throbber
THE JOURNAL OF INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS
`Volume LV
`December 2007
`
`0022-1821
`No. 4
`
`Notes on the Journal of Industrial Economics Website
`www.essex.ac.uk/jindec/
`
`DIRECT TO CONSUMER ADVERTISING AND
`PRESCRIPTION CHOICE
`
`Toshiaki Iizukaw
`Ginger Z. Jinz
`
`This paper examines the effect of direct-to-consumer advertising
`(DTCA) of prescription drugs on doctors’ choice of drug brands. Using
`antihistamines as an example, we show that DTCA has little effect on
`the choice of brand despite the massive DTCA expenditure incurred in
`this class. In contrast, promotional activities directed toward physicians
`have larger and longer lasting effects. These results, together with the
`market-expanding results shown in Iizuka and Jin (2005), suggest that
`DTCA is effective in increasing the aggregate demand per therapeutic
`class but does not affect doctor choice of prescription within a class.
`Therefore, DTCA may be viewed as a public good for all drugs in the
`same class.
`
`Posted 12 June, 2006
`
`wAuthors’ affiliations: Graduate School of International Management, Aoyama Gakuin
`University, Aoyama, Tokyo, Japan.
`e-mail: toshi.iizuka@gmail com
`zDepartment of Economics, University of Maryland & NBER, College Park, Maryland
`20742, U.S.A.
`e-mail: jin@econ. umd. edu
`
`VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND SHARED FACILITIES
`IN UNREGULATED INDUSTRIES
`
`Felipe Balmacedaw
`Eduardo Saavedraz
`
`In this paper we analyze the equilibrium market structure, following
`liberalization, of an industry involving an essential facility. Two
`alternative modes of market entry are considered, in conjunction with
`vertical integration, namely: (i) full entry, which means building a new
`and more efficient facility at a positive fixed cost; and (ii) partial entry,
`which means purchasing existing capacity from the incumbent, at a fixed
`price per unit that is freely negotiated between the incumbent and the
`entrant. We show that vertical integration is a dominant strategy for
`
`r 2007 The Authors. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial
`Economics. Published by Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK, and 350 Main Street, Malden,
`MA 02148, USA.
`
`771
`
`Page 1 of 12
`
`ACRUX DDS PTY LTD. et al.
`
`EXHIBIT 1616
`
`IPR Petition for
`
`U.S. Patent No. 7,214,506
`
`

`

`THE JOURNAL OF INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS
`Volume LV
`December 2007
`
`0022-1821
`No. 4
`
`Notes on the Journal of Industrial Economics Website
`www.essex.ac.uk/jindec/
`
`DIRECT TO CONSUMER ADVERTISING AND
`PRESCRIPTION CHOICE
`
`Toshiaki Iizukaw
`Ginger Z. Jinz
`
`This paper examines the effect of direct-to-consumer advertising
`(DTCA) of prescription drugs on doctors’ choice of drug brands. Using
`antihistamines as an example, we show that DTCA has little effect on
`the choice of brand despite the massive DTCA expenditure incurred in
`this class. In contrast, promotional activities directed toward physicians
`have larger and longer lasting effects. These results, together with the
`market-expanding results shown in Iizuka and Jin (2005), suggest that
`DTCA is effective in increasing the aggregate demand per therapeutic
`class but does not affect doctor choice of prescription within a class.
`Therefore, DTCA may be viewed as a public good for all drugs in the
`same class.
`
`Posted 12 June, 2006
`
`wAuthors’ affiliations: Graduate School of International Management, Aoyama Gakuin
`University, Aoyama, Tokyo, Japan.
`e-mail: toshi.iizuka@gmail com
`zDepartment of Economics, University of Maryland & NBER, College Park, Maryland
`20742, U.S.A.
`e-mail: jin@econ. umd. edu
`
`VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND SHARED FACILITIES
`IN UNREGULATED INDUSTRIES
`
`Felipe Balmacedaw
`Eduardo Saavedraz
`
`In this paper we analyze the equilibrium market structure, following
`liberalization, of an industry involving an essential facility. Two
`alternative modes of market entry are considered, in conjunction with
`vertical integration, namely: (i) full entry, which means building a new
`and more efficient facility at a positive fixed cost; and (ii) partial entry,
`which means purchasing existing capacity from the incumbent, at a fixed
`price per unit that is freely negotiated between the incumbent and the
`entrant. We show that vertical integration is a dominant strategy for
`
`r 2007 The Authors. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial
`Economics. Published by Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK, and 350 Main Street, Malden,
`MA 02148, USA.
`
`771
`
`Page 1 of 12
`
`

`

`Copyright of Journal of Industrial Economics is the property of Blackwell Publishing Limited and
`its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listsermr without the
`copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email
`articles 'For individual use.
`
`Page 2 of 12
`
`Page 2 of 12
`
`

`

`Direct to Consumer Advertising and Prescription Choice ∗
`
`Toshiaki Iizuka† Ginger Z. Jin‡
`
`Abstract
`
`This paper examines the effect of direct-to-consumer advertising (DTCA) of prescription
`
`drugs on doctor choice of drug brands. Using antihistamines as an example, we show that
`
`DTCA has little effect on the choice of brand despite the massive DTCA expenditure incurred
`
`in this class. In contrast, promotional activities directed to physicians have a larger and long-
`
`lasting effects. These results, together with the market-expanding results shown in Iizuka
`
`and Jin (2005), suggest that DTCA is effective in increasing the aggregate demand per
`
`therapeutic class but does not affect doctor choice of prescription within a class. Therefore,
`
`DTCA may be viewed as a public good for all drugs in the same class.
`
`1
`
`Introduction
`
`Traditionally, prescription drugs were marketed towards doctors, and direct-to-consumer adver-
`tising (DTCA) was limited. This is partly because DTCA on TV was prohibitively expensive:
`prior to 1997, any DTCA that contained both brand name and medical claims must disclose a
`“brief summary” of drug effectiveness, side effects, and contraindications. As a result, TV ads
`with these details were long and costly. In August 1997, the Food and Drug Administration
`(FDA) clarified that pharmaceutical firms can advertise brand name and indications on TV
`without a “brief summary.”1 Following the clarification, DTCA expenditures increased substan-
`tially from $800 million in 1996 to $2.5 billion in 2000, which created an intensive debate on the
`
`∗† Graduate School of International Management, Aoyama Gakuin University. Email: toshi.iizuka@gmail.com
`‡Department of Economics, University of Maryland & NBER. Email:
`jin@econ.umd.edu. We wish to thank
`Thomas Hubbard, Scott Stern, Timothy Hannan, Judy Hellerstein, Bill Evans, Seth Sanders, John Rust, Robert
`Maness, and the participants at the NBER 2003 IO meeting for constructive comments and suggestions. Also
`thank Kathryn Aikon for helping us interpret the FDA rules, and Catherine Burt for guiding our usage of the
`NAMCS data. The first author acknowledges grants from Grants-in-Aid for Scientific Research, Japan Society of
`Promotion of Science. All errors remain ours.
`1DTCA still needs to include a “major statement” of the most important risks and refer consumers to other
`
`sources for more comprehensive information.
`
`1
`
`Page 3 of 12
`
`

`

`effects of DTCA. Proponents of DTCA emphasize the educational value of DTCA: many chronic
`diseases are under-diagnosed and under-treated, and DTCA can inform potential patients of the
`existence of such medical treatment. Opponents argue, however, DTCA may mislead patients
`into demanding heavily-advertised drugs, leading to inappropriate drug use and unnecessary
`purchase of expensive drugs.2
`
`To understand the effects of DTCA on pharmaceutical demand, it is useful to consider
`the impact of DTCA in two steps.
`In the first step, DTCA may inform the public of the
`existence of the medication and thereby bring potential patients to the doctor. If true, DTCA
`expands the prescription drug market. Second, after the patient visits the doctor, DTCA may
`affect the doctor’s prescription choice. For example, a patient who watched a TV commercial
`of a prescription drug may persuade the doctor to prescribe the medicine, even if it is not the
`appropriate one. Clearly, proponents of DTCA stress the potential benefit from the first step,
`and opponents of DTCA are concerned about the harm generated by the second step.
`
`Our previous study (Iizuka and Jin, 2005) examined the first step by combining 1994
`– 2000 drug-specific DTCA data with the 1995 – 2000 National Ambulatory Medical Care
`Surveys (NAMCS) and found that higher DTCA expenditures were associated with increased
`doctor visits. This paper contributes to the debate by examining the second step, i.e., whether
`DTCA affects physician prescription choice once the patient visits a doctor. We focus on the
`prescription of non-sedating antihistamines, one of the most heavily DTC-advertised classes.
`Utilizing the data above, we estimate a discrete choice model. We allow advertising to last
`long and estimate depreciation rates for the four types of promotional expenditures – detailing,
`medical journal advertising, free samples, and DTCA (the first three target doctors). We find
`that DTCA has a positive but not statistically significant effect on specific brand choices. In
`contrast, advertising directed to doctors has a much larger and long-lasting effect on the choice
`of prescription. Thus, the primary role of DTCA appears to bring potential patients to the
`doctor but not to affect the choice of prescription.
`
`This paper contributes to the small, but growing literature that analyzes the demand
`effects of DTCA.3 Most of the existing evidence is based on aggregate data. Calfee et al. (2002)
`didn’t find a significant effect of DTCA on new Statin prescriptions or renewals. Rosenthal et al.
`(2003) examined the aggregate sales data of five therapeutic classes and found that DTCA has a
`significant effect on total class sales but not on market shares within each class. Narayanan et al.
`(2004) examined the effect of DTCA and other marketing efforts on allergy prescriptions. They
`found that DTCA increases both category sales and brand share, but the latter effect is weaker
`
`2Both sides of the debate are well documented. See Holmer (1999) and Holmer (2002) for a summary of the
`
`proponent’s position, and Hollon (1999) and Wolfe (2002) for a summary of the opponent’s position.
`3Even a smaller collection of literature exists on the supply side of DTCA. This includes Rosenthal et al.
`
`(2002) and Iizuka (2004).
`
`2
`
`Page 4 of 12
`
`

`

`than that of detailing. While closely related, our paper is different from the above references
`because we use patient-level prescription data rather than aggregated market-level data. The
`advantage of individual data is that we can control for various patient-doctor attributes such as
`age, gender, race, insurance status, and physician specialty. Consumer and doctor heterogeneity
`could drive the effect of advertising on aggregate market shares, but it is difficult for an analysis
`using aggregated data to control for such heterogeneity.
`
`A working paper by Wosinska (2002) is probably the closest to ours. Using individual claim
`data from Blue Cross of California, she examined the impact of DTCA on the prescriptions of
`cholesterol-reducing drugs. She found that DTCA has a small but significant impact on the
`demand if the brand is on the formulary. Aside from examining a different therapeutic class,
`this paper is different from Wosinska’s in two ways: first, we use national representative data and
`control for various patient and doctor characteristics, which is difficult to achieve by using claim
`data from a single insurer. More importantly, we allow four types of promotional expenditures
`to depreciate over time and estimate a separate depreciation rate for each. By this, we can
`distinguish the instant impact of advertising from the effect that lasts over time.
`
`2 Data
`
`We combine individual-level data from NAMCS and brand-level advertising data for non-
`sedating antihistamines from TNS Media Intelligence/ Competitive Media Reporting (CMR)
`and IMS Health. NAMCS provides a national representative sample of individual visits to
`office-based physicians. For each office visit, it includes the month of visit, patient demograph-
`ics, insurance status, physician specialty, and prescription choices, if any.4 Monthly DTCA
`expenditure data from 1994 to 2001 is obtained from CMR. CMR monitors advertising ex-
`penditures in several media, including network TV, cable TV, newspapers, and magazines. In
`addition to DTCA, pharmaceutical firms promote their drugs via professional channels targeting
`physicians. This includes detailing, medical journal advertising, and free samples. From IMS
`Health, we obtain monthly data from July 1997 to December 2001 and annual data from 1994
`to 1997. Our analysis focus on the visits that occurred between July 1997 and December 2001,
`but we use prior advertising data to construct advertising stock (see Section 3 for more detail).
`
`Since NAMCS doesn’t collect information on prescription copays, we obtain corresponding
`monthly wholesale price from IMS Health. We compute patient-day price based on the sales
`dollars and quantity sold for each drug. We note that the wholesale price is not ideal since
`this may poorly correlate with the patient’s copay, but this is the best we can do for a national
`representative sample. Aware of this caveat, we use the wholesale price as a proxy control and
`
`4See Cherry et al. (2001) for more detailed description of NAMCS.
`
`3
`
`Page 5 of 12
`
`

`

`do not interpret its impact as price elasticity. All data are matched by drug names and by the
`month of visit.
`
`The drug class we examine is the non-sedating antihistamines. We focus our attention to
`the second-generation non-sedating antihistamines, i.e., Claritin, Zyrtec, and Allegra. Neither
`generic nor over-the-counter (OTC) versions of these drugs were available during the time period
`of our data.5 Historically, this class also included Seldane and Hismanal. We didn’t include them
`in the data set primarily because we observe them very infrequently. However, we included
`a Hismanal withdrawal dummy in the estimation in order to control for the possibility that
`doctor preference on Claritin, Zyrtec and Allegra might have changed after the withdrawal of
`Hismanal.6 In total, we observe 2,545 patient-visits between July 1997 and 2001, which resulted
`in the prescription of one of the three allergy drugs. These patients correspond to 1,151 unique
`doctor identities, implying that on average we observe 2.21 patient-visits per doctor.
`
`Non-sedating antihistamine is one of the most heavily advertised classes using direct-to-
`consumer channels. However, the use of DTCA differs somewhat among the three drugs, which
`allows us to identify the effects of advertising on the choice of prescription drugs. While Claritin
`is clearly the leader in DTCA expenditures in this class (see Figure 1), this does not appear to
`have helped increase or maintain its market share: Claritin’s market share has declined since
`1997 regardless of the large amount of DTCA (see Figure 2). This suggests that DTCA may
`not have a strong impact on the physician’s prescription choice. Table 1 reports descriptive
`statistics.
`
`3 The Model
`
`If a physician maintains her authority to choose a drug, DTCA may encourage people “to seek
`medical help,” but may not influence brand choice. On the other hand, if DTCA enables patients
`to “persuade” the physician to prescribe what they want, DTCA may have a positive effect on
`brand choice. To distinguish these arguments, we estimate demand for prescription drugs using
`a conditional logit model. Specifically, we assume that physician k chooses a drug j for patient
`i at time t, among J alternatives, which maximizes the objective function represented by Vijkt:
`
`mA(m)
`δx
`j(t−x)]
`
`t−tj0
`
`X x
`
`=0
`=1
`5Claritin switched to the OTC market in 2002, and Clarinex entered the market also in 2002.
`6Although Seldane was not officially withdrawn from the market until February 1998, FDA had proposed
`
`[βm ·
`
`4X m
`
`max
`j∈J
`
`Vijkt =
`
`removing Seldane from the marketplace as early as January 1997 (FDA 1997). Since our analysis starts from
`
`July 1997, we believe the impact of Seldane withdrawal is minimal. Hismanal was introduced to the market in
`
`January 1998 and withdrawn on June 21, 1999. Hismanal withdrawal dummy equals one after July 1999.
`
`4
`
`Page 6 of 12
`
`

`

`+ βX Xjt + βP Pjt + βjY Yit + βjH Hkt + βjW Wt + ekjt + ǫijt.
`
`We distinguish four types of promotional expenditures in Ajt: DTCA, detailing, professional
`journal advertising, and free samples. This allows us to separately examine the impact of
`different promotional devices available for pharmaceutical firms. Because the effect of advertising
`may last more than one month, for each type of advertising, we model the advertising stock as
`a sum of the flows from the month of drug entry (tj0) to the month under study (t) with a
`constant depreciation rate δ per month. We estimate a separate δ for each type of advertising.7
`
`As for the other terms, Xjt is a vector of product characteristics including both drug
`dummies and the age of the drug, Pjt is the wholesale price, Yit is a vector of patient i’s
`attributes including insurance status (i.e. Medicare, Medicaid, private insurance and self-pay)
`and demographics (i.e. age, gender and race), Hkt is a vector of physician k’s specialty (i.e.
`family practice, internal medicine, and all others), and Wt is a dummy set to one after Hismanal
`withdrawal. We allow the effects of Yit, Hkt, and Wt to be drug specific, which effectively
`captures individual heterogeneity.
`
`The error term consists of two parts: ekjt denotes physician k’s unobserved preference for
`drug j, and ǫijt is the logit error independent across patients. We treat ekjt as random effects
`that conform to a normal distribution with an unknown variance.8 In doing so, we capture the
`unobserved correlation among the patients that have seen the same doctor.9
`
`To obtain parameter values, we write down the likelihood function and maximize it by
`using the NLMIXED procedure in SAS. The procedure employs a dual quasi-Newton algorithm
`and adaptive Gaussian quadrature to allow for random effects (by physician identity) in the
`non-linear specification of conditional logit. Since there is a possibility for diminishing returns
`to advertising, we have also tried log(Ajt) or the quadratic term of Ajt instead of linear Ajt.
`Since the main results never change, we only report those with linear Ajt.
`
`There are some concerns that the advertising variables of our interest are endogenous
`in the sense that they could be correlated with aggregate demand shocks such as changes in
`
`7To construct advertising stock, we need data prior to July 1997. For DTCA, we have monthly DTCA
`
`expenditure data between January 1994 and June 1997. For professional advertising variables, we have annual
`
`data between 1994 and 1997 and monthly data after July 1997. To accommodate the seasonal nature of the disease
`
`and corresponding advertising expenditures, we allocate the annual data between 1994 and 1997 to each month
`
`using the observed pattern of advertising spending between 1998 and 2001. Specifically, for each advertising type,
`
`we compute the average expenditure share of each month between 1998-2001 and apply them to 1994-1997 data.
`8Precisely, there are two variance terms, one for Zyrtec and one for Allegra (Claritin is the comparison group).
`9Aside from doctor clustering, one may also be concerned about unobserved correlations within the same drug-
`
`month. To our knowledge, the econometric literature has not provided a universal solution for double clustering,
`
`and we believe doctor-clustering is more appropriate in this context.
`
`5
`
`Page 7 of 12
`
`

`

`demographics. This is particularly problematic in the studies that use aggregate sales data,
`where individual attributes are not observed. Fortunately, micro-level data we use allows us to
`include extensive interactions between patient/doctor characteristics and drug dummies, thus
`alleviating the problem.10 Moreover, advertising expenditures are usually determined three to
`four months ahead of time, so it is less likely that the simultaneity problem (or reverse causality)
`biases the estimates.
`
`4 Empirical Results
`
`We present the results in two tables: Table 2 reports the coefficients by advertising, individual
`characteristics, physician characteristics, and the timing of Hismanal withdrawal. Based on these
`estimates, Table 3 reports the marginal effect of increasing each type of advertising expenditure
`of drug j on the probability of prescribing drug j.
`
`Our main interest lies in the four types of promotional activities. As shown in Table 2,
`the coefficient for DTCA is not statistically different from zero, suggesting that, regardless of
`the massive DTCA campaign on allergy drugs, DTCA has no significant impact on physician’s
`prescription choices.11 This contrasts with the results in Iizuka and Jin (2005) that DTCA
`increases visits to physicians substantially. Interestingly, the coefficients for detailing promotion
`and medical journal advertising are positive and weakly significant, suggesting that prescription
`choices are influenced by the promotional efforts targeted at doctors. These results suggest that
`consumer-directed and professional-directed advertising play quite different roles in promoting
`prescription drugs; while DTCA increases patients visits to doctors, professional advertising
`affects the doctor’s prescription choice. The third type of professional advertising – free samples
`– appears to have little impact on prescription choice.
`
`The marginal effects reported in Table 3 paint a more detailed picture: calculated at the
`sample average (weighted), the marginal effects suggest that increasing drug j’s DTCA by $1
`million in a month has a positive but insignificant effect on the probability of prescribing drug
`j in that month. This result is similar across all the three drugs. In comparison, one-million-
`
`10Some previous studies in this area (e.g., Berndt et al., 1995 and Iizuka and Jin, 2005) have used the instruments
`
`of the type “DTCA for the firm in unrelated classes.” This strategy was difficult to implement in this case
`
`because the correlation between allergy advertising and the same firm’s advertising in other classes is not strong.
`
`For example, Claritin accounts for most of Schering Plough’s advertising budget and this leads to a very weak
`
`correlation between the ads expenditure of Claritin and Schering Plough’s 18 other products.
`11The result that the coefficient on DTCA is insignificant may have two interpretations: first, the true effect is
`
`indistinguishable from zero; second, our estimates are imprecise. Since the data have more variations in DTCA
`
`than in the other advertising variables, we suspect the first interpretation is more plausible.
`
`6
`
`Page 8 of 12
`
`

`

`dollar increase in Claritin detailing would enhance the probability of prescribing Claritin by
`10.9% (with standard error 5.39%). Similarly, one-million-dollar increase of journal advertising
`would lead to significantly more prescriptions in Claritin and Zyrtec, but not Allegra.
`
`The estimated depreciation rates reported in Table 2 suggest that professional advertising
`lasts longer, while DTCA is short-lived. These depreciation rates are estimated precisely except
`that the coefficient on DTCA is not statistically different from zero and the DTCA depreciation
`reaches the lower bound of zero. These estimates suggest, for example, the effect of detail-
`ing reduces to 87.4% after one month and 66.8% after three months, but DTCA depreciates
`completely within a month.12
`
`Since DTCA not only has a weaker impact in the current month, but also depreciates
`much faster in the following months, the overall effect of DTCA is substantially weaker than
`that of professional advertising. To give an example, suppose an average firm increases detailing
`promotion by $1 million in a specific month (at the mean of all observed variables). This
`investment increases the cumulative stock of detailing promotion over the next 12 months by
`$6.36 million.13 If another firm tries to use DTCA to offset the business-stealing effect created
`by the first firm’s detailing, this firm would have to increase DTCA by as much as $14.93 million
`in the same month.14 This shows that the business-stealing effect of DTCA is much weaker than
`that of detailing. The same argument goes for professional journal advertising.
`
`The other coefficients also provide insights into the demand for allergy drugs. The co-
`efficient for price suggests that prescription choices are not sensitive to the wholesale price.
`As noted before, however, this may be because our price measure correlates poorly with the
`patient’s out-of-pocket costs. Dummy variables corresponding to Allegra and Zyrtec are not
`different from zero, suggesting that the efficacy of the three drugs are similar. The interaction
`between Allegra and Hismanal withdrawal dummy is insignificant, suggesting that doctor pref-
`erence between Allegra and Claritin did not change after the withdrawal. The same results hold
`for Zyrtec. Also, estimates suggest that women are less likely to receive Claritin relative to men,
`and older age increases the probability of receiving Allegra relative to Claritin and Zyrtec, in
`order. Relating to insurance status, Claritin is more popular among privately insured patients.
`Within Medicaid patients, Allegra is less preferred relative to Claritin and Zyrtec.15
`
`12In a related research, Berndt et al. (2003) reports that, using aggregate data for antiulcer drugs, the effect of
`
`detailing reduces to 95% after one month.
`131 + 0.874 + 0.8742 + .. + 0.87411 = 6.359.
`14We obtain this result as follows. First, if one spends $1 million in DTCA in a specific month, the cumulative
`
`stock of this DTCA over the next 12 months is still $1 million. Using the coefficients reported in Table 2, we can
`
`compute the necessary DTCA expenditures to offset detailing advertising as 6.359/1 ∗ 0.4425/0.1885 = 14.93.
`15However, we should be cautious because NAMCS collects information on the type of insurance that most
`
`likely covers the visit, not the resulting prescription.
`
`7
`
`Page 9 of 12
`
`

`

`5 Discussion
`
`If we integrate the results shown above and the results from Iizuka and Jin (2005), DTCA seems
`effective in increasing aggregate demand per therapeutic class but does not affect doctor choice of
`prescription within a class. This suggests that the effect of DTCA is primarily market-expanding
`rather than business-stealing. Thus, DTCA may be viewed as a public good for all drugs in the
`same class. In this section, we provide supply-side evidence that supports this argument.
`
`If DTCA is a public good, one may immediately ask why drug firms do not simply free ride
`on others’ advertising efforts. Which companies, if any, have incentives to use DTCA given the
`nature of the advertising? To consider these questions, note that even if the public-good nature
`of DTCA does not allow an advertising company to reap the full benefits, the company may
`still find it worthwhile to advertise if the absolute effect of market-expansion is large enough.
`This suggests that companies with larger market shares are more likely to use DTCA, since they
`benefit more from the increased market size. Moreover, we would also expect that there is a
`cut-off point below which low-market share firms do not advertise at all. In fact, we can obtain
`a crude estimate on this threshold using the results from Iizuka and Jin (2005). In that paper,
`we reported that every $28 DTCA after 1997 would generate one patient visit in the next 12
`months. This implies that if one extra visit generates one prescription, consumer compliance
`rate is 60%, and every filled prescription implies $80 profits for the drug manufacturer, the
`manufacturer will advertise as long as its market share is over 58.3%.16
`
`To check these predictions, we look at all therapeutic classes included in NAMCS and
`examine which firms use DTCA more intensively. Here, we implicitly assume that the public
`good argument applies to all therapeutic classes, although our analysis up to this point focuses on
`antihistamines. The assumption is consistent with the existing evidence that DTCA has a much
`smaller or no impact on prescription choice relative to detailing (e.g., Rosenthal et al. (2003),
`Wosinska (2002)). We match the DTCA data for all prescription drugs obtained from CMR and
`NAMCS by drug name and year of visit. Since NAMCS is a national representative, we use the
`weight it assigns to each individual visit to compute the market share of each prescription drug
`in its drug class, where drug class is defined by the 4-digit National Drug Code as of 2000.
`
`Table 3 tabulates yearly DTCA expenditure by whether a drug’s market share within its
`class was 0-20%, 20-40%, 40-60%, or 60+% in the previous year. Using data covering between
`1995 and 2000, the table shows that drugs with market shares 40% or higher in the previous
`year spent a lot more on DTCA per drug-year than those with smaller market shares. Put more
`crudely, the propensity of DTCA increases dramatically with market share: for drugs with 20%
`or less market shares in year t-1, only 3.7% advertise in year t. In contrast, for drugs with 60+%
`
`16That is, 28/(80 ∗ 0.6) = 0.583.
`
`8
`
`Page 10 of 12
`
`

`

`market shares, 19% advertise. If restricted to the classes that ever used DTCA, a drug with a
`60+% market share on average accounts for 69% of the total DTCA expenditure in its class,
`while a drug with a 20-% market share only contributes 4%.17
`
`This supports the argument that “larger” drugs benefit more from the market-expanding
`effects of DTCA, and therefore have more incentives to advertise than their “smaller” competi-
`tors within the same therapeutic class. Thus, the supply-side evidence is consistent with the
`demand side results that DTCA may be viewed as a public good in a therapeutic class.
`
`6 Conclusion
`
`This paper examines the effect of DTCA on doctor choice of prescription drugs. Using antihis-
`tamines as an example, we show that DTCA has little effect on the choice of brand despite the
`massive DTCA expenditure incurred in this class. In contrast, we find that direct-to-physician
`advertising (i.e., detailing and medical journal advertising) has a larger and long-lasting effect
`on prescription choice. These results, together with the market expanding results shown in
`Iizuka and Jin (2005), suggest that DTCA is effective in increasing the aggregate demand per
`therapeutic class but does not affect doctor choice of prescription within a class. Therefore,
`DTCA may be viewed as a public good for all drugs in the same class. Regarding the debate on
`the effect of DTCA, our results support the view of proponents that DTCA has little impact on
`the choice of prescription once the patient arrives at the physician office. We note, however, that
`welfare implications are far reaching, partly because our model does not consider the potential
`substitution between the antihistamines we examine and other alternatives such as non-drug
`treatments and over-the-counter medications.
`
`7 References
`
`Berndt, E.R., L. Bui, D.R. Reiley, and G.L. Urban [1995]: ”Information, Marketing, and Pricing in the
`
`US Antiulcer Drug Market,” American Economic Review, 85(2), pp. 100-105.
`
`Berndt, E.R., R.S. Pindyck, and P. Azoulay [2003]: ”Consumption Externalities and Diffusion in Phar-
`
`maceutical Markets: Antiulcer Drugs,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 51(2), pp. 243-270.
`
`Calfee, J., C. Winston, and R. Stempski [2002]: ”Direct-to-Consumer Advertising and the Demand for
`
`Cholesterol-reducing Drugs” Journal of Law and Economics, pp. 673-690.
`
`17All these patterns are robust if we estimate regression models, controlling for drug class fixed effects and
`
`common year dummies.
`
`9
`
`Page 11 of 12
`
`

`

`Cherry, D.K., C.W. Burt, D.A. Woodwell [2001]: “National Ambulatory Medical Care Survey: 1999
`
`Summary” downloaded at www.cdc.gov.
`
`Food and Drug Administration (FDA) [1997]:”FDA Proposes to Withdraw Seldane Approval” FDA
`
`Talk Paper T97-3, Jan. 13, 1997.
`
`Hollon, M.F. [1999]: “Direct-to-Consumer Marketing of Prescription Drugs” Journal of American Med-
`
`ical Association, January 27, Vol 281, No. 4.
`
`Holmer, A. [1999]: “Direct-to-Consumer Prescription Drug Advertising Builds Bridges Between Patients
`
`and Physicians” Journal of American Medical Association, January 27, Vol 281, No. 4.
`
`Holmer, A. [2002]: “Direct-to-Consumer Advertising – Strengthening Our Health Care System” New
`
`England Journal of Medicine, February 14, Vol. 346, No. 7.
`
`Iizuka, T. [2004]: “What Explains the Use of Direct-to-Consumer Advertising of Prescription Drugs?”
`
`Journal of Industria

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket