throbber
Working Paper Number 61
`June 2005
`
`Patents, Price Controls and Access to New Drugs:
`How Policy Affects Global Market Entry
`By Jean O. Lanjouw
`
`Abstract
`
`We consider how patent rights and price regulation affect whether new drugs are
`marketed in a country, and how quickly. The analysis covers a large sample of 68
`countries at all income levels and includes all drug launches over the period 1982-2002.
`It uses newly compiled information on legal and regulatory policy, and is the first
`systematic analysis of the determinants of drug launch in poor countries. Price control
`tends to discourage rapid product entry, while the results for patents are mixed. There is
`evidence that local capacity to innovate matters and that international pricing externalities
`may play a role.
`
`Exhibit 1138
`IPR2017-00807
`ARGENTUM
`
`000001
`
`

`

`
`
`Patents, Price Controls and Access to New Drugs:
`How Policy Affects Global Market Entry1
`Jean O. Lanjouw
`
`April 19, 2005
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Abstract
`
`
`We consider how patent rights and price regulation affect whether new drugs are marketed in a
`country, and how quickly. The analysis covers a large sample of 68 countries at all income levels
`and includes all drug launches over the period 1982-2002. It uses newly compiled information on
`legal and regulatory policy, and is the first systematic analysis of the determinants of drug launch
`in poor countries. Price control tends to discourage rapid product entry, while the results for
`patents are mixed. There is evidence that local capacity to innovate matters and that international
`pricing externalities may play a role.
`
`
`
`
`1 The author is an Associate Professor, Agricultural and Natural Resources Department, University of California
`at Berkeley, and a Non-Resident Senior Fellow at the Center for Global Development and the Brookings
`Institution. This paper was prepared for the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, Innovation, and Public
`Health of the World Health Organization. Daniel Egel and Margaret MacLeod, the Brookings Institution, and
`Rachel Menezes, the Center for Global Development, provided superb research assistance. Early work was done
`while I was resident at those institutions and I appreciate their encouragement. I thank Bronwyn Hall, Peter
`Lanjouw, Mark Schankerman, John Strauss and Brian Wright for their useful suggestions, as well as seminar
`participants at U.C. Berkeley, Stanford, Yale, the University of Arizona and the World Bank. The World Bank
`and the Brookings Institution provided funding for the purchase of data used in this project.
`
`2
`
`000002
`
`

`

`I. Introduction
`The pharmaceutical industry faces a rapidly evolving legal and regulatory environment.
`Governments, drug companies and advocacy groups continue to engage in a decade-long battle over
`the type of patent rights that will be available to industry, particularly in poor countries. Particular
`criticism has focused on the intellectual property standards required of members of the World Trade
`Organization—standards known as Trade-Related aspects of Intellectual Property, or TRIPS, rules.
`International drug pricing is also coming under the spotlight. Americans have accused the Europeans
`and Canadians of using their price control systems to free-ride on U.S. consumers, and the United
`States is starting to push for regulatory changes in bilateral trade negotiations.2 These pressures may
`well generate future reforms on a broad scale.
`The choices made by each country about its patent system and price regulation will have many
`ramifications – influencing the size of future investment in medical research, the availability of the
`resulting therapies, how the financial burdens are distributed across countries, and finally the health of
`consumers. We focus here on how policy choices affect whether new drugs are marketed in a
`country, and how quickly. Because there are fixed costs associated with launching new products, it
`would seem intuitive that both weaker price regulation and stronger intellectual property would
`facilitate entry by virtue of increasing firm profit.3 However, what makes this an interesting economic
`problem is that intellectual property can have a second important effect. While patents indeed make
`local markets more attractive, they also convey control over launch decisions to multinational firms
`with global interests.4 Multinationals may delay or even avoid launching drugs in lower-priced
`countries because they are concerned about the implications for pricing in other markets. If they
`hesitate, and patent rights block otherwise willing local entrants, then strong patent rights may actually
`reduce product entry.
`
`
`2 See, for example, the speech by Mark McClellen, then Commissioner of the U.S. FDA, before the First
`International Colloquium on Generic Medicine. September 25, 2003, Cancun, Mexico. Available at
`http://www.fda.gov/oc/speeches/2003/genericdrug0925.html (accessed 12/28/03). Most recently, the U.S.
`insisted that reforms to Australia’s domestic price and reimbursement system be a part of the AUS Free Trade
`Agreement (see www.aph.gov.au/Senate/committee/freetrade_ctte for details and discussion. Accessed
`1/24/05). Suggesting a future agenda, see “Ten Questions,” Pfizer Annual Review 2004: “We believe
`Americans carry an unfair share of the global cost of biomedical research. We think that’s a serious issue that
`should be near the top of the global trade agenda.”
`3 Local fixed costs include obtaining marketing approval from the country regulatory authority and educating
`doctors and patient groups about the drug’s benefits. These costs can be sizeable, particularly for the first entrant.
`4 While in principle smaller local firms could develop new drugs, in fact multinationals hold almost all product
`patents. Some 86% of the applications for product patents in India in 1995 were submitted by inventors with a
`non-Indian address (CDRI, 1996) and in most developing countries the share is far higher. As firms based in
`developing countries also begin to invest in the development and patenting of new products they will have the
`same global marketing incentives and constraints faced by the current multinationals.
`
`
`
`3
`
`000003
`
`

`

`Although the pricing of patented pharmaceuticals has attracted a great deal of attention
`recently, the question of whether new drugs are marketed at all, remarkably, has not.5 This is
`significant given that less than one-half of the new pharmaceutical molecules marketed
`worldwide are sold in any given country – whether rich or poor. Even those drugs that are
`eventually marketed in one country frequently appear on pharmacy shelves only six or seven
`years after becoming available to consumers elsewhere.6 Both price regulation and intellectual
`property rights influence these outcomes. The CEO of Pfizer, Hank McKinnell, frankly
`acknowledged this point some years ago when he threatened that the company would withhold
`new treatments from France unless the government allowed higher drug prices (Financial
`Times, December 10, 2001).
`When considering the effect of patent rights it is important to distinguish two main
`types: those that protect of methods of manufacture (“process patents”) and those that protect
`pharmaceutical products (“product patents”).7 Process patents are relatively weak. While one
`firm’s patents on methods for producing a molecule might give it a monopoly for a time, a
`second firm can legally devise (and patent) a new method and come into the market. Indeed,
`countries have purposefully chosen a “process-only” patent regime for pharmaceutical
`innovations in order to foster a domestic industry based on inventing around originators’
`manufacturing processes.8 Although relatively weak, process patents may nevertheless
`encourage product entry by slowing down the arrival of competitors, allowing firms to cover
`fixed entry costs.
`The ambiguity arises with product patents because these concentrate control in the hands
`of a single innovating firm. In the debate preceding the TRIPS Agreement it was argued that
`countries refusing to grant product patents were failing to get many newer drugs precisely
`because of the threat of follow-on imitative competition. If innovator firms could be assured of a
`local monopoly, it was suggested, they would find it attractive to launch more products. In the
`presence of externalities, however, this argument is no longer obvious.
`
`
`5 Although when Gilead Sciences recently offered to expand to 95 the number of countries eligible to receive its
`key anti-retroviral drug “at cost”, the offer was called “disingenuous” by the NGO Doctors without Borders
`because the firm has been supplying only 22 of the original 68 eligible countries. San Francisco Chronicle,
`March 18, 2005.
`6 A “drug” refers to a chemical entity in any of its presentations – e.g. tablets, capsules, liquid.
`7 Some countries also give additional protection to new formulations and new uses of existing products.
`8 India’s rejection of its adopted colonial British patent code in 1972 in favor of a system allowing only short (5-
`7 year) process patents for drugs provides an example. With only process patents available, the multinational
`subsidiary Glaxo India faced several local competitors from the first day that it marketed its blockbuster drug
`ranitadine (Zantac); while Cipla was manufacturing a version of the Pfizer drug Viagra shortly after the drug’s
`global launch (Wall Street Journal, July 10, 1998).
`
`
`
`4
`
`000004
`
`

`

`Several mechanisms can generate international pricing externalities. Some developed country
`price regulators explicitly use cross-country comparisons to establish ceiling prices. U.K. drug
`prices, for example, are used as an international reference by regulators in Austria, Canada,
`Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands and Portugal (Bloom and van Reneen, 1998; see
`also Jacobzone 2000). Physical arbitrage across country borders can also erode prices in higher-
`priced markets. Arbitrage is legal among E.U. member countries, which pushes prices in the
`direction of uniformity although it has not resulted in a single price across markets (Kanavos, et.
`al., 2004; Ganslandt and Maskus, 2004). Arbitrage between most countries is illegal.
`Nevertheless there are concerns about black market movements, with occasional high-profile
`stories involving developing countries and a soaring trade between the U.S. and Canada.9
`
`The behavior of political interest groups can also push prices toward uniformity. Consumers
`forcefully object to paying prices that are higher than those they see being charged to consumers
`elsewhere, giving firms and their regulators reason to fear a political backlash if obviously
`different prices are in place. A growing literature examines how firms may distort behavior to
`avoid the imposition of regulation or soften its effect. Glazer and McMillan (1990), for example,
`model pricing by a monopolist where the firm may choose to forestall regulation by setting a price
`closer to that desired by the regulator. Erfle and McMillan (1990) find that oil firms limited their
`price increases during the 1979 oil crisis. Price restraint was more pronounced on more visible
`fuels like home heating oil and more likely among large and visible firms. Ellison and Wolfram
`(2004) show that pharmaceutical firms acted collectively to limit price increases during a period of
`intensive political discussion of health care reform in the U.S. Firms identified as particularly
`vulnerable to regulation were more likely to engage in price restraint and lobbying. Examining the
`stock prices of credit card firms, Stango (2003) finds that announced rate cuts were less damaging
`to returns when the announcements followed a regulatory threat. Again this result was more
`pronounced for politically visible firms.10
`
`Identifying the precise mechanisms generating pricing externalities across markets is not the goal
`of this paper. Rather, the concern here is whether product patents can reduce access to new drugs
`by making firms that care about externalities – whatever the source – more important players.
`
`
`9 For example, “HIV Drugs For Africa Diverted to Europe,” The Washington Post, October, 2002; “Europeans
`Investigate Resale of AIDS Drugs,” New York Times, October 29, 2002.
`10 Behavior beyond pricing may also be affected. For example Maxwell, Lyon, and Hackett (2000) examine
`firm efforts to deter consumer mobilization, and thereby government-imposed regulation, by voluntarily limiting
`their pollution output.
`
`
`
`5
`
`000005
`
`

`

`Whether access is, in fact, limited is also a key question for interpreting the welfare implication of
`firms’ inability to fully price discriminate across countries.11
`
`Two examples of firm behavior in this environment are instructive. In the late 1980s, Bayer chose
`not to introduce its new antibiotic ciprofloxacin in India. To do so it would have needed to price
`the product very low to be competitive in that market, at a time when the firm was negotiating
`prices in its more important markets. Instead, ciprofloxacin was introduced in India three years
`after its world launch by the Indian firm Ranbaxy. However, eight years after the drug’s global
`launch and long after the entrance of a multitude of local producers, Bayer finally entered the
`Indian market (interview with Bayer executive, India, 1997). More recently, GlaxoSmithKline
`and Pfizer have cut back supplies of their products to Canada to prevent drugs from leaving for the
`United States – where they damage the higher prices that the firms enjoy in that country.12 In
`both of these situations the multinationals found it profitable to engage in a local market at a low
`price. Their reluctance to do so clearly stemmed from the potential implications for their profits in
`other markets. What is particularly notable in the story of ciprofloxacin is the further suggestion
`that pricing externalities may become less acute later in the product lifecycle.13
`
`Given the considerations raised here, one would expect to see three types of entry into
`poorer country markets. Firms interested in producing only for the local or regional market
`should be willing to enter at any time, assuming that expected returns in the local market at least
`cover the fixed costs of entry. Multinationals might enter poorer markets quickly in situations
`where they can set a price that is close to their target price in the major markets. Sales would
`then be limited to the local elite. Finally, one might see multinationals waiting for some time
`after the global launch of a new product, and then entering developing country markets with a
`low price that allowed them to capture market share. Which of these strategies are feasible and
`likely will be influenced by price regulation and the intellectual property regime.
`To date there has been little analysis of the determinants of international drug launches.
`Danzon, Wang and Wang (2005) examine launch data from 25 major markets for the years 1994-1998,
`and a selected sample of 85 new chemical entities (NCE). They are specifically concerned with the
`
`
`11 Maleug and Schwartz (1994) show that uniform pricing by a monopolist yields lower global welfare than
`third-degree price discrimination when demand dispersion is such that many markets are left unserved under
`uniform pricing. See also Scherer and Watal (2002). This result is accentuated if one allows for global
`equity concerns and differences in the marginal utility of income across consumers (See Jack and Lanjouw,
`2005, where they apply many-person Ramsey pricing to the problem of global pharmaceutical pricing.)
`12 Wall Street Journal, January 22, 2003; “Pfizer Cuts Supplies to Canadian Drugstores,” The Washington Post,
`April 5, 2005.
`13 One candidate explanation is the fact that controlled prices set in high-income countries in the early entry
`years are typically not renegotiated over time (Jacobzone, 2000).
`
`
`
`6
`
`000006
`
`

`

`effects of price regulation. Rather than summarizing differences in price control systems directly, they
`use the price for a standard unit in a drug’s therapy class in an earlier year as indicator of the intensity
`of regulation. A similar variable is constructed for expected market size. Both higher prices and larger
`markets are found to have a significantly positive effect on the likelihood and speed of launch.
`Kyle (2004a and 2004b) analyzes 21 OECD countries and much larger set of drug launches,
`including 1577 molecules developed during the period 1980-2002. She focuses primarily on how firm
`characteristics affect launch timing and finds, for example, that domestic firms have a 5 times higher
`probability of launching at home (with domestic status most important in Japan and Italy). A dummy
`for price regulation has a significantly negative effect and she finds that firms are less likely to follow
`launch in a low-price country with launch in a high-price country.
`
`None of these papers consider intellectual property (IP) as a determinant of marketing
`decisions. McCalman (2004) provides an econometric analysis of how intellectual property might
`influence launch decisions – of American Hollywood movies. His data are from 1997-99 covering 37
`countries, and he estimates hazard models for the effect of IP strength on the speed of film launches
`across countries. He finds a non-monotonic relationship with moderate IP associated with the most
`rapid diffusion. There is, in his context however, no scope for pricing spillovers across countries.
`
`This paper analyzes launch patterns across a very large sample of 68 countries over the period
`1982-2002. The paper provides descriptive statistics; and probit and hazard analyses of the likelihood
`and speed of launch. Explanatory variables include those related to the attractiveness of markets and
`local technical capacity. Those of primary interest are newly constructed policy variables for the
`availability and strength of patent protection and the stringency of price control. This is the first
`analysis of pharmaceutical launch patterns that includes developing countries. Their experience is of
`independent interest and provides more variation in the policy variables than is found among OECD
`members.
`II.
`The Drug Launch Data
`The launch data are drawn primarily from the December 2002 “LifeCycle: Drug Launches”
`database constructed by the private vendor IMS Health. The database identifies the month and year
`that a product first has retail sales in a given country, and indicates which entries represent first world
`launches of new chemical entities (NCE).14 For each product launched, it gives the tradename, the
`Anatomical Therapeutic Classification (ATC) code, active ingredient, composition, and firm making
`the launch. Coverage includes entry during the 21 years 1982-2002 in the retail sector and, for some
`countries, the hospital sector also. The Indian market was not covered by IMS during this period so
`
`14 In some cases the same chemical was indicated as being ‘new’ more than once, or was identified as ‘new’ at a
`country launch later than the first launch in the world. In these cases the first appearance is taken as the global
`launch date.
`
`
`
`7
`
`000007
`
`

`

`we incorporate similar information obtained from the Indian market research company, ORG-MARG.
`The Indian data cover a partial, but broad, set of therapeutic classes – including launches of all
`antibiotics, ulcer and cancer drugs – and includes all products in those classes launched in the Indian
`market during the period 1986-98. The combined dataset covers 68 countries or country groups, 60%
`of which have at least twenty years of information.15 Further details regarding data construction are
`available in Lanjouw (2005).
`
`III.
`Description of Global Launch Patterns
`Table 1 gives the number of NCE’s with a first appearance (global launch date) in each
`year. The first column indicates the number of new “blockbusters”. These are drugs that
`were found among the top 200 in terms of world revenue in 1998 or 2003, or among the top
`100 U.S. revenue earners in 1995 and 1993 (Med Ad News, various issues). The second
`column includes all drugs. There was an increase in the number of new chemical entities
`launched in the mid-1980’s, with some fall off in the numbers in the early 2000’s (perhaps
`due in part to data processing delays). On the whole, however, the number of NCE’s
`appearing each year was fairly similar over the period.
`There were 836 new pharmaceuticals first marketed during the period 1982 – 2002. Table 2
`indicates the location of these first launches. The table includes countries having at least one first
`launch, ordered by income class.16 Two points stand out. First, firms almost invariably launch
`products first in rich country markets. Second, a very large share of all drugs is launched first in Japan
`(and only there – see below).
`Figure 1 gives an idea of the number of countries that an NCE typically reaches. It is based
`only on the 300 NCEs with global launch dates early in the period (1982-1988) to avoid truncation.
`We see that just a very few drugs from that time period were launched worldwide. The mean number
`of countries is 20, the median is 9, and almost 20% of new drugs are marketed in just a single country.
`Of the 54 single-market drugs represented in this figure, 23 were sold only in Japan, 13 only in Italy,
`with the rest scattered across countries. Japan is clearly distinctive – it is the location of 24% of all
`drug launches, but 43% of those marketed in a single country. From 1995 there was a marked
`increase in the number of countries reached within a short span after global launch, so it is likely that
`today the distribution shown in Figure 1 has shifted rightward.
`Table 3 indicates how long it takes for a drug to become available to a country’s consumers.
`Calculations in this table are restricted to the 122 NCEs first launched 1986-92 and assigned to therapy
`classes for which the Indian data are available. There is some truncation for drugs entering after a
`
`15 French West Africa (Benin, Cameroon, Congo, Cote d’Ivoire, Gabon, Guinea, Senegal) and Central America
`(Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatamala, Honduras, Panama) are aggregated by IMS because they are very small
`markets.
`16 The income classes follow those in the World Bank 2002 World Development Indicators Report. The ranges
`for GNI per capita measured in 1999 U.S. dollars are: Low ≤ $755 < Lower ≤ $2995 < Middle ≤ $9265 < High.
`
`
`
`8
`
`000008
`
`

`

`long delay because the data end at 2002, but each NCE has at least 120 months of information. It is
`evident that lags tend to lengthen as one goes down the income rankings. The group summary at the
`bottom of the table shows that differences are most pronounced between the high-income countries
`and the rest.17 However, there is also clearly a great deal of variation across individual countries:
`median launch lags range from months (Japan, Switzerland) to over eight years (Latvia, Lebanon).
`There is also considerable variation across products within countries: For example, the difference
`between the 10th and 90th percentile of the lag distribution is over 10 years in Morocco and Peru and
`over 7 years in some of the OECD countries.
`To avoid differing degrees of truncation across years, Table 4 restricts attention to launches
`that occur within 10 years of the first global launch of each NCE. The ten-year span includes most
`market entry, as shown in the previous table. Table 4 includes the 91 “blockbuster” and 462 total
`drugs in all therapy classes first launched during 1982-92 (so India is dropped). The first column, on
`the left side of the table gives the percentage of all drugs that was eventually launched in the row
`country at any point within a ten-year lag. The second column gives the percentage of blockbusters
`eventually launched in each country.
`Considering the first column, the percentage of drugs launched within a ten year lag
`ranges from lows of 19% and 22% (Egypt, Malaysia) to highs of 49% and 53% (Italy, Japan).
`Thus, no consumers anywhere have access to more than about one-half of the new
`pharmaceuticals that enter the world market. The mean (unweighted) percentage is 34.8% for
`the high-income countries, and 29.9% and 28.4% for the middle- and low-income countries,
`respectively. As expected, “blockbuster” drugs that experience high sales revenues in the
`developed world are also launched more frequently in the poorer countries than drugs overall,
`although in no country is the rate for even this more select group close to 100%. The fact that
`drugs are not launched more widely can be due to the availability of substitutes, differences in
`disease patterns across countries, and rejection by some local regulatory authorities.
`The remaining columns of Table 4 give the cumulative distribution of drug launches at
`different lags from one year to nine years. Thus the column headed “3” indicates the percentage of all
`NCE launched within ten years in a given row country that arrived in that market within three years.
`Countries are listed by income group and, looking down this column, we again see that drugs are more
`likely to be launched within three years in the richer countries than in the poorer countries. This is
`highlighted in Figure 2, which shows unweighted averages for each income group. However, the
`pattern is not strong. Israel, at 27%, for example, has a smaller share on the market this quickly than
`either the Philippines or Thailand (44% and 41% respectively). Again we see the large range of
`experience overall. Germany has 75% of its drugs on the market within three years of the global
`launch, Saudi Arabia just 16%.
`
`
`17 The difference for high income countries is not driven by the fact that Japan has a large number of unique
`drugs. Dropping Japan lowers the average number of drugs to 40 and increases the median lag to 28 months.
`
`
`
`9
`
`000009
`
`

`

`IV.
`
`Most global market entry is done by the “first” firm, defined as the firm that makes the first
`
`global launch of an NCE in a high-income country, or any country for the few NCE launched
`exclusively in the poorer countries. This firm almost surely holds most of the patents associated with
`an NCE and is typically a multinational. A smaller share is done by “other” firms – which may in
`many cases be entry done under license as part of a marketing arrangement and thus effectively
`controlled by the first firm (the data do not allow one to distinguish). “Other” firms may also be
`multinationals.
`Shares for the low- and middle-income countries are shown in Table 5, broken down by type
`of patent regime. Moving from left to right, a stronger patent regime is associated with more of the
`drug launch in a country being done by the first firm. Overall, two-thirds of all drug launches and
`three-quarters of blockbuster launches are done by the first firm. These firms are responsible for about
`80% of the new drug launches in the poorer countries that occur within the first 3 years. That these
`firms enter markets more rapidly is also clear in Figure 3, which shows the timing of drug entry in
`high or lower-income countries conditional on launch being done by the “first” or “other” firm.
`
`The Explanatory Variables
`Annual series were constructed to describe each of the main policy areas:
`Intellectual Property Protection: These include indicator variables for the availability of
`patents on innovative methods of manufacture for pharmaceuticals (process patents), and on
`new pharmaceutical compounds (product patents). Historically, countries have offered either
`no protection in the area of pharmaceuticals, process patents only, or both process and product
`patents. The data include the statuary term of each form of protection, and information about
`whether a country allows for an extension to the patent term to compensate for time spent in the
`marketing approvals process.
`How a country interprets and enforces its patent laws clearly affects how meaningful any
`patent “rights” are to their owners. Unfortunately this is a difficult characteristic to capture in
`data. We use one variable, “strong,” falling between 0 and 1, which takes on a higher value as a
`country limits how patent rights can be curtailed. Specifically, it is the average of non-missing
`values for three other 0/1 indicators: the first equals one if a country will not impose compulsory
`licensing until three years after patent grant; the second equals one if the country has no formal
`obligation to “work” a patent (supply the market); and the third equals one if the country does
`not revoke patents for failing to work if there is such a requirement. This variable was devised
`by Walter Park, who provided the data required for its construction for most countries for each
`five years beginning in 1980 (see Ginarte and Park, 1997, for details). For missing countries, his
`
`
`
`10
`
`000010
`
`

`

`data were supplemented assuming current values throughout the period based on the legal texts.
`A similar variable composed of enforcement-related indicators was not found to have any
`explanatory power and therefore was not included in the estimations.
`Price Control: Countries approach the control of pharmaceutical prices in a bewildering
`variety of ways. We consider systems of explicit price regulation and summarize the variation
`across countries with two dummy variables – one for the existence of “some” price control
`regulation and the second for “extensive” price control. A price regime is label “extensive” if all
`drugs are regulated, rather than just a subset of the market, or if a country’s price regulation is
`identified by commentators as being particularly rigorous. The set of reports consulted in
`making this determination, and legal texts sourced for relevant IP law, are given in Lanjouw
`(2005).
`
`The legal and regulatory policies of a country result from some process, and this makes
`endogeneity an obvious concern when trying to understand the effects of any policy regime. In our
`case, one might expect firms to lobby hardest to obtain strong patent protection in countries viewed as
`attractive markets for entry, potentially creating a positive bias in estimated relationships.18 However,
`a consideration of history suggests that substantive within-country changes in the patent law can
`reasonably be treated as exogenous for our purpose – certainly in their timing. Such changes tend to
`be forced by the rules of entry into new political groups (e.g., Portugal and Spain joining the EU in
`1992); by newly negotiated standards created at an international level (e.g., many poor countries and
`TRIPS, Mexico and NAFTA); or a vulnerability to trade pressure and the political dynamic of bilateral
`negotiations (Korea, Brazil, and Jordan in the 1980s and 1990s). (See Sell, 2003.) The link to the
`dynamic of trade negotiations is reflected in comments by the body that advises the U.S. Congress and
`administration on IPR and trade, the Industry Functional Advisory Committee on IPR for Trade
`Matters (IFAC-3), in its reports to the US Trade Representative:
`
`CAFTA (the Central American Free Trade Agreement) “mirrors, as closely as possible, the
`Singapore and Chile FTAs in order to establish clear precedents in most key areas of
`intellectual property protection for future FTA negotiations.”
`
`And
`
`“IFAC-3 is particularly gratified that….with high-level agreements with both small
`developing countries in the CAFTA and a strong and mature developed country like Australia,
`it will prove much easier to convince future FTA countries that strong intellectual property
`
`
`18 And lobby they do. For a candid discussion see historical issues of the PhRMA annual report.
`
`
`
`11
`
`000011
`
`

`

`protection is in the interests of all countries regardless of their economic circumstances.”
`(Italics mine).19
`Price regulatio

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket