throbber
Chapter 28
`
`THE ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF ADVERTISING
`
`KYLE BAGWELL
`
`Columbia University
`
`Contents
`
`Abstract
`Keywords
`1. Introduction
`2. Views on advertising
`2. I. Setting the stage
`2.2. The persuasive view
`2.3. The informative view
`2.4. The complementary view
`2.5. Summary
`2.5.1. Combative advertising
`2.5.2. Persuasion and consumption distortions
`2.5.3. Joint supply
`2.5.4. Brand loyalty, advertising scale economies and market power
`3. Empirical regularities
`3.1. The direct effects of advertis.ing
`3.1.1. Sales
`:'1.1.2. Brand loyalty and market-share stabi lity
`3.1. 3. Advertising scale economies
`3.2. The indirect effects of advertising
`3.2.1. Concentration
`3.2.2. Profit
`3.2.3. Entry
`3.2.4. Price
`3.2.5. Quality
`3.3. Summary
`4. Monopoly advertising
`4.1 . The positive theory of monopoly advertising
`4. l. l. The Dorfman-Steiner model
`
`Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume 3
`Edited by M. Armstrong and R. Porter
`© 2007 Elsevier B. V. All rights reserved
`DOl: 10.1016/Sl573-448X(06)03028-7
`
`1703
`1703
`1704
`1708
`1708
`1710
`1716
`1720
`1723
`1724
`1724
`1724
`1724
`1725
`1726
`1726
`1729
`1731
`1734
`1734
`1737
`1741
`1743
`1746
`1748
`1749
`1749
`1749
`
`PLAINTIFFS'
`TRIAL EXHIBIT
`PTX0432
`
`MEDA APTX03504410
`
`PTX0432-00001
`
`1
`
`CIP2096
`Argentum Pharmaceuticals LLC v. Cipla Ltd.
`IPR2017-00807
`
`

`

`1702
`
`K. Bagwell
`
`4. 1.2. Two examples
`
`4.2. The normative theory of monopoly advertising
`
`4.2. l. The persuasive view
`
`4.2.2. An al.ternative approach
`
`4.2.3. Price-maintaining and price-decreasing monopoly advcnis.ing
`
`4.2.4. Price-increasing mo nopoly advertising
`
`4.3. Summary
`5. Advertising and price
`5.1. Homogeneous products
`
`5.2. Differentiated products
`
`5.3. Non-price advertising
`
`5.4. Loss leaders
`
`5.5. Summary
`6. Advertising and quality
`6. I. Signaling-efficiency effect
`6.2. Repeat-business effect
`
`6.3. Match-products-to-buyers effect
`
`6.4. Quality-guarantee effect
`
`6.5. Summary
`7. Adverti sing and entry deterrence
`7.1. Advertising and goodwill
`
`7.2. Advertising and signaling
`
`7.3 . Surnnmry
`8. Empirical analyses
`8.1. Advertising and the household
`
`8.2. Advertisi ng and firm conduct
`
`8.3. Summary
`9. Sunk costs and market structure
`9.1. Main ideas
`
`9.2. Econometric tests and industry histories
`
`9.3. Related work
`
`9 .4. Summary
`I 0. New directions and other topics
`1 0.1. Advertising and media markets
`
`I 0.2. Advertising, behavioral economics and neuroeconomics
`
`1 0.3. Other topics
`
`10.4. Summary
`II. Conclusion
`Acknowledgements
`References
`
`1751
`1753
`1753
`1756
`1757
`1758
`1761
`1762
`1762
`1766
`1769
`1772
`1773
`1774
`1774
`1779
`1783
`1786
`179 1
`1792
`1792
`1798
`1802
`1803
`1803
`1808
`1813
`1813
`1814
`1818
`1819
`1821
`1821
`1821
`1825
`1827
`1828
`1828
`1829
`1829
`
`MEDA APTX03504411
`
`PTX0432-00002
`
`2
`
`

`

`Ch. 28: The Economic Analysis of Advertising
`
`1703
`
`Abstract
`
`This chapter offers a comprehensive survey of the economic analysis of advertising.
`A first objective is to organize the literature in a manner that clarifies what is known.
`A second objective is to clarify how this knowledge has been obtained. The chap(cid:173)
`ter begins with a discussion of the key initial writings that are associated with the
`persuasive, informative and complementary views of advertising. Next, work that char(cid:173)
`acterizes empirical regularities between advertising and other variables is considered.
`Much of this work is conducted at the inter-industry level but important industry stud(cid:173)
`ies are also discussed . The chapter then offers several sections that summarize formal
`economic theories of advertising. In particular, respective sections are devoted to pos(cid:173)
`itive and normative theories of monopoly advertising, theories of price and non-price
`advertising, theories of advertising and product quality, and theories that explore the
`potential role for advertising in deterring entry. At this point, the chapter considers the
`empirical support for the formal economic theories of advertising. A summary is pro(cid:173)
`vided of empirical work that evaluates the predictions of recent theories of advertising,
`including work that specifies and estimates explicitly structural models of firm and con(cid:173)
`sumer conduct. This work is characterized by the use of industry (or brand) and even
`household-level data. The chapter then considers work on endogenous and exogenous
`sunk cost industries. At a methodological level, this work is integrative in nature: it
`develops new theory that delivers a few robust predictions, and it then explores the em(cid:173)
`pirical relevance of these predictions at both inter-industry and industry levels. Finally,
`the chapter considers new directions and other topics. Here, recent work on advertising
`and media markets is discussed, and research on behavioral economics and neuroeco(cid:173)
`nomi cs is also featured. A final section offers some concluding thoughts.
`
`Keywords
`
`Advertising, Survey, Theory, Empirical analysis
`
`JEL classification: M300, LlOO, D800
`
`MEDA APTX03504412
`
`PTX0432-00003
`
`3
`
`

`

`1704
`
`K. Bagwell
`
`"What makes the advertising issue fascinating . . . is that it is fundamentally an issue in how to establish
`truth in economics." (Phill ip Nelson, l974a)
`
`1. Introduction
`
`By its very nature, advertising is a prominent feature of economic life. Advertising
`reaches consumers through their TV sets, radios, newspapers, magazines, mailboxes,
`computers and more. Not surprisingly, the associated advertising expenditures can be
`huge. For example, Advertising Age (2005) reports that, in 2003 in the U.S., General
`Motors spent $3.43 bi11ion to advertise its cars and trucks; Procter and Gamble devoted
`$3.32 billion to the advertisement of its detergents and cosmetics; and Pfizer incurred a
`$2.84 billion advertising expense for its drugs. Advertising is big business indeed.
`From the current perspective, it is thus surprising to learn that the major economists
`of the 19th century and before paid little attention to advertising. The economic analy(cid:173)
`sis of advertising is almost entirely a 20th-century project. Why did not 19th-century
`economists analyze advertising? Two reasons stand out.
`First, 19th-century economic research is devoted largely to the development of the
`theory of perfect competition, and this theory does not immediately suggest a role for
`advertising. As Pigou (1924, pp. 173-174) remarks, "Under simple competition there
`is no purpose in this advertisement, because, ex hypothesi, the market will take, at the
`market price, as much as any one small seller wants to sell". Of course, whether a firm
`is competitive (i.e., price-taking) or not, it might advertise if it were thereby able to
`shift its demand curve upward so that a higher price could be obtained. But here a more
`basic problem arises: under the conventional assumptions that consumers have fixed
`preferences over products and perfect information with regard to prices and qualities,
`there is no reason for consumers to respond to advertising, and so the posited demand
`shift is unjustified. 1
`Second, while advertising has long been used by merchants, its transition to "big
`business" is more modern . In the late 19th and early 20th centuries, following signif(cid:173)
`icant advances in transportation (railroads) and communication (telegraph) networks,
`manufacturers were motivated to pursue innovations in the machinery of production
`and distribution, so that economies of scale could be reaped. These economies, how(cid:173)
`ever, could be achieved only if demand were appropriately stimulated. The turn-of(cid:173)
`the-century technological innovations that are associated with mass production and
`
`1 As Braithwaite (l928, p. 28) explains: "Under conditions of perfect competition producers would gain
`nothing by spendi ng money on advertisement, for those conditions assume two things - (1) that the demand
`curve is fixed and cannot be altered directly by producers, and (2) that since producers can sell all that they
`can produce at the market price, none of them could produce (at a given moment) more at that price than they
`are already doing".
`
`MEDA APTX03504413
`
`PTX0432-00004
`
`4
`
`

`

`Ch. 28: The Economic Analysis of Advertising
`
`1705
`
`distribution thus gave significant encouragement to large-scale brand advertising and
`mass marketing activities. 2
`At the beginning of the 20th century, advertising was thus a ripe topic for economic
`research. The economic analysis of advertising begins with MarshalJ (1890, 1919),
`who offers some insightful distinctions, and then gathers momentum with Chamber(cid:173)
`lin's (1933) integration of selling costs into economic theory. Over the second half of
`the century, the economic analysis of advertising has advanced at a furious pace. Now,
`following the close of the 20th century, a substantial literature has emerged. My purpose
`here is to survey this literature.
`In so doing, I hope to accomplish two objectives. A first objective is to organize the
`literature in a manner that clarifies what is known.3 Of course, it is impossible to sum(cid:173)
`marize all of the economic studies of advertising. Following a century of work, though,
`this seems a good time to bring to the surface the more essential contributions and take
`inventory of what is known. Second, I hope to clarify how this knowledge has been
`obtained. The economic implications of advertising are of undeniable importance; how(cid:173)
`ever, the true nature of these implications has yielded but slowly to economic analysis.
`There is a blessing in this. With every theoretical and empirical methodological inno(cid:173)
`vation in industrial organization, economists have turned to important and unresolved
`issues in advertising, demonstrating the improvements that their new approach offers.
`Advertising therefore offers a resilient set of issues against which to chart the progress
`gained as industrial organization methods have evolved.
`It is helpful to begin with a basic question: Why do consumers respond to advertising?
`An economic theory of advertising can proceed only after this question is confronted.
`As economists have struggled with this question, three views have emerged, with each
`view in turn being associated with distinct positive and normative implications.
`The first view is that advertising is persuasive. This is the dominant view expressed
`in economic writings in the first half of the 20th century. The persuasive view holds that
`advertising alters consumers' tastes and creates spurious product differentiation and
`brand loyalty. As a consequence, the demand for a firm's product becomes more inelas(cid:173)
`tic, and so advertising results in higher prices. In addition, advertising by established
`firms may give rise to a barrier to entry, which is naturally more severe when there are
`economies of scale in production and/or advertising. The persuasive approach therefore
`suggests that advertising can have important anti-competitive effects, as it has no "real"
`
`2 The emergence of large-scale advertising is also attributable to income growth, printing and literacy ad(cid:173)
`vances, and urbanization. See also Borden (1942), Chandler (1990), Harris and Seldon (1962), Pope (1983),
`Simon (1970) and Wood (1958).
`3 Surprisingly, there does not appear to exist another contemporary and comprehensive survey of the eco(cid:173)
`nomic analysis of advertising. Various portions of the literature are treated in other work. For example,
`Ekelund and Saurman (1 988) offer an interesting discuss.ion of early views on advertising by economists,
`and Cornanor and Wilson (1979) and Schrnalensee (1972) prov ide valuable surveys of early empirical analy(cid:173)
`ses. Tirole ( 1988) discusses in detail a few of the recent theories of advertising. Finally, in Volumes 1 and 2
`of the Handbook of Industrial Organization, Schmalcnscc (1989) provides further discussion of empirical
`findings, while Stiglitz ( 1989) offers some brief rcilcctions on the theory of advertising.
`
`MEDA APTX03504414
`
`PTX0432-00005
`
`5
`
`

`

`1706
`
`K. Bagwell
`
`value to consumers, but rather induces artificial product differentiation and results in
`concentrated markets characterized by high prices and profits.
`The second view is that advertising is informative. This view emerged in force in
`the 1960s, under the leadership of the Chicago SchooL According to this approach,
`many markets are characterized by imperfect consumer information, since search costs
`may deter a consumer from learning of each product's existence, price and quality. This
`imperfection can lead to market inefficiencies, but advertising is not the cause of the
`problem. Instead, advertising is the endogenous response that the market offers as a so(cid:173)
`lution. When a firm advertises, consumers receive at low cost addi tional direct (prices,
`location) and/or indirect (the firm is willing to spend on advertising) information. The
`firm's demand curve becomes more elastic, and advertising thus promotes competition
`among established firms . As well, advertising can faci litate entry, as it provides a means
`though which a new entrant can publicize its existence, prices and products. The sug(cid:173)
`gestion here, then, is that advertising can have important pro-competitive effects.
`A third view is that advertising is complementary to the advertised product. Accord(cid:173)
`ing to this perspective, advertising does not change consumers' preferences, as in the
`persuasive view; furthermore, it may, but need not, provide information. Instead, it is
`assumed that consumers possess a stable set of preferences into which advertising en(cid:173)
`ters directly in a fashion that is complementary with the consumption of the advertised
`product. For example, consumers may value "social prestige", and the consumption of
`a product may generate greater prestige when the product is (appropriately) advertised.
`An important implication is that standard methods may be used to investigate whether
`advertising is supplied to a socially optimal degree, even if advertising conveys no in(cid:173)
`formation.
`These views are all, at some level, plausible. But they have dramatically different pos(cid:173)
`itive and normative implications. The persuasive and informative views, in particular,
`offer conflicting assessments of the social value of advertisi ng. It is of special impor(cid:173)
`tance, therefore, to subject these views to ri gorous empirical and theoretical eval uation.
`Over the past fifty years, the economic analysis of advertising, like the field of industrial
`organization itself, can be described in terms of a sequence of empirical, theoretical and
`again empirical evaluative phases.
`The empirical analysis of advertising was at center stage from the 1950s through the
`I 970s. Over this period, a voluminous literature investigated general empirical relation(cid:173)
`ships between advertising and a host of other variables, including concentration, profit,
`entry and price. Much of this work employs regression methods and uses inter-industry
`data, but important studies are also conducted at the industry, firm and even brand levels.
`This period is marked by vigorous and mostly edifying debates between advocates of
`the persuasive and informative views. The debates center on both the robustness and the
`interpretation of empirical findings, and they identify some of the limitations of regres(cid:173)
`sion analyses, particularly at the inter-industry level. While the inter-industry analyses
`are often inconclusive, defe nsible empirical patterns emerge within particular industries
`or narrow industry categories. The evidence strongly suggests that no single view of
`advertising is valid in ail settings.
`
`MEDA APTX03504415
`
`PTX0432-00006
`
`6
`
`

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket