. The utility of patient i who consumes drug j made of
`chemical k at time t is given by the following expression:
`
`(8)
`
`where ai is a brand-specific intercept; r is the risk aversion parameter; 1rp is the utility weight
`for price; ( ~ilt + (ikt + eijt) represents the distribution of patient heterogeneity; and k, l indexes
`nests. 9 ~ilt, (ikt, and eijt are unobserved to the econometrician but observed to the physicians
`
`when they make their prescribing decisions. We assume that ~ilt, (ikt and eijt are i.i.d. extreme
`
`value distributed. In this specification, r represents the coefficient of absolute risk aversion.
`
`Also, we allow a brand-specific intercept to capture time-invariant differences among drugs.
`
`9This is equivalent to modeling physicians' choice as a three-stage nested process, where they choose between
`
`the inside goods and the outside good in the first stage, choose one of the chemicals in the second stage, and an
`
`alternative made of the chemical chosen in the second stage.
`
`10
`
`MEDA_APTX03503009
`
`PTX0433-00012
`
`12
`
`

`

`Note that iiikt is observed neither by physicians nor patients when prescribing decisions
`
`are made. It is observed by physicians/patients only after patients have consumed the drug,
`
`but it remains unobserved by the econometrician. P hysicians make their decisions based on the
`
`expected utility of their patients. Let I (t) and Jh(t) denot e the representative opinion leader's
`
`information set and physician h's information set at time t , respectively. For drug j E A k, if
`physician his well-informed about chemical k at time t, his/her expected utility will be:
`
`E[uift llh(t) ]
`
`E[uijt llk(t) ] + "fpGft + "fs F Sjt
`= aj - exp( - r E[qk ii(t )] + ~r2 (0'~(t) + 0'~))- 1fpPjt
`+ "fpGft + "!s F Sit + c:;itt + (ikt + eift,
`
`(9)
`
`where G_ft is a detailing goodwill stock for drug j at time t, and 'YP captures the effect of
`
`persuasive detailing; F Sit is the amount of free samples given for drug j at time t, and 'Ys
`
`captures the effect of free samples. Similar to Git, we assume that G_ft accumulates as follows:
`
`(10)
`
`We emphasize that G_ft is drug j specific rather than chemical k specific. Furthermore, we allow
`
`the depreciation rat es t o be different for G{t and G_ft. We should also note that Ching and
`
`Ishihara (2010) just focus on modeling the informative role of det ailing, and they do not allow
`
`for G_ft in the utility function. They also do not control for free samples.
`
`If physician his uninformed about chemical kat timet, his/her expected utility of choosing
`
`drug j E Ak becomes:
`
`E[uiftllk] + "fpGft +"(sF Sit
`ai- exp(-rrj_k + ~r2(Q:~ + 0'~)) -1fpPjt
`+"fpGft + "fsFSft + c:;ilt + (ikt + eift·
`
`(11)
`
`It should be noted that patient heterogeneity components of the utility function ( <:;ilt, (ikt, eift)
`
`reappear in the expected utility equation because they are stochastic only from the econometri(cid:173)
`
`cian's point of view.
`
`Equations (8)-(11) apply only to the inside goods. In each period, physicians may also
`
`choose an outside alternative that is not included in our analysis (i.e., other non-bioequivalent
`
`11
`
`MEDA_APTX0350301 0
`
`PTX0433-00013
`
`13
`
`

`

`drugs). We assume the expected utility associated with the outside alternative takes the follow(cid:173)
`
`ing functional form:
`
`(12)
`
`The time trend of the outside alternative allows the model to explain why the t ot al demand for
`
`inside goods may increase or decrease over time.
`
`The quantity demand for drug j E Ak, nit, can be expressed as,
`
`where Sizet is the size of the market, S(jl·) is the market share of drug j, Ejt represents a
`measurement error, and ed is a set of demand side parameters.
`
`(13)
`
`3.2 Model NMC (Narayanan et al. 2005)
`
`Many elements in Model NMC are similar to Model CI. Therefore, we will only discuss the
`
`elements that are specific t o Model NMC. All the variables introduced in the previous section
`
`will be used here without repeating the descriptions.
`
`3.2.1 Updating of the Information Set
`
`In Model NMC, in addition to consumption experience signals, detailing provides physicians
`
`with noisy signals about the true quality of drugs. Let ij~kt be the detailing signal about the
`
`quality of chemical k that physician h receives at time t. Similar to consumption experience
`
`signals, it may be expressed as,
`
`where f)hkt is the signal noise. We assume that f)hkt is an i.i.d. normally distributed random
`
`variable with zero mean:
`
`(14)
`
`fJhkt
`
`rv N(O, O"~).
`
`(15)
`
`12
`
`MEDA_APTX03503011
`
`PTX0433-00014
`
`14
`
`

`

`Signals from patients' experiences and detailing are used to update I(t + 1) in a Bayesian
`
`fashion. According to the Bayesian rule (DeGroot 1970), the expected quality is updated as
`
`follows:
`
`where fltt is the sample mean of all the detailing signals for chemical k in period t. 10 Note that
`
`unlike Model CI, the expected quality is updated based on consumption signals and detailing
`
`signals. ik(t) and wk(t) are expressed as
`
`and
`
`(17)
`
`where K,d is a scaling parameter similar to K,.
`
`ik and wk can be interpreted as the weights that
`
`physicians attach to consumption experiences and detailing efforts in updating its expectation
`
`about the level of qk.
`
`The perception variance at the beginning of timet+ 1 is given by (DeGroot 1970):
`
`(18)
`
`Physicians' prescribing decisions are identical to those of Model CI except that all physi(cid:173)
`
`cians are informed of I(t), i.e., Mkt = 1 Vk, t.
`
`4 Background and Data Description
`
`4.1 Background
`
`Now we turn to discuss the Canadian market of ACE-inhibitor with diuretic in Canada. ACE-
`
`inhibitor works by limiting production of a substance that promotes salt and water retention in
`
`the body. Diuretic prompts the body to produce and eliminate more urine. This helps in lowering
`
`13
`
`MEDA_APTX03503012
`
`PTX0433-00015
`
`15
`
`

`

`blood pressure. This class of combination drugs are usually not prescribed until therapy is
`
`already underway. The majority of Canadian have some form of coverage for prescription drugs.
`
`In 1995, it is estimated that 88% of Canadian had coverage: 62% were covered under private
`
`plans, 19% under provincial plans, and 7% were covered under both. 11 Provinces subsidize
`
`the cost of prescription drugs for at least some sectors of the population, most notably seniors
`
`and social assistance recipients. Patented drug prices are regulated in Canada by the Patented
`
`Medicine Prices Review Board (PMPRB). There are two components to this price regulation.
`
`One is the limit on increases of patented drugs already on the market; the other is the limit on
`
`introductory prices of new patented drugs. According to PMPRB guidelines, the prices of most
`
`new drugs may not exceed the maximum price of other drugs that treat the same disease.
`
`4.2 Overview of the Data
`
`Data sources for this study come from IMS Canada, a firm specializes in collecting sales and
`
`detailing data for the Canadian pharmaceutical industry. The revenue data is drawn f

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket