throbber
Authorized Generic Drugs:
`Short-Term Effects and Long-Term Impact
`
`Exhibit 1130
`IPR2017-00807
`ARGENTUM
`
`Federal Trade Commission
`August 2011
`
`000001
`
`

`

`AUTHORIZED GENERIC DRUGS:
`SHORT-TERM EFFECTS AND LONG-TERM IMPACT
`———————
`A REPORT OF THE
`FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
`
`JON LEIBOWITZ
`WILLIAM E. KOVACIC
`J. THOMAS ROSCH
`EDITH RAMIREZ
`JULIE BRILL
`
`Joni Lupovitz
`Eileen Harrington
`Richard Feinstein
`David Vladeck
`Joseph Farrell
`Willard K. Tom
`Randolph W. Tritell
`Jeanne Bumpus
`Susan S. DeSanti
`Cecelia J. Prewett
`Donald S. Clark
`
`Report Drafters and Contributors
`
`Chairman
`Commissioner
`Commissioner
`Commissioner
`Commissioner
`
`Chief of Staff
`Executive Director
`Director, Bureau of Competition
`Director, Bureau of Consumer Protection
`Director, Bureau of Economics
`General Counsel
`Director, Office of International Affairs
`Director, Office of Congressional Relations
`Director, Office of Policy Planning
`Director, Office of Public Affairs
`Secretary of the Commission
`
`Karen A. Goldman, Office of the General Counsel
`William E. Cohen, Deputy General Counsel for Policy Studies, Office of the General Counsel
`Karen L. Grimm, Assistant General Counsel for Policy Studies, Office of the General Counsel
`Christopher N. Bryan, Office of the General Counsel
`Robert A. Nelson, Jr., Formerly Office of the General Counsel
`
`Brett W. Wendling, Bureau of Economics
`David R. Schmidt, Assistant Director, Office of Applied Research and Outreach, Bureau of Economics
`Mark Hertzendorf, Bureau of Economics
`Luke M. Olson, Bureau of Economics
`Hajime Hadeishi, Formerly Bureau of Economics
`Cagatay Koc, Formerly Bureau of Economics
`Gregory J. Kuczura, Formerly Bureau of Economics
`
`Ellen Connelly, Bureau of Competition
`Jamie Towey, Bureau of Competition
`
`Inquiries concerning this report should be directed to:
`William E. Cohen (202) 326-2110 or wcohen@ftc.gov
`David R. Schmidt (202) 326-2781 or dschmidt@ftc.gov
`
`000002
`
`

`

`EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
`
`This Report analyzes the competitive effects of authorized generic drugs (“AGs”).1 AGs
`are pharmaceutical products that are approved as brand-name drugs but marketed as generic
`drugs. AGs do not bear the brand-name or trademark of the brand-name drug or manufacturer,
`but the brand-name and AG products are manufactured to the brand’s specifications. In
`examining competitive effects, the Report looks both at the price and revenue effects of AG
`competition and at the potential long-term impacts on incentives for generics to challenge
`patents on brand-name drugs. The Report also assesses the competitive implications of patent
`litigation settlements in which brand-name companies refrain from offering an AG when the
`generic company agrees to defer its entry (so-called “pay-for-delay settlements”). For more than
`a decade, the Commission has expressed concern about brand-name companies paying generics
`to delay entry. As this Report observes, promises not to compete with generic entrants by
`marketing an AG are a common form of compensation to generics in such arrangements, and the
`competitive effects of such promises should therefore be analyzed in the same manner as other
`forms of consideration paid to generics.
`
`Authorized generics have a unique impact during the first six months of generic
`competition. Under the Hatch-Waxman Amendments, when the first generic (the “first-filer”)
`challenges the brand’s patent, the FDA may not approve any additional generic competitors until
`180 days after the first-filer launches its product.2 During that period, because of the absence of
`competition, both the generic drug price and the first-filer’s revenues are significantly higher
`than they would be when there are additional generic competitors. Congress created this
`exclusivity as an incentive for generic companies to enter as soon as possible by challenging
`invalid patents or patents that are not infringed.
`
`Competition from AGs during the 180-day exclusivity period has the potential to reduce
`both generic drug prices and generic firm revenues. The courts have ruled that 180-day
`exclusivity does not preclude a brand-name company from entering with its own generic because
`it already has approval for its product; therefore, it can sell an AG during that exclusivity
`
`1 The Federal Trade Commission conducted this study at the request of Senators Grassley, Leahy, and
`Rockefeller, as well as at the request of Representative Waxman, all of whom asked the Commission
`to examine the competitive effects of authorized generic drugs. See Letter from Senators Charles
`Grassley, Patrick Leahy, and John Rockefeller to Deborah Platt Majoras, Chairman, Fed. Trade
`Comm’n (May 9, 2005) (infra Appendix A); Letter from Hon. Henry A. Waxman, U.S. House of
`Representatives, to Deborah Platt Majoras, Chairman, Fed. Trade Comm’n (Sept. 13, 2005) (infra
`Appendix B). Then-Commissioner Leibowitz also requested the FTC to study “the competitive
`implications of authorized generics.” Jon Leibowitz, Commissioner, Fed. Trade Comm’n, Health Care
`and the FTC: The Agency as Prosecutor and Policy Wonk, Remarks at the Antitrust in HealthCare
`Conference 9–10 (May 12, 2005), http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/leibowitz/050512healthcare.pdf.
`2 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(b)(iv) (2010). Exclusivity now may be “shared” by two or more applicants
`filing on the same day. See 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv)(I)–(II)(bb) (2010).
`
`000003
`
`

`

`period.3 Brand-name companies now frequently launch an AG to compete with the first-filer.
`
`AGs thus have been the subject of controversy. Brand-name companies that offer AGs
`contend that they are procompetitive – that they make valuable products available to consumers
`at lower prices than those of brand-name products and provide competition that leads to lower
`generic prices overall. Some in the generic drug industry, in contrast, contend that AGs harm
`competition by drawing revenues away from generic firms during the 180-day exclusivity period
`provided for first-filers that challenge a brand-name company’s patents. They caution that this
`reduces the potential reward available to generics that challenge patents, thereby discouraging
`patent challenges that facilitate earlier generic competition and reduce prices for consumers.
`This, the AG critics argue, undermines long-run competition and the goals of the Hatch-Waxman
`Amendments.
`
`As a first step toward shedding light on this controversy, the Commission in June 2009
`issued an interim report that focused on the short-term effects of AGs during the 180-day
`exclusivity period (the “Interim Report”).4 That report presented an initial analysis suggesting
`that “consumers benefit and the healthcare system saves money during the 180-day exclusivity
`period when an AG enters the market, due to the greater discounting that accompanies the added
`competition provided by the AG.”5 The Interim Report, however, also found that “AG entry
`significantly decreases the revenues of a first-filer generic company during its 180-day
`exclusivity period.”6 Apart from a preliminary analysis of the use of AGs in patent litigation
`settlements, the Commission left most questions of long-term effects – including any possible
`impact of AG competition on the calculus of generic entry via patent challenges – for
`exploration in a final report.
`
`This final Report refines the short-term analysis of the Interim Report and expands the
`analysis to consider long-term effects. It combines information obtained by compulsory process
`from more than 100 brand-name and generic manufacturers with price and sales data acquired
`from commercial sources and information gleaned from FDA databases to assess AGs’
`competitive effects. Moreover, it updates and extends the Interim Report’s study of the use of
`AGs as a form of consideration in patent litigation settlement agreements.
`
`The new analysis finds that, depending on model specifications, competition from an
`authorized generic during the 180-day exclusivity period is associated with retail generic prices
`that are 4-8 percent lower and wholesale generic prices that are 7-14 percent lower than prices
`without authorized generic competition. On average, the retail price of a typical generic drug
`during the 180-day exclusivity period is 86 percent of the pre-entry brand price without AG
`
`3 See Teva Pharm. Indus. Ltd. v. Crawford, 410 F.3d 51, 54 (D.C. Cir. 2005).
`4 FED. TRADE COMM’N, AUTHORIZED GENERICS: AN INTERIM REPORT (“Interim Report”) (2009),
`http://www.ftc.gov/os/2009/06/P062105authorizedgenericsreport.pdf.
`Id., Executive Summary, at 2.
`Id.
`
`6
`
`5
`
`-ii-
`
`000004
`
`

`

`competition and 82 percent of the pre-entry brand price when an AG competes. Similarly, the
`average wholesale price of a typical generic drug during exclusivity, which is 80 percent of the
`pre-entry brand wholesale price without an AG, falls to 70 percent of the brand price with AG
`competition. An analysis of authorized generic pricing over the long term provides no evidence
`that AG prices are higher than prices of other generics, allaying concerns that AGs might be less
`aggressive competitors.
`
`The new analysis also confirms the Interim Report’s finding that authorized generics
`have a substantial effect on the revenues of competing, generic firms during the 180-day
`exclusivity period; depending on how the models are specified, they estimate that the presence of
`authorized generic competition reduces the first-filer generic’s revenues by 40 to 52 percent, on
`average. Moreover, the impact of AG competition on first-filer revenues persists outside of
`exclusivity. Revenues of the first-filer generic manufacturer in the 30 months following
`exclusivity are between 53 percent and 62 percent lower when facing an AG.
`
`With regard to long-term incentive effects, the analysis concludes that the reduced
`revenue stemming from authorized generic competition during 180-day exclusivity has not
`affected the generic’s incentives in a way that has measurably reduced the number of patent
`challenges by generic firms. Any disincentive effects would likely be experienced in small
`markets or in situations where the generic had little chance of winning the patent suit anyway.
`The Report examines a variety of evidence to reach these conclusions.
`
`•
`
`Based on economic analysis, revenue lost from authorized generic competition
`would be most likely to affect decisions to challenge patents on products with
`small sales.
`
`"
`
`If a challenger anticipates a 50 percent chance of success, an expectation
`of AG competition could tilt the balance against bringing a patent
`challenge in markets with brand sales between $12 million and $27
`million, a range that accounts for 13 percent of drugs, but given their low
`sales, approximately one percent of total prescription drug expenditures.
`AGs, however, are rarely introduced for these small drugs. For the drugs
`with higher sales that frequently do attract AG competition, AGs may
`conceivably deter only a narrow range of challenges that the generic
`believes it will rarely win, meaning that the challenges are unlikely to
`result in early generic entry even if pursued.7
`
`7 For instance, for a drug with brand sales of $130 million, a generic that does not anticipate AG
`competition will expect a patent challenge to be profitable if it has at least a 4 percent chance of
`winning; with AG competition, that generic would need at least a 10 percent chance of winning to
`expect a patent challenge to be profitable. Under this mode of analysis, the AG might discourage a
`challenge only if the generic thinks the chance of winning is between 4 and 10 percent, i.e., when the
`challenge is unlikely to be successful. For larger drugs, the presence of an AG is critical to the patent-
`challenge decision only when the expected likelihood of success is even less than 10 percent.
`
`-iii-
`
`000005
`
`

`

`•
`
`•
`
`Considerable evidence suggests that brand-name firms launch authorized generics
`to preserve their profits following the onset of generic competition. The
`evidence, however, also reveals that brand-name companies do recognize that
`authorized generics, when launched, reduce the revenues of generic rivals and
`could deter future generic entry.
`
`"
`
`"
`
`Brand-name firm documents frequently note that launching an AG at the
`time of generic entry increases revenue, but they also recognize that
`authorized generic competition reduces generic competitors’ profits and
`could discourage future patent challenges. The documents furnish no
`basis for deeming one rationale more important than the other.
`
`Brand-name firm AG marketing practices are consistent with revenue-
`enhancement following the onset of generic competition and do not
`suggest a sacrifice of overall profits to discourage generic entry. None of
`the econometric estimates provided evidence that brand-name firms
`sacrifice revenues by introducing AGs. Moreover, about two-thirds of the
`AGs studied were launched after 180-day exclusivity had ended or when
`no exclusivity had occurred. This does not preclude a disincentive effect
`for those AGs that were marketed during 180-day exclusivity periods, but
`it does suggest that other explanations for AG marketing should also be
`considered. Furthermore, almost all AGs marketed during exclusivity
`continued to be marketed for an extended period. Again, the pattern
`suggests that AG marketing provides value to brand-name firms distinct
`from any potential disincentive effect from devaluing 180-day exclusivity.
`
`Although none of the generic companies’ internal documents expressly discusses
`authorized generics as a factor in deciding whether to file a particular patent
`challenge or identifies specific instances when the expectation of an authorized
`generic dissuaded the company from challenging a patent,8 some generic
`companies’ internal documents do reflect a general concern that AGs could
`impact the profitability of patent challenges or suggest that AG competition
`requires generic firms to better manage their product selection and litigation
`processes. The document submissions provide no evidence that any firm has
`substantially abandoned its basic patent-challenge business strategy because of
`the proliferation of authorized generics. On the contrary, documents submitted by
`some generic companies question contentions that AGs create significant
`disincentives to patent challenges. Different generic companies have adopted
`different business strategies in the face of AG competition, and those strategies
`
`8 An absence of documents is not necessarily determinative: generic companies simply might not have
`recorded the reasons for a decision to refrain from filing a patent challenge. In reaching its
`conclusions, the Commission considered all the evidence before it; no single category, including the
`documents provided by generic firms, was dispositive.
`
`-iv-
`
`000006
`
`

`

`appear to reflect how they view AGs and their potential long-term impact.
`
`•
`
`•
`
`Generic companies typically expect authorized generic competition during the
`180-day exclusivity period and often build that assumption into their forecasts,
`which means reducing the expected revenues for the generic challenger.9 And
`one company provided an analysis suggesting that this reduction in expected
`profits had led it to reject or defer filing patent challenges for two products in
`small markets.
`
`Finally, despite the presence of AG competition, generic companies have
`continued to challenge patents, even on brand-name drugs with small markets.
`
`"
`
`"
`
`"
`
`From 2003 through 2008, 17 percent of the drugs subject to a first patent
`challenge had sales below $50 million. The median revenue of drugs
`subject to a first patent challenge fell during this period, while AGs were
`becoming common, from $553 million to $131 million.
`
`The number of drugs receiving their first Paragraph IV certification
`approximately doubled between 2003 and 2008.10
`
`Generic companies’ willingness to pursue Paragraph IV challenges when
`they know that they are likely to share exclusivity with other generic
`companies indicates that AGs have not deterred generic challenges. The
`evidence comes from examination of patent challenges for new chemical
`entities, a category of drugs for which first-filers expect to have to share
`exclusivity.11 The percentage of such drugs drawing first-day patent
`challenges has increased greatly despite the likelihood of shared
`exclusivity, from 6 percent in 2002 to 73 percent in 2008.
`
`Each category of evidence has its limitations. And each category is consistent with some
`expected impact on incentives to challenge patents, particularly for drugs in small markets. On
`the whole, however, whether viewed from the perspective of a break-even analysis drawn from
`
`9 While the Report finds that AGs have infrequently been launched for drugs in markets with less than
`$50 million of annual brand sales, generic documents discussing assumptions about AG competition
`do not draw distinctions based on market size. The documentary evidence regarding this point,
`however, is limited.
`10 “Paragraph IV” generic drug applications, filed with the Food and Drug Administration pursuant to 21
`U.S.C. § 355(j)(2)(A)(vii)(IV), certify that a patent is invalid or will not be infringed by the generic
`drug and begin the process of generic entry via patent challenge.
`11 New chemical entities are drugs for which the active ingredient has not received previous FDA
`approval. For new chemical entities, the first day that applications with Paragraph IV certifications are
`allowed is four years after approval of the brand-name drug. This is a specific, known day, on which
`filers will expect to share exclusivity.
`
`-v-
`
`000007
`
`

`

`quantitative data, brand-name firm strategic documents and marketing practices, generic firm
`memoranda and forecasts, or the number of patent challenges observed even for small-market
`drugs, authorized generics appear not to have substantially altered generic firms’ willingness to
`enter by challenging questionable patents.
`
`While there is little evidence of authorized generic competition affecting the number of
`patent challenges, there is strong evidence that agreements not to compete with an authorized
`generic have become a way for brand-name companies to compensate generic competitors for
`delaying entry. These agreements can be part of “pay-for-delay” patent settlements, which have
`long concerned the Commission.12 These agreements involve a brand-name firm compensating a
`generic and the generic agreeing to delay its entry. One form that compensation can take is the
`brand’s commitment, in exchange for the first-filer’s agreement to delay entry, not to sell an AG
`during the first-filer’s 180-day exclusivity period. Because the first-filer’s revenue will
`approximately double absent an authorized generic, its revenues will be much larger by agreeing
`to delay than if it litigated, won, and faced AG competition. The generic firm benefits from
`greater profits during its 180-day exclusivity; the brand-name firm benefits from later generic
`entry; but consumers suffer from delay of generic competition. Because generics often are
`priced substantially below the price of brand-name drugs,13 even a few additional months
`without generic competition can significantly increase overall prescription drug costs.
`
`Settlements in which the brand-name company agrees not to compete with an AG have
`become commonplace. Between FY 2004 and FY 2010, 39 of 157 patent settlements with first-
`filer generics (approximately 25 percent) contained such provisions, which have been used with
`some frequency and have become common in agreements with pay-for-delay provisions.14 The
`average delay for the 39 agreements was 37.9 months, and the total market for the drugs
`involved (an indeterminate amount of which represented consumer harm tied to the practice)
`exceeded $23 billion. The promise to suppress AG competition – not the AG itself – is
`responsible for any ensuing consumer harm.
`
`
`In conclusion, this Report finds that, during the 180-day exclusivity period, competition
`from authorized generics lowers prices for consumers and lowers revenues for the independent
`
`12 FTC staff estimates that “pay-for-delay” arrangements, overall, cost American consumers $3.5 billion
`per year. FED. TRADE COMM’N, PAY-FOR-DELAY: HOW DRUG COMPANY PAY-OFFS COST
`CONSUMERS BILLIONS 8–10 (2010), http://www.ftc.gov/os/2010/01/100112 payfordelayrpt.pdf.
`13 See, e.g., CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, HOW INCREASED COMPETITION FROM GENERIC DRUGS HAS
`AFFECTED PRICES AND RETURNS IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 31 (1998),
`http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/6xx/doc655/pharm.pdf. “No AG” agreements also deny consumers the
`benefit of price discounts from AG competition during the 180-day exclusivity period.
`14 Of the 39 agreements from FY 2004 to FY 2010, 24 were made between FY 2004 and FY 2009 (an
`average of four per year), while 15 were made in FY 2010. The 15 agreements in FY 2010 in which
`brand-name firms agreed not to introduce an AG were nearly 60% of the 26 agreements that year
`containing payments to a first-filer generic and a restriction on that firm’s ability to market its product.
`
`-vi-
`
`000008
`
`

`

`generic competitor. Over the longer term, lower expected profits could affect a generic
`company’s decision to challenge a patent on products with low sales, and one company provided
`a few examples where it claimed the expectation of an authorized generic led it to reject or delay
`such a challenge. Overall, however, patent challenges, even on drugs with low sales, remain
`robust and, by most measures, have increased despite the prevalence of authorized generic
`competition. Moreover, as a consequence of an authorized generic’s significant negative impact
`on a generic’s revenues, some brand-name companies have used agreements not to launch an
`authorized generic as a way to compensate an independent generic in exchange for the generic’s
`agreement to delay its entry. The frequency of this practice and its profitability may make it an
`attractive way to structure a pay-for-delay settlement, a practice that causes substantial consumer
`harm.
`
`-vii-
`
`000009
`
`

`

`000010
`
`000010
`
`

`

`AUTHORIZED GENERIC DRUGS:
`SHORT-TERM EFFECTS AND LONG-TERM IMPACT
`———————
`A REPORT OF THE
`FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
`
`
`
`CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................1
`I. THE BASIC REGULATORY FRAMEWORK AND THE HATCH-WAXMAN AMENDMENTS ........................... 2
`II. THE KEY ISSUES ADDRESSED IN THIS REPORT ..................................................................................... 4
`III. STUDY SCOPE AND DATA SOURCES .................................................................................................... 6
`IV. ORGANIZATION OF THE REPORT.......................................................................................................... 8
`CHAPTER 2: AN OVERVIEW OF AG MARKETING AND ITS RELATIONSHIP TO
`THE EXCLUSIVITY SYSTEM .................................................................................................11
`I. AG MARKETING: TRENDS AND INDUSTRY PRACTICES ........................................................................ 11
`A. The Scope and Time Course of AG Marketing ................................................................................ 11
`B. Brand and Generic Industry Involvement in Authorized Generics ................................................. 14
`1. Authorization of Generic Drugs by NDA-Holding Companies ................................................... 15
`2. Distribution of AGs: In-House Marketing and External Generic Partners ................................ 17
`II. AG MARKETING: RELATIONSHIP TO 180-DAY EXCLUSIVITY PERIODS AND PATENT CHALLENGES . 25
`A. AG Marketing During 180-Day Exclusivity Periods ....................................................................... 26
`B. AG Marketing Apart from 180-Day Exclusivity Periods and Patent Challenges ........................... 27
`III. CONCLUSION ..................................................................................................................................... 32
`CHAPTER 3: SHORT-TERM IMPACTS OF AUTHORIZED GENERICS: PRICE AND
`REVENUE EFFECTS DURING 180-DAY EXCLUSIVITY ..................................................33
`I. PRIOR STUDIES ..................................................................................................................................... 34
`II. DESCRIPTION OF THE DATA ................................................................................................................ 36
`III. THE EFFECT OF AUTHORIZED GENERIC COMPETITION DURING THE EXCLUSIVITY PERIOD ............ 38
`A. Market Prices of Generic Drugs ..................................................................................................... 40
`1. Generic Retail Market Prices ...................................................................................................... 41
`2. Generic Wholesale Market Prices ............................................................................................... 46
`3. Generic Firm Level Pricing Analysis .......................................................................................... 48
`B. Market Prices of Brand-Name Products ......................................................................................... 50
`1. Brand Retail Prices ..................................................................................................................... 50
`2. Brand Wholesale Prices .............................................................................................................. 52
`3. Investigating Lower Brand Prices During Exclusivity ................................................................ 54
`C. Wholesale Expenditures .................................................................................................................. 56
`1. Wholesale Revenues of ANDA-Generic Firms ............................................................................ 57
`2. Wholesale Revenues of the Brand-Name Product ....................................................................... 59
`3. Wholesale Revenues of Brand-Name Firms ................................................................................ 61
`IV. CONCLUSION ..................................................................................................................................... 63
`CHAPTER 4: THE MARKETING OF AUTHORIZED GENERICS: BRAND-NAME
`FIRMS’ OBJECTIVES AND STRATEGIES ...........................................................................65
`I. AUTHORIZED GENERICS AND REVENUE ENHANCEMENT .................................................................... 66
`A. The Use of Authorized Generics to Maintain a Revenue Stream .................................................... 66
`B. The Use of Brand-Name Discounting to Maintain a Revenue Stream ............................................ 69
`
`000011
`
`

`

`II. AUTHORIZED GENERICS AND IMPACT ON GENERIC FIRMS’ INCENTIVES ........................................... 71
`III. EVIDENCE FROM BRAND MARKETING PRACTICES ............................................................................ 72
`A. Relationship to Exclusivity; Timing of Launch and Withdrawal ..................................................... 72
`B. Pricing, Market Share, and Profit-Splits ......................................................................................... 75
`IV. CONCLUSION ..................................................................................................................................... 77
`CHAPTER 5: THE MARKETING OF AUTHORIZED GENERICS: GENERIC FIRM
`PERCEPTIONS AND DECISION-MAKING ..........................................................................79
`I. THE IMPACT OF AGS ON GENERIC FIRM REVENUES AND PROFITS: GENERIC COMPANY CONCERNS
`AND RESPONSES ...................................................................................................................................... 80
`A. The Nature of Generic Company Concerns .................................................................................... 80
`B. Differing Generic Company Responses .......................................................................................... 83
`II. THE LONG-TERM IMPACT OF AGS ON GENERIC FIRM INCENTIVES TO BRING GENERIC PRODUCTS TO
`MARKET VIA PATENT CHALLENGES ....................................................................................................... 85
`A. Documents Suggesting an Impact on Generic Entry through Patent Challenges ........................... 86
`B. Documents Suggesting that Impacts of AGs on Generic Entry through Patent Challenges May Be
`Overstated ........................................................................................................................................ 89
`III. CONCLUSION ..................................................................................................................................... 92
`CHAPTER 6: LONG-TERM EFFECTS OF AUTHORIZED GENERICS: PRICE,
`REVENUE, AND BREAK-EVEN EFFECTS ...........................................................................93
`I. PRIOR STUDIES ..................................................................................................................................... 94
`II. DATA AND METHODOLOGICAL APPROACH ........................................................................................ 96
`III. MARKET PRICES OF GENERIC DRUGS ............................................................................................. 100
`A. Retail Prices .................................................................................................................................. 101
`B. Wholesale Prices ........................................................................................................................... 102
`IV. WHOLESALE EXPENDITURES ........................................................................................................... 103
`A. Evolution of Revenue Shares in Markets with and without AGs ................................................... 103
`B. Wholesale Expenditures on the First-Filer’s Product ................................................................... 105
`C. Wholesale Expenditures on The Brand-Name Firm’s Products ................................................... 107
`V. INCENTIVES TO FILE PARAGRAPH IV CHALLENGES ......................................................................... 109
`A. The Profit Calculation ................................................................................................................... 109
`B. Break-Even Analysis ..................................................................................................................... 112
`1. Markets without an AG .............................................................................................................. 112
`2. Markets with an AG ................................................................................................................... 113
`3. Effect on Threshold Probability of a Successful Challenge ...................................................... 115
`VI. CONCLUSION ................................................................................................................................... 118
`CHAPTER 7: ASSESSING THE IMPACT OF AG COMPETITION FROM PATENT
`CHALLENGE DATA ................................................................................................................121
`I. PATENT CHALLENGES BY SALES LEVEL ............................................................................................ 122
`A. Challenges to Patents on Low-Sales Drugs .................................................................................. 122
`B. Trends in Sales Levels of Drugs Subject to Challenge .................................................................. 125
`II. THE PREVALENCE OF PATENT CHALLENGES AND DRUGS SUBJECT TO PATENT CHALLENGES ....... 126
`A. ANDA Filings and Paragraph IV Certifications ........................................................................... 126
`B. Drugs Subject to ANDAs with First PIV and PIII Certifications .................................................. 128
`III. PATENT CHALLENGES LEADING TO SHARED EXCLUSIVITY: NEW CHEMICAL ENTITIES ................ 133
`IV. CONCLUSION ................................................................................................................................... 137
`
`
`
`000012
`
`

`

`CHAPTER 8: THE USE OF AUTHORIZED

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket