throbber
ENTRY DECISIONS IN THE GENERIC
`PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY
`
`Fiona M. Scott Morton
`
`Working Paper 6190
`
`000001
`
`Exhibit 1129
`Exhibit 1129
`IPR2017-00807
`IPR2017-00807
`ARGENTUM
`ARGENTUM
`
`000001
`
`

`

`NBER WORKINGPAPER SERIES
`
`ENTRY DECISIONS IN THE GENERIC
`PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY
`
`Fiona M. Scott Morton
`
`Working Paper 6190
`http://www.nber.org/papers/w6 190
`
`NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
`1050 Massachusetts Avenue
`Cambridge, MA 02138
`September 1997
`
`Thanks are due to Peter Reiss, John Roberts, Garth Saloner, Andrea Shepard, Dimitri Vayanos,
`Matthew White, seminar participants at UBC, Northwestern, University of Chicago, University of
`Michigan,and the NBER 1.0. winter conference. I am also grateful to Merck and Co.for allowing
`me to gather data from their library. All errors are the responsibility of the author. This paperis part
`of NBER’s research program in Industrial Organization. Any opinions expressed are those of the
`author and notthose of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
`
`© 1997 by Fiona M.Scott Morton. All rights reserved. Short sectionsof text, not to exceed two
`paragraphs, may be quoted withoutexplicit permission providedthatfull credit, including © notice,
`is given to the source.
`
`000002
`
`000002
`
`

`

`Entry Decisions in the Generic Pharmaceutical
`Industry
`Fiona M. Scott Morton
`NBER Working Paper No. 6190
`September 1997
`JEL Nos. L65, L20, L21
`Industrial Organization
`
`ABSTRACT
`
`In this paper I use dataon all generic drug approvals granted from 1984-1994 to examine
`
`whether heterogeneity among potential generic entrants can be used to predict which firmswill
`
`chooseto enter a particular market. The findings suggest that a firm’s portfolio characteristics,
`
`namely, its previous experience with a drug or therapy reduces the cost of preparing an ANDA and
`
`increasesthe probability of entry. A subsidiary’s parent's experienceis not generally significant in
`
`predicting entry of the subsidiary. Firmsalso prefer entering markets that are similar, in terms of
`
`revenue and sales to hospitals, to markets already in their portfolios. On both scientific and
`
`marketing dimensions, the evidence showsthatfirms are specializing.
`
`I explore severaldifferent
`
`ways of constructing the set of potential entrants and find that the results are not affected by
`
`methodologicalvariation. Standard IO theory suggests that profits per entrant will decline in the
`
`numberof entrants. Previousresearch has found that generic prices depend on the numberofgeneric
`
`entrants, and the results presented here show that the total numberof entrants increases with the size
`
`of the market (revenue). These findings imply that generic firms face a negative competition
`
`externality which makestheir expectations about who else might be planning to enter any given
`
`market important in the entry decision. The limited evidence on entrant beliefs supports this
`
`conjecture as do several features of a regulatory upheaval when firms began entering different
`
`markets than they had in the past.
`
`Fiona M. Scott Morton
`Graduate School of Business
`University of Chicago
`1101 East 58th Street
`Chicago, IL 60637
`and NBER
`fionasm@gsb.uchicago.edu
`
`000003
`
`000003
`
`

`

`I. Introduction
`
`A firm’s decision to enter a particular market is one of the most important economicactionsin a
`
`market economy. The numberoffirmsin a market and distribution of market share have long been
`knownto affect price levels and consumer welfare. Most researchin this area uses the convenient
`
`assumption of symmetric firms, although this is of course not a good representation ofreality. In
`
`contrast, this paper takes explicit accountof heterogeneity among potential entrants to predict which
`firmsare likely to enter which markets. In particular, it examines the entry choices of heterogeneous
`generic pharmaceuticalfirms and findsthat they specialize along both scientific and marketing
`dimensions. Thehistory and experience ofa firm that lead it to enter particular markets can be thought of
`as firm ‘capabilities,’ in the sense that word is used in the business press. This industry providesa setting
`wherea firm’s capabilities can be explicitly measured and the result of using existing capabilities or
`
`developing new ones can be observed.
`
`The entry decision is complex because the numberof firms in a marketaffects the payoff to any
`one of them from entering that market; each entrant creates a negative externality for the others that can
`
`be severe. Profits earned by an entrantfirm therefore depend on entry decisions of other firms. Entrants
`
`sink entry costs simultaneously because firms do not typically announcetheir entry plans and the FDA
`
`does not reveal whose application it has received. The timing of the game, combined with research
`
`showing generic prices (and presumably profits) depend on the numberofgeneric entrants, implies that
`generic firms face the difficult problem of how to form expectations about where others will enter. Those
`
`expectations will affect its own entry decisions.
`
`The question of which firms are expected to enter -- as well as do enter -- which markets in a
`
`simultaneous gameis important. For a generic pharmaceutical manager making entry decisions for his or
`her firm,it is clearly a crucial problem. I discuss and examine how a generic pharmaceutical firm might
`form expectationsofrivals’ actions and what firm equilibrium strategies might be. I argue that repeat
`players may usean entry strategy that provides stability of expectations: specialization. Specialization
`
`based on both scientific and marketing characteristics is natural becauseit reflects lower costs and
`
`provides a well-understood way to form conjectures about where competitors will enter.
`
`It is possible to conduct an empirical study of firm decision-making in the generic
`
`pharmaceutical industry because entry regulations create relatively good experiments and the regulatory
`
`agency, the Food and Drug Administration (FDA), generates data that are available to researchers. In this
`
`paperI use data on all generic drug entries from 1984 to 1994 to examineentry patterns and
`
`3
`
`000004
`
`000004
`
`

`

`specialization.In particular, I explore whether generic entrants are choosing markets based on past
`experience as measured by characteristics of their portfolios. I find that a firm’s previous experience with
`a drug or therapyincreases the probability of entry into a similar market. The experience ofa firm’s
`parent on various dimensionsis generally not helpful in predicting entry, above and beyondthe firm’s
`(subsidiary) experience. Marketing similarities between the entry opportunity and characteristics of the
`
`firm’s portfolio such as market revenue and hospital share are also important in explaining entry.
`Additionally, I show that larger markets, those that attract more entry, are markets with more sales to
`
`hospitals and those where the drug treats a chronic condition.
`
`In 1989 a major scandal erupted whenvariousillegal practices were uncovered in the generic
`drug industry. I present results showing that the subsequent regulatory upheaval re-weighted the
`
`components of entry cost and disrupted established industry practices, including the pattern of
`
`specialization. Firms began to enter markets that looked different, rather than similar, to markets they
`
`were alreadyin.
`
`II. Institutional Framework and Timing
`
`A firm that invents a new drug must get approval from the FDA by showingthe drugis safe and
`effective. A New Drug Application (NDA)reports tests showing safety andefficacy andis typically
`
`expensive to construct and takes many years to be approved. A firm taking this routeis called an
`
`innovator and the product is typically promoted undera proprietary brand name. In 1984 the
`
`pharmaceutical regulatory regime wassignificantly altered by the Waxman-Hatch Act. Thislegislation,
`
`amongother things, allowed generic firms to submit Abbreviated New Drug Applications (ANDAs)for
`drugs approved since 1962. A flood of new ANDAswasfiled in responseto the law. The advantagesof
`the ANDAprocess are summarizedin the quotation below.
`
`“The benefit of the ANDAprocess to generic manufacturersis that it does not require these
`companiesto repeatcostly clinical and animalresearch on active ingredients or finished dosage
`forms already found to be safe and effective. A generic drug must contain the sameactive
`ingredients; be identical in strength, dosage form, and route; be bioequivalent; and be
`manufactured underthe samestrict standards as the brand-name drug to gain FDA approval.”
`(Frost and Sullivan report (1994))
`
`4
`
`000005
`
`000005
`
`

`

`Somefirms submit both NDAs and ANDAs,but the vast majority specialize in one or the other.
`The other main type offirm in the industry is a “generic firm”thatsells generic products. Figuring out
`how to manufacture the drug and performing the bioequivalency studies required for the ANDA can take
`from several months to a couple of years depending on the formulation of the drug, the effort and skill of
`the firm, andthe availability of good suppliers. The application process requires factory inspections
`from the FDA and independentlaboratory tests of several preliminary batches of the product. A firm
`must therefore be ready to make the product -- new equipment must be purchased and operational, for
`
`example -- months before the firm is legally permitted to beginsellingit.
`
`The time between submission of the ANDA andgranting of approval from the FDA averaged
`
`about seventeen months over the 1984-94 period, although annual averages have varied greatly overthe
`
`last decade (Scott Morton (1996)). Therefore, a firm must start applying for permission to manufacture a
`
`specific drug two to three years before its patent expires if the entrant wishes to be active in the market
`
`immediately following patent expiration. Historically, many firms have not applied in a timely fashion
`
`despite the well-knownfact that a firm that is first into a market and the only generic for even a few
`
`monthsearnslarge profits. A useful rule of thumb is that generic markets for most drugsdo notlast very
`long compared to the productlife of a patented and branded drug. Bythetimeall the patents on a drug
`
`have expired,it is relatively old technology and superior therapeutic substitutes are very likely to have
`
`been invented. Demandfor the drug in patient days and revenue beginsto fall after patent expiration;
`
`not many drugs remain major markets five years after patent expiration. (See Caveset al. (1991) and
`
`Stern (1995).) Thus, we should not see profit-maximizing generic firms wasting any time in entering a
`
`market -- once the relevant patents expire -- and the model will not build in an option for delay.!
`
`The FDA doesnot reveal what applications it has received from which firms; no one can receive
`
`information on pending applications from the FDA. However, firms may announcetheir own intentions
`
`or actions. An (admittedly incomplete) examination of annual reports and interviews suggests that
`
`announcingis rare. Industry participants claim they do not wantto reveal that they think a particular
`
`marketis a good one to enter. Since all firms have accessto essentially the same information,this claim
`
`does not seem to be very convincing. However, another firm’s opinion could function as an additional
`
`signal of value for what could be an unknown, but common,value. Additionally, although a firm might
`
`announceit has applied fora particular drug, there is no guarantee approval will be grantedin the time
`
`frame anticipated by the applicant. The announcementis notcredible. The firm could still be missing
`
`sometests or have a sloppy application. At the last minute, the FDA could decideatrial did not meet
`
`1 Bolton and Farrell (1990) model an option for delay in their entry game.
`
`5
`
`000006
`
`000006
`
`

`

`FDAstandards and mustbe redone;or the factory mightfail a late inspection. A year’s delay (which
`could easily happen due to regulatory uncertainty) can cause an application that was submitted and
`
`announcedto be approved after that of a competitor responding to the announcement. A firm therefore
`
`cannot precommitto a market with an application announcement. Theresult of this lack of announcingis
`that generic firms are effectively sinking entry costs simultaneously.
`
`The pharmaceuticalindustry is characterized by high fixed costs (invention) and low marginal
`
`costs (production). Although an ANDAandthe research involved are muchless costly than basic
`
`research and NDAs,entry cost is nevertheless significant for a generic drug project wherethereis likely
`
`to be vigorous price competition. The average size of brand markets in the samplethatlater attract one
`
`generic entrantis $22 million. Generic products usually capture about half of molecule volume,although
`
`at prices 30-50% lowerthan the brand price. Thus per firm generic revenuesare likely to be less than $10
`
`million per year, perhaps as low as $5 million for a product (perhaps with multiple concentrations). In
`
`interviewsI have been told that filing an ANDA costs one quarter of a million dollars, twenty million
`
`dollars and various figures in between. This order of magnitude matches a one-entrant marketsize,
`
`although ANDAcosts clearly must vary across drugs and firms. Generic drug industry participants
`
`exhibit great concern overexcessentry, falling prices, and the effect on profits. Stories of unexpected
`
`failures due to the appearanceof extra entrants are common. If fixed and sunk costs were zero, marginal
`
`cost pricing would provide an acceptable rate of return, no one would be willing to charge less than
`
`marginal cost, and manufacturers would not worry about making a drug on which they are losing money
`
`overall.
`
`I therefore make the assumptionthat fixed sunk costs are an important componentin the
`
`project’s budget.
`
`The FDA imposesno requirement to produce once an ANDAis granted. Thus an unused but
`
`approved ANDAis an option, available to be usedif prices rise, rivals exit, or the market becomes more
`
`attractive for any reason. Exit -- formal withdrawal of the ANDA-- is not anattractive alternative unless
`
`price is expected to be below marginalcost for the life of the drug (where marginal cost includes the
`
`opportunity cost of using equipment to make other drugs). There are several categories of ANDA
`
`withdrawal: the firm may discontinue the product, the product can be withdrawn by mutual consent, the
`
`firm might violate an FDA standard so that the FDA withdraws the ANDA,orthe product may be found
`
`not to be efficacious (all NDA and ANDAsforthat product are withdrawn). The last two (and maybe
`
`three) reasons are cases where the FDAis forcing the firm to exit, rather than situations where the firm
`
`choosesto leave the market because it is unsatisfactory. An ANDAcanbesold ortransferred easily with
`
`the physical productionsite, or if the original manufacturer becomes a contract manufacturer for the new
`
`owner. Buying an ANDAwithoutits factory means newtests and inspections mustbe carried out to the
`
`6
`
`000007
`
`000007
`
`

`

`FDA’s satisfaction; this is not necessarily faster or cheaper than starting from scratch. Thusentry by a
`
`particular firm is a fairly irreversible decision; the costs that can be recovered upon exit from one drug
`
`(and not a factory) are close to zero.
`
`In 1989 what became knownasthe “generic scandal” broke out. Investigations by the US
`
`Attorney’s office in Baltimore began in 1988, and by the end of 1989 had uncovered several cases of
`
`bribery in the generic drug approval process. Four reviewers at the FDA were found to have been taking
`
`bribes in return for speeding approvalofthe bribing firms’ ANDAs.* Additionally, some firms were
`
`found to have submitted the original branded productas their own in tests designed to compare a
`
`potential generic to the brand. The “generic” drug would passthe test with flying colors.3 In one case a
`
`generic firm wasactually selling the recoated branded product.4 Laterin the investigation, violations of
`
`manufacturing rules were also uncovered. The fallout from these discoveries greatly affected approvals
`
`and manufacturing in the following several years. The FDA’s Generic Drug Division fired many
`
`reviewers and the remaining reviewers proceeded very cautiously and slowly. New reviewers were
`
`hired, ethics standards promulgated, and the division was reorganized. ANDAsgranted from 1989-1993
`
`took years longer than usual to be approved.
`
`Additionally, although this was not a concern of the FDA investigation, it became knownthat
`
`industry participants had been bribing employeesofrival firms for information on approvalactivity.
`
`Manyfirms were engaging in gossip and inquiry into the entry plansof rival generic firms. The people
`
`in the industry included in my informalpoll claim muchof this activity cameto a halt at the time of the
`
`FDAscandal and investigation because managers were worried that their behavior would be interpreted
`
`as unethicalor illegal. This left firms with much less information on the entry plans of competitors.
`
`The discovery ofirregularities in the approval process led to a review of what are known as
`
`“good manufacturing practices.” Many more, andstricter, inspections of manufacturing facilities were
`
`carried out than had gone on previously. Manyfirms were forced to withdraw products from the market
`
`for a period of months-- years, in somecases -- until their manufacturing satisfied the FDA. During the
`
`time the products were off the market the firms were upgrading their manufacturing process, suppliers,
`
`or proceduresandtraining. The regulatory changes took place over several years and involved political
`
`actors from Congress, Health and HumanServices, the FDA, and law enforcement. The criminal
`
`2 The investigation was launched because Mylan becamesuspiciousthat its drugs were not getting approval as
`quickly as competitors and found incriminating evidence in the garbage can of their FDA reviewer. (Chicago
`Tribune, Nov. 22, 1992)
`3 The independentlabs doing the testing noticed when the coating chipped off, the brand logo wasvisible!
`4 This hardly seemslike a profit-maximizing strategy.
`
`7
`
`000008
`
`000008
`
`

`

`investigation wasstill going strong in 1992, although most convictions had been secured by then.>
`
`Overall, the period from 1988 to at least 1992 was a time of great upheaval and uncertainty in the generic
`
`drug industry.
`
`III. Model
`
`The entry gameandthe role of competition and fixed costs has been addressed by a numberof
`
`researchers (Bresnahan and Reiss (1988, 1991b), for example). These models predict the total number of
`
`entrants in a market, partly because this piece of information is of great interest to 1.0. economists and
`
`policy makers. However, the issue of exactly which potential entrant ends up entering is undetermined in
`
`many gametheoretic models of entry. Typically, entrants are modeled as drawn from a limitless pool of
`
`identical potential entrants, probably an unrealistic assumption for most markets. Often it is difficult to
`
`measure and model heterogeneity among potential entrants; additionally, heterogeneity has a strong
`
`impact on form of the entry game. Berry (1992) addresses the question of which entrants enter which
`
`markets, as well as how manyentrants enter a market, in his study of the airline industry. However, the
`
`generic pharmaceutical industry is characterized by simultaneous entry, rather than sequential, as in the
`
`Berry model. The following simple modelillustrates its main features.
`
`The gamehas two periods. In the first period firms choose whetheror not to enter specific
`
`markets by sinking their fixed costs. In the second period production and sales determine net profits.
`
`Profits will depend on the numberofentrants in two ways. First, equilibrium price will decline in the
`
`numberofentrants. (Price will hereafter mean generic price.) Despite the fact that the product is very
`
`homogeneousandthe industry lookslike it should exhibit Bertrand pricing, several studies have
`
`documented that generic pricesfall steadily with the numberof generic firms (Caveset al. (1991), Frank
`
`and Salkever (1995), Wiggins and Maness(1995)).
`
`Secondly, an increasing numberof firms means smaller quantity sold for each,all else equal.I
`
`assume a molecule’s marketsize is fixed because productsare relatively old by the time their patents
`
`expire; the brand has expanded the market as muchas it can. The drop in price due to the introduction of
`
`generics does not increase total quantity sold of the molecule, probably dueto the price-insensitivity of
`doctors (see CWH (1991)).” However, lower generic prices will increase generic quantity at the expense
`
`of brand quantity. If total generic quantity sold is Q, and 7 is the numberof generic firms, I assume Q/n
`
`falls with n, despite the expansion in Q due to lower prices. The important feature of the modelis that
`
`5 Chicago Tribune, Nov. 22, 1992 p 13A
`
`8
`
`000009
`
`000009
`
`

`

`profits decline with an additional entrant. This will hold, and the coordination problem will be
`
`particularly important, when both price and quantity sold per firm decline with additional entry. The
`
`expression below representstotal profits for firm i earned in marketj.
`
`Ty = (pit) — ca)qu(n) — Fa
`
`whereprice (p) and quantity (q) depend on the numberoffirms (n) in the manner described. cjj and Fi
`denote the marginal cost and fixed entry cost respectively that are specific to firm i and marketj.
`
`Theidea hereis that there is heterogeneity across firms and it shows upin firm costs. The model
`
`will produce the sameentry rule whetherfirms differ in marginal cost, fixed cost, or both.” For the
`
`purposesofdiscussion, for the rest of the paper I will assumethat it is the fixed cost of entry that differs
`
`across firms and markets, while marginal costs are constantacrossfirms.’ Firms differ in the skills of
`
`their research group, suppliers, equipment, etc. which will affect ANDAcost. Drug markets also vary in
`
`howdifficult a drug is to formulate and test, and therefore how muchanentrant will spend to enter. The
`
`basic implications of this sort of modelare that in larger markets more firms will find it profitable to
`
`enter, each additional entrant will lower the net profit of all other entrants, and lowercost firms should
`
`enter where higher cost firms should not. The analysis in the paper will test these implications.
`
`In equilibrium firms choose markets to enter based on differences in past experience. Each firm
`
`has a fixed cost F; that is observable and common knowledge. Strategies are enter if F;<F* and stay outif
`
`F>F*, F* is defined such that firms with costs higher in the distribution than F* earn negative profit
`
`whenall firms with F,<F* enter. No mistakes occur under this scheme because each firm knows whereit
`
`lies in the realized distribution of fixed costs for the market and will not enter if there is not “room” for
`
`it. The postulated strategies form a Nash equilibrium because the low cost entrants will earn non-
`
`negative profit when the high cost firms stay out and therefore prefer to enter, while the high cost firms
`
`© The elasticity of demandis clearly not zero atall price levels. However, in the observedprice range,elasticity of
`demand for a molecule is very low.
`? Later in the paper, I use drug experiencevariables to proxy for fixed cost differences across firms. Experience
`variables will also pick up any experience-based differences in marginal cost. Other marginalcost differences come
`from the batch production nature of pharmaceutical manufacturing. The marginal cost of a batch (rather than a pill)
`includes the opportunity cost of capital. A firm with strong demand for more drugs than it can produce at one time
`has an attractive outside option, production of one ofits other drugs, for any given piece of capital. Since the quality
`of the outside option will vary across firms and over time, the marginal cost of a batch will also vary. The problem
`of opportunity cost of a batch is an important factor in the firm’s decision to enter a market, and it is impossible to
`measure without detailed plant-level data. Finally, there will be some marginal cost differences are due to
`characteristics of the production process that I cannot measure or control for. These final two sources of marginal
`cost differences are unaccountedfor in this study.
`
`9
`
`000010
`
`000010
`
`

`

`will only lose moneyif they enter and the low cost firmsalso enter, so they prefer to stay out. A firm’s
`fixed cost level will help predict entry in this game,as will the cutoff level for the market, F*.
`All firms can work outthe cutoff point in the fixed cost distribution. The firm enters if its own
`
`fixed cost falls below that cutoff level.
`
`pr(entry 4) = pr( Fi < Fj*)
`
`where Fj* representsthe cutoff fixed cost level for marketj.
`The model mostclosely related to this problem is that of Dixit and Shapiro (1986). They
`describe a case of N identical potential entrants vying for spots in a market that “holds” only M firms,
`and build a model based on mixedstrategies.? There is a probability of entry from which each firm can
`calculate its expected profits from entering or not (using a binomialprobability density). The equilibrium
`probability of entry is derived from the indifference of a firm to choosing enteror not enter.!9 Dixit and
`Shapiro point out that choosing a pure strategy equilibrium in which onlyMfirmsplay “enter”is
`artificial unless the reason for choosing those M firmsis incorporated into the game. The modelandthe
`empirics below do incorporate reasonsfor particular firms to enter, allowing the firmsto do better than
`just flipping a coin, and allowing the researcher (and presumably competitors) to predict entry, although
`not perfectly.
`
`Firmsbear considerable risk due to simultaneousentry in the standard model of competition
`described above.“Over-entry”results in a lower than expected market price, volume, andprofits, and the
`ex post desire not to have entered the marketin the first place. Price might stay above marginal cost, and
`yet belowalevel that yields zero profit on the project, without firms havingthe incentiveto exit the
`industry. “Under-entry” of course, produces economicprofits until additional firms are approved to make
`the drug (which normally would occur within two to three years). At any moment, each firm is trying to
`enter only “good” markets. Eachis trying to be in a market with the equilibrium, or fewer than
`equilibrium, numberoffirms.
`
`SSSSSSSSSSSSSSSSSSSSSSSSSSeeSSSSSeeeeeeEEEee
`
`8 The correct assumption undoubtedly varies by market.
`9 Large markets cannot be served by only one firm because each firm has an upward sloping supply curve due to the
`opportunity cost of capital (using all its machinesto increase output of one drug) andthe risk associated with
`dedicatinga large part of the firm’s capital to one drug.
`10 The probability of entry times the number of potential entrants can be greater or less than the numberoffirms
`which can earn positive profits, which direction the inequality goes depends onthe shapeofthe profit function.
`Dixit and Shapiro showthat for convex profit functions (Cournot, for example) on averagethere will be over-entry.
`
`10
`
`000011
`
`000011
`
`

`

`Thisraises the difficult problem of how generic firms make entry decisions in conjunction with
`
`other firms whenthey cannot explicitly coordinate. Bolton and Farrell (1990) examinetheclassic
`
`problem of two firms deciding whetheror not to enter a natural monopoly market. They are primarily
`
`interested in when a central planner can do better than the decentralized case of each firm deciding based
`
`on its own private information. The randomnessinherentin not coordinating will result in “mistakes.”If
`
`firms could avoid those mistakes by using the services of a central planner, welfare would be increased.
`
`The increase in social welfare in their model comes from the reduction in “duplication” (both firms
`
`enter) and “delay” (both firms wait for the other to enter). These are analogousto the generic
`
`pharmaceutical industry where producer surplusis savedif the fixed cost of entry is not paid twice and
`
`consumersurplusis increased if the entry occurs quickly so that prices fall. However, Bolton and Farrell
`
`show thatif private information, perhaps about the entry costs of the twofirms,is sufficiently important,
`
`central planning will result in lowertotal surplus.
`
`It is difficult to isolate evidence of the negative externality problem from the ‘low-cost firms
`
`should enter’ story. If it is the case that an entrant’s profits depend on the numberofother entrants in the
`
`market, then an entry decision cannot depend on a firm’s own characteristics alone. Because of oligopoly
`
`or competitive interaction, the entrant’s beliefs about the actions of other entrants will affect its entry
`
`decision.!! Each firm has an interest in notentering if it believes too many otherfirms will enter. Beliefs
`
`about other players’ strategies determines which equilibrium (of many)is selected. Anyset of beliefs
`
`that coordinated firms’ actions would work: geographic, alphabetic, phases of the moon, etc.. However,
`
`beliefs are difficult to measure and I will be unable to use them in the empirical analysis.
`
`The cost story, on the other hand, reflects a situation where there are firms with sufficiently high
`
`fixed costs that they cannot earn positive profit even if given an entry slot; beliefs about whoelse will
`
`enter do not affect entry decisions. However, if any firm with costs below a certain threshold can earn
`
`positive profits in the market, then market size should not be a helpful predictor of entry. The reason
`
`more firms enter larger markets is because they can fit - despite the business stealing efforts of their
`
`rivals. Thus the significance of market size measures in predicting entry will provide some evidence for
`
`the existence of negative competitive externalities in the industry. ] use observable characteristics of the
`
`firm andits portfolio to proxy for firm fixed costs of entry. Estimation relies on those firm characteristics
`
`as well as knowledge of actual and potential entry events and measures of market size such as revenue.
`
`11 Notice that beliefs matter only among firmsthat could makea profit if they were given an entry slot. For
`example,it is easy to construct an example of a natural monopoly where any firm in the cost distribution could earn
`non-negative profits as a monopolist, but none could earn non-negative profits in a duopoly.
`
`11
`
`000012
`
`000012
`
`

`

`IV. Data
`
`The data I use to examine entry behavior are ANDAapprovals granted from 1984-1994. A firm
`
`becomespart of the datasetif it is granted an ANDAinthe time period; a particular drug becomespart of
`
`the datasetif it is applied for in an ANDA approved during this time period. Each approved ANDAis an
`
`observation. The FDA provides the submission date, the approval date, the applicant nameas well as
`
`characteristics of the drug such as ingredients, form, route (into the body), and strength.
`
`I recode the
`
`FDA’s detailed form and route descriptions into five basic categories according to the type of machinery
`
`needed to manufacture a drug with certain characteristics and the cleanliness standards required in the
`
`manufacturing facility. The first category is oral solid, which formsthe bulk of the observations in the
`
`data. The second groupis injectable drugs, third is topical preparations, followed by oral liquids, and
`
`then ocular drugs.'!2 Note that the ANDAs making upthe dataset are not a sample, but the complete
`
`universe of ANDAsapproved in the United States during the time period 1984-94.
`
`I have calculated or collected information on additional variables such as the firm's primary type
`
`of product (brand or generic) and the parent of the applicant(if it exists). A drug’s therapeutic classis
`
`assigned according to the description under“indications” in the 1993 volume of Physician’s GenRx, a
`
`comprehensive pharmaceutical reference. There are approximately thirty therapeutic categories in the
`
`dataset.
`
`I also include the date legal restrictions on entry into the drug expire. Simply including thelast
`
`patent expiration date is not a good method because,first ofall, there are usually several patents in force
`
`and it is not obvious to the uninformed observer which oneis the binding patent. Also, the FDA may
`
`have extended exclusivity rights due to excessive approval times, or may have granted an exclusivity
`
`period for a new route or dosage form, among other innovations.
`
`I resolved cases where the published
`
`dates for these restrictions did not match the entry pattern by telephoning patent lawyers at the firm in
`
`question. Although time-consuming, this method was quite successful; I was forced to exclude only a
`

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket