throbber
Lessons from the Commercialization
`of the Cohen-Beyer Patents:
`The Stanford University Licensing Program
`MARYANN P. FELDMAN. 1\1zfler Dzstznguzshed Proftssor zn Hzgher Educatzon.
`institute ofHzgher Fducatzon. Unwersity of Georgia. U:S.A.
`ALES SANDRA COLAIANNI, Center for Genome Ethics, Law, and Policy, Duke Univmity, U.S.A.
`CONNIE KANG LIU, Joseph L. Rotman School of1vfanagement, University ofToronto, Canada
`
`ABSTRACT
`The Cohen-Boyer licensing program, by any variety
`of mctrics, was widely successful. Recombinant DNA
`(rONA) products provided a new technology platform
`for a range of industries, resulting in over US$35 hil(cid:173)
`l ion in sales for an estimated 2,442 new products. Over
`rhe duration of the life of rhe parents (they expired in
`December I'J9/), rhe rechnolo8Y was licensed to 46R
`companies, many of them fledgling biotech companies
`who used the licenses to establish their legitimacy. Over
`the 25 years of the licensing program, Stanford and the
`C"niversity of California system accrued US$255 million
`in licensing revenues (ro the end of200 1 ), much of which
`was subsequently invested in research and research infra(cid:173)
`structure. In n"lany V\'ays, Stanford's n1anagen"lent of the
`Cohen-Buyer parents has become the gold standard for
`universiry technology licensing. Stanford made pragmatic
`decisions and was flexible, adapting its licensing strategies
`as circwnstances changed.
`
`INTRODUCTION
`1.
`The licensing of the Cohen-Buyer patents by
`StanfurJ University represents one of the must
`successful university
`technology licenses. The
`Jiscovery covers the technique of recombinant
`DNA and allows for the useful rnanipulaiion of
`genetic material. Examining StanfurJ's licensing
`of the intellectual property is best understood
`in comext and as part of the university's larger
`strategy. Moreover, designing and setting up the
`licensing program involved uncharted territory at
`
`that time. The first patent issued on December
`2, 1980, after 6 years under review at the U.S.
`Patent and Trademark Office: the original appli(cid:173)
`cation was filed in November 1974. This dare was
`two weeks before the effective date of the Bayh(cid:173)
`Dole Act, which assigned intellectual property
`(IP) riglns over facull y Jiscuveries from feJerall y
`funded research to universicies and emphasized
`the university's responsibility for commercializa(cid:173)
`tion. 1 The intention was to provide a means for
`economic growth, technological change, and en(cid:173)
`hanced U.S. competitiveness.
`The Cohen and Boyer's discovery provided
`tools for generic engineering and was rhe subject of
`comroversy that led to a lively public debate dur(cid:173)
`ing the decade of the 1970s. Sally Smith Hughes
`documents Cohen and Boyer's scientific discovery,
`Stanford's decision to pursue patents, and the pub(cid:173)
`lic controversies surrounding recombinant DNA. 2
`The debate was symbolically resolved with the June
`1980 U.S. Supreme Court ruling on Diamond v
`C'hakrabarty, a landmark 5-4 Jecisiun, which
`made the patenting of life forms possible with che
`Court's oft-quoted clause, "anything under the sun,
`that is made by man." This decision cleared the way
`for the Cohen-Boyer application, which covered a
`fundamental technique, with the potential to be(cid:173)
`come a platform technology rhar essentially led ro
`a new paradigm in hiorech research.
`
`Feldman MP, A Colaianni and C Liu. 2007 Lessons from the Commercialization oft he Cohen-Boyer Patents: The Stanford
`Untversity Licensing Program. In fntef!ectual Property Management in Health and Agricultural innovation: A Handbook of
`Best Practices (eds A Krattiger, RT Mahoney, L Nelsen, et al.) Ml HR: Oxford, U.K, and PIPRA: Davis, U.S.A. Available online at
`www.1 pHandbook.org.
`
`CCJ ?007 MP Felrlmen, A roiCJienni CJnrltl itL Sharing the Artnf!P Manogement Photocorying end rlistrihution through the
`Internet for noncommercial purposes is permitted and encouraged.
`
`HANDBOOK OF BEST PRACTICES ]1797
`
`Sanofi/Regeneron Ex. 1 043, pg 1 067
`
`Merck Ex. 1043, pg 1093
`
`

`
`FELDMAN, COLAIANNI & LIU
`
`Of course, once rhe patent was granted,
`Stanford University, as rhe assignee, was required
`to design a licensing program that would be con(cid:173)
`sistent with the public-service mission of the
`university and provide sufficient incentives for
`private industry w invest the requisite resources
`to bring products to market while producing rev(cid:173)
`enue for the university. Feldman, Colaianni and
`Liu1 detail the hiswry of Stanford's licensing pro(cid:173)
`gram, focusing on the process and the logic that
`guided the commercialization regime. Given the
`early controversy surrounding rhc Cohen-Boyer
`patem, the eventual success required a great deal
`of creadvity, strategy, and persistence. Certainly,
`the professionals involved all cunrribured to the
`success, from Donald Kennedy, then president of
`Stanford, Robert Rosenzweig, then vice president
`for public affairs, Nils Reimer, founding direcror
`of the Stanford Office of Technology Licensing
`(OTL) Lo KaLheriue Ku, Lheu licemiug assuciale
`and current director of the OTL.
`The purpose of this chapter is to summa(cid:173)
`rize lessons learned from Stanford's design and
`implementation of the Cohen-Buyer licensing
`program. Many universities attempt to emulate
`Stanford University's success at technology trans(cid:173)
`fer; however, there is a limited appreciation for
`the high degree of creativity and adaprability of
`the Stanford Office ufTechnulugy and Licensing
`(OTL) in setting up its licensing program and
`maldng the myriad decisions that guided the
`ultimate outcome. In spite of many obstacles,
`Stanford University pursued the recombinant
`DNA patents and designed a strategy that met the
`public-service goals of the university by broadly
`licensing the technology; provided incemives for
`private companies to commercialize derivative
`products; and contributed to the creation of an
`innovation system that benefited Silicon Valley
`and reached across the American economy.
`
`2. A LIST OF LESSONS LEARNED FROM
`COHEN-BOYER
`
`2.1 Keep wider university goals in mind
`Despite the economic success of the licensing
`program, profit was not the primary morive.
`
`Stanford University had four goals rhar guided
`the development of the Cohen-Boyer license:
`to be consistent with the public-service ide(cid:173)
`als of rhe university
`to provide the appropriate incentives in
`order that genetic engineering technology
`could be commercialized for public benefit
`in an adequare and timely manner
`to manage the technology in order to mini(cid:173)
`mize the potential for biohazard
`to provide income fur educational and re(cid:173)
`search purposes
`
`•
`
`Robert Rosenzweig, vice presidem for public
`affairs at Stanford, in a 1976 open letter addressed
`to "Those Interested in Recombinant D1VA," wrote
`"It is a fact that the financing of private uniwrsi(cid:173)
`ties is more difficult now than at any time in re(cid:173)
`cent memory and that the most likely prediction for
`the future i> that a hard >truggle will be required tv
`maintctin their quttlity." As a result of these finan(cid:173)
`cial concerns, he concluded, "we cannot lightly
`discttrd the possibility of significant income thttt is
`derived from activity that is legal, ethical, and not
`destructive of the values of the institution."
`The balance of financial objectives against
`other goals is further demonstrated when Stanford
`decided not to pursue extending the patent life.
`The uriginal197 4 patent application had claimed
`both the process of maldng recombinam DNA
`and any producrs that resulted from using that
`merhod. These applications were subsequently di(cid:173)
`vided into the process patent and rwo divisional
`product applications: one claimed recombinant
`DNA products produced in prokaryotic cells
`and the other claimed the products in eukaryotic
`cells. Stanford filed a terminal disclaimer, which
`meant that all subsequent applications claiming
`recombinant DNA, regardless of how long the
`patem prosecution process took, would expire
`on December 2, 1997-thc same date as the
`original 191l0 parent. 4 Tn effect, Stanford agreed
`to give up royalty rights on the life of the sub(cid:173)
`sequent patents (issued in l 984 and l 988) that
`would have extended pasr rhe original patent's
`expiration dare. This limired Stanford's collection
`of royalties because of rhe time delay inherem in
`commercialization, especially of pharmaceutical
`
`1798 I HANDBOOK OF BEST PRACTICES
`
`Sanofi/Regeneron Ex. 1 043, pg 1 068
`
`Merck Ex. 1043, pg 1094
`
`

`
`CHAPTER 17.22
`
`products. Stanford honored its obligation to the
`licensees wich che realization chat, as Kathy Ku
`wrote ac che time " ... it would not be good public
`policy orpubtic relations if we were to ask for or even
`get such an extension."
`Stanford did not require other nonprofit re(cid:173)
`search instimtions to take a license in order to usc
`the technology. Niels Reimers and Kathy Ku re(cid:173)
`port that the thought oflicensing the technology
`out to other nonprofit research institutions had
`never entered into discussiuns about the licens(cid:173)
`ing program. This licensing practice estahlished a
`research exemption, or research-use exemption,
`which is consistent with the norms of open sci(cid:173)
`ence,5 and stands in contrast to recent develop(cid:173)
`ments in research-usc exemption policies, such as
`Duke u. Madey and che \VARF stem-cell licens(cid:173)
`ing program."
`To summarize, engaging in commercial ac(cid:173)
`Livily encourage~ higher educalion iusLiluLions lo
`act like for-profit entities. lntellectual property
`has no value unless ic is defended. Stanford set up
`a litigation reserve fund that provides a credible
`threat of enforcement of the license. Despire sev(cid:173)
`eral attcmprs to withhold payments from a variety
`of large and small companies plus one attorney
`who made challenges to the patents a "hobby,"
`Stanford was able to settle these disputes infor(cid:173)
`mally and without formal litigation. This stands
`in contrast to the recent upswing in litigation by
`U.S. universities. including a recent law suit filed
`by the University of Alabama to prevent an artist
`from using the universities athletic colors.
`
`2.2 Consult widely to build consensus
`While imdlectual property typically involves
`limited disclosure, Stanford University engaged
`in a partern of consulting widely across various
`stakeholders to achieve consensus and to ensure
`that its actions were supported. For example,
`Rosenzweig worked to achieve consensus with
`both the faculty and the National Institutes of
`Health (NIH) as the sponsoring agency. In a 1976
`open letter, he asked the faculty to comment on
`whether the university should proceed with the
`patent process. Rosenzweig also sent a letter to
`Donald Fredrickson, NIH director. asking his
`opinion on patenting the Cohen-Boyer discovery
`
`and enclosed a copy of the memorandum sent to
`faculty. Fredrickson responded by sending a mass
`mailing to "a broad range of individuals and insti(cid:173)
`tutions," asking them for their comments on the
`patent question. 7 Fredrickson's letter laid out five
`possible alternatives that NII I could take regard(cid:173)
`ing recombinant DNJ\. patenting and subsequent
`licensing: In response, Fredrickson received ap(cid:173)
`proximately 50 lerters.
`J\. compromise consensus emerged from
`among a list that Frederickson generated that
`Stanford should be able to patent recombinant
`DNA research but with nonexclusive licensing.
`A nonexclusive license ran counter to economic
`logic, contrary to the subsequent preferences ar(cid:173)
`ticulated in the Bayh-Dolc, J\.ct and ignored peti(cid:173)
`tions from Genentech and Cetus who stood to
`gain from exclusive licenses. The logic was that
`eDNA was a platform technology and that any
`one company could nol exploiL all Lhe po~siGle
`applications. Broad nonexclusive licensing not
`only contributed to the economic success of the
`patents but also created a population of compa(cid:173)
`nies who drove the technology forward.
`There arc other instances when Stanford
`sought transparency that was consistent with the
`actions of a university. While applicants generally
`keep patent applications secret from the date they
`are filed until they are granted and therefore pro(cid:173)
`tected, Stanford opened the patent prosecution
`file to the public. This was an unusual move that
`was consistent with reducing subsequent ques(cid:173)
`tions about the technology and was also consis(cid:173)
`tent with the public mission of the university.
`Stanford engaged in an open process that at(cid:173)
`tempted to build consensus across a wide range
`of stakeholders. While the universiry did stand to
`profit from the licensing program, their actions
`were consistent with the university's larger and
`more traditional societal goals.
`
`2.3 Don't behave opportunistically
`The most successful university technology trans(cid:173)
`fer involves relationships that develop over time.
`Signing a licensing agreen1.ent represents a trans(cid:173)
`action that is a first step in a relationship that re(cid:173)
`quires maintenance and oversighr. Each licensee
`received an annual letter from the Stanford OTL.
`
`HANDBOOK OF BEST PRACTICES 11799
`
`Sanofi/Regeneron Ex. 1 043, pg 1 069
`
`Merck Ex. 1043, pg 1095
`
`

`
`FELDMAN, COLAIANNI & LIU
`
`That went a long way in esmblishing long-term
`relationships and encouraging dialogue.
`When Stanford initiated its licensing pro(cid:173)
`gram, no precedent existed for specific licensing
`terms of the IP. Keeping with its practice of con(cid:173)
`sulting widely and building consensus, Stanford
`interviewed a variety of companies representing
`different markets when the license terms, particu(cid:173)
`larly the royalty rates on end products, were be(cid:173)
`ing formulated. Through this effort, licenses were
`pre-sold and unrealistic terms were avoided. To
`make the licensing process easier, the OTL took
`great pains to categorize the different potential
`recombinant DNA products and to offer appro(cid:173)
`priate royalty rates. In the end, the OTL settled
`on four different product categories: basic genetic
`products, bulk products, end products, and pro(cid:173)
`cess improvement products. By scaling the rates
`to reflect the visibility of the licensee's product
`and Lhe expecled revenue from each license, Lhe
`OTL encouraged compliance. A graduated royal(cid:173)
`ty system ensured that smaller companies weren't
`penalized with low sales volume.
`Stanford made pragmatic decisions about
`pricing its intellectual property and kept the an(cid:173)
`nual fees and royalty rates reasonable. While this
`might have reflected a strategy to deal with some
`of the weaknesses with the patent, the university
`could have been greedy and pursued higher rates.
`Nils Reimers recalled at least one alumnus writ(cid:173)
`ing, "You've got a patent: you can dominate every(cid:173)
`thing here. Why are you cha1;rjng such a low royalty?
`You know Stanford could use the money. Charge a
`higher royalty." 8 This advice was nut taken. The
`rates that were chosen were selected after con(cid:173)
`sultation with industry about accepted practices
`and did not exploit the university's 1nonopoly
`position.
`Furthermore, Stanford created special provi(cid:173)
`sions for lower licensing fees and royalty rates for
`small firms in 1989. At this time, 209 fledging
`biotech firms, most of them in the San Francisco
`Bay Area, signed licensing agreements.
`
`2.4 Be flexible and experiment
`Over the 17 years of the licensing program
`Smntord experimented whh five versions of
`the standard license agreements and provided
`
`three special licensing agreements. A total of
`468 companies licensed the Cohen-Boyer tech(cid:173)
`nology. Licensing the patents was very much a
`learning process that balanced the capabilities of
`companies, especially in the embryonic biotech
`industry, with the economic potential of the
`technology. Ku later noted, "Stanford wtls try(cid:173)
`ing to license an inuention for which products had
`neuer been sold tlnd which would t~pply to milny
`diuerse, estt~blished industries, in t~ddition to the
`newly emerging biotechnology industry." 9 Table 1
`summarizes the various licensing regimes and
`the number of companies that signed up under
`each version. Certainly the economic impact
`would have been less without this flexibility and
`adjustments.
`The first version of the license provided two
`incentives to encourage companies to sign up.
`Remember that the technology was already in the
`public domain dnuugh publicaliuu and Lhal Lhe
`open patent files and companies were already us(cid:173)
`ing rDNA. It was not clear that companies would
`comply with the terms. 1he first incentive for
`companies to take a license in 1981 was a credit
`tmvard future royalties over the first five years,
`up to a total of US$300,000. The second incen(cid:173)
`tive came when companies were advised that
`the licensing terms would change and encour(cid:173)
`aged them to sign up early. In response to this
`news, 82 companies signed up. The largest share
`of earned royalties from product sales accrued to
`these firms. 10
`The first license's terms were a US$10,000
`up-front fcc with a minimum annual advance
`(MAA) of US$10,000. Earned royalty rates on
`products were provided on a graduated basis for
`bulk products, end product sales, and process irn.(cid:173)
`provements on existing products based on pro(cid:173)
`duction cost savings. Under the licensing agree(cid:173)
`ments, Stanford received unprecedented royalties
`on downstream drug sales in a stipulation known
`as reach-through I icensing: Stanford received end(cid:173)
`product royalties based on a percentage of final
`product sales. The Cohen-Boyer IP rights ex(cid:173)
`tended to all products developed using the tech(cid:173)
`nology. If companies did not sign a license agree(cid:173)
`mem, any end pro duns they developed that used
`rDNA could potentially be contested.
`
`1800 J HANDBOOK OF BEST PRACTICES
`
`Sanofi/Regeneron Ex. 1 043, pg 1 070
`
`Merck Ex. 1043, pg 1096
`
`

`
`TABLE 1: COHEN-BOYER STANDARD LICENSING AGREEMENTS HISTORY (IN U.S. dollars)
`
`CONTINUED ON NEXT PAGE
`
`Sanofi/Regeneron Ex. 1043, pg 1071
`
`I
`)> z
`0
`"' 0
`0
`"' ~
`"' m
`V>
`--<
`"" ~
`--< r;
`
`(")
`
`m
`V>
`
`00 s
`
`Merck Ex. 1043, pg 1097
`
`

`
`00
`0
`"-'
`
`I
`
`0
`
`)> z
`0
`"' 0
`"" Q
`"' m
`"' --< .,
`~ n
`--< a
`
`TABLE 1 (CONTINUED)
`
`R&D
`agreement
`
`Endof1994 Sign-uppayment
`waived;
`all future MAA as
`one-time payment
`
`N/A
`
`N/A
`
`NA
`
`36
`
`$553,083
`(0.22%)
`
`-,
`m
`
`?-
`
`~ )>
`8 s;
`)>
`z
`z
`11"
`
`' c
`
`Sanofi/Regeneron Ex. 1 043, pg 1 072
`
`Merck Ex. 1043, pg 1098
`
`

`
`CHAPTER 17.22
`
`The second standard licensing agreement
`dropped the royalty-credit incemive and an ad(cid:173)
`ditional 15 companies signed the agreement. In
`Augu~t 1985, the OTL is~ued it~ third ~tandard
`ver~ion of the license agreement, which allowed
`for negotiation by providing a space to write
`in agreed-upon rates. In practice, though, the
`earned-royalty rates were almost always at the
`same graduated rates that were used in the sec(cid:173)
`ond version. This fact may be attributed to the
`~haring of information among potential licensees
`about prevailing terms and what terms might be
`expected. Another ten firms signed up under this
`licensing agreement. Another adjustment was
`made in November 1986, with rhe fourth stan(cid:173)
`dard licensing agreement. Instead of a graduated(cid:173)
`royalty rate, a flat rate of 1 o/o on end products
`and 3% on bulk products was used. These were
`the highest rates under the prior version and re(cid:173)
`JlecLed Lhe realizaLiun d1al Lhe palenl~ could eam
`higher rates. In response, perhaps motivated by
`the possibility of further increases in the future,
`21 more firms signed licensing agreements. !he
`fifth version of the Cohen-Boyer standard licens(cid:173)
`ing agreemem, adopted in September 1989, dem(cid:173)
`onstrated further strategic changes. In order to
`encourage licensing by small stan-up companies,
`consideration of company size was introduced.
`For companies with fewer than 125 employees,
`the sign-up fee and MAA fee remained the same,
`at US$10,000 each. The strategy wotked-209
`small biotech firms became licensees under this
`version, along with 12 large companies.
`In addition to the ~candard agreement~, there
`were three nonstandard licensing agreement~ that
`provided alternative agreements, making sure
`that Stanford could collect as much revenue as
`po~sible withom being unfair to companie~ with
`special circumstances. The first was an alternative
`license for small distributors or resellers of recom(cid:173)
`binant DNA products. Fifty companies signed on
`under this alternative agreement, accounting for
`17.5 o/o of the total275 licensees signed after 1991
`and providing US$462,000 in licensing revenue.
`At the end of 1994, a research and development
`license agreement, with greatly reduced rates, was
`developed w encourage sran-ups chat would not
`realize product sales within the patent lifetime.
`
`Another 39 companies signed the research and
`developmem license agreemems, and, although
`these licenses did not yield much licensing
`revenue, they were important to the legitimacy of
`the ~mall companie~. A third nonstandard licens(cid:173)
`ing agreement was offered in the final year to tie
`up a few loose ends.
`In total, the Cohen-Boyer licenses generated
`US$254 million in revenue during its 17 -year
`term. The initial sign-up and annual fees generated
`US$26 million, which was 10% of the totallia:ns(cid:173)
`ing income. The licensing program certainly would
`have been less successful without these revisions
`and accommodations. A whopping 90% of the
`total revenue (US$228 million) was from royalty
`income from product sales. This mirrors the com(cid:173)
`mercial success of recombinant DNA products.
`
`2.5 Technology transfer is all
`about skewed distributions
`While ochers have noted that the distribution of
`technology transfer revenues are highly skewed,
`with a few blockbusters accounting for most rev(cid:173)
`enues, our examination of the companies that
`licensed the recombinant DNA technology and
`their products demonstrates that even within a
`single license, highly skewed outcomes account
`for the high revenues. Commercial products de(cid:173)
`veloped by the licensees generated over US$35
`billion dollars in sales of recombinant DNA
`produces over the life of the pacem. Stanford
`reported 2,442 products based on recombinant
`DNA by the time the Cohen-Royer parent ex(cid:173)
`pired in December 1997, reflecting a range uf ap(cid:173)
`plications in a variety of industrie~. u Starting in
`1991, 400 new products, on average, were being
`brought to the market every year. Recombinant
`DNA product sale~ reached US$500 million
`dollars in 1987 and then doubled from 1988 to
`1990. Sales doubled again from 1991 to 1994
`and yet again from 1994 to 1998.
`The revenue received from each of the Cohen(cid:173)
`Buyer licensees ranged from US$4.24 million to
`US$54.78 million dollars. Of the 468 licensees
`of Cohen-Boyer technology, ten companies alone
`provided 77% (US$197 million) of the total li(cid:173)
`censing income. One company, Amgen, account(cid:173)
`ed for over one-fifth of the total revenues received
`
`HANDBOOK OF BEST PRACTICES 11803
`
`Sanofi/Regeneron Ex. 1 043, pg 1 073
`
`Merck Ex. 1043, pg 1099
`
`

`
`FELDMAN, COLAIANNI & LIU
`
`under the licensing program. Figure 1 provides a
`breakdown of the royalty share provided by dif(cid:173)
`rerent companies.
`Table 2 li~t~ the~e ten companie~ and the
`product~ developed under the license. Many of
`the products were developed under strategic al(cid:173)
`liances between start-up biotech firms and large
`pharmaceutical firms, or between biotech firms.
`All of the top-ten companies, except l\1erck
`(which signed the agreement in 1984) signed the
`first standard agreement in December 1980. The
`next 10 companies accounted for another 10%,
`while the remaining companies generated less
`than 13% of total royalty revenue.
`
`3. CONCLUSIONS
`In the 1970s, universities became more entrepre(cid:173)
`neurial, looking for different streams of revenue
`LhaL supponed Lhe universiLy's mission. As a re(cid:173)
`sult, a new system of technology transfer emerged.
`Cenainly the Cohen-Boyer patents and Stanford
`University's licensing program were at the heart
`of the debate and central to the evolving system.
`
`It would be a mistake to look back at
`Stanford's success with the Cohen-Boyer licenses
`and think that its success was inevitable or that
`the licensing pruce~~ wa~ ea~y. An examination
`of history reveals many episodes where Stanford
`University could have behaved opportunistical(cid:173)
`ly or taken a wrong turn. The mistaken notion
`that Stanford and the University of California
`system were pursuing revenue as a primary goal
`ignores the controversies that faced Stanford at
`that time and the creativity and discipline that
`Stanford had to employ to surmount them.
`Stanford's licensing program is a good example,
`not just in terms of its monetary success, but
`in terms of the lessons it affords to others who
`work in the area of licensing and technology
`uansfer. \Vhile many universities have now in(cid:173)
`stimted licensing programs and are aggressively
`pursuing intellectual property rights, our study
`demomLraLes LhaL Lhis process is uol al all easy
`or straightforward. In retrospect, Stanford's li(cid:173)
`censing venture might have failed at several
`turns and Stanford was forced to be innova(cid:173)
`tive to accommodate rhe great uncertainties
`it faced. Had Stanford and the University of
`
`FIGURE 1: DISTRIBUTION OF ROYALTIES
`
`Others 13%
`
`Arngen 21.5%
`
`Next 1010%
`
`Chi ron
`
`Norvo Nordisk 3%
`
`Genentech 14%
`
`Schering 7%
`
`Source: Compiled by the authors.
`
`1804[ HANDBOOK OF BEST PRACTICES
`
`Sanofi/Regeneron Ex. 1 043, pg 1 07 4
`
`Merck Ex. 1043, pg 1100
`
`

`
`CHAPTER 17.22
`
`TABLE 2: BLOCKBUSTER DRUGS OF TOP TEN LICENSEES OF COHEN-BOYER PATENT
`
`Amgen
`
`$54,783,507
`
`Epogen
`Procrit'
`Neupogen
`
`FY 1989-1990
`
`,,,,,,,
`
`,,,,,,,
`< >
`? ? >
`..... , ... .. , ......... , . •• , •••• ) >
`. .... , ... .. , ......... , ... , ....
`<< < i < i <
`<< < i <
`FY 1985-1986
`
`,,,,,,
`>< > < ? >
`>< ) )/ ? ..... , ... , ....
`........... , ....
`.}. ? << }. i < i <
`
`/ ? ..... , ... , .... \'
`< }. ? < ::::: "'""
`
`Genentech
`
`$34,737,780
`
`Humulind
`Protropin
`Roferon A'
`Activase
`Nutropin
`Pulmozyme
`Nutropin AQ
`Actimmune
`Kogenate
`
`Johnson &Johnson
`
`$13,418,280
`
`Procrit"
`
`FY 1992-1993
`
`Abbott
`
`$lJ,804,444
`
`Various in vitro HIV
`diagnostics
`
`FY1987-1988
`
`Genetic Institute
`
`$5,946,978
`
`Recombinate
`
`FY1993-1994
`
`a. Partnered with Ortho and Johnson and Johnson.
`
`b. Partnered with Gener1tech.
`c. Partnered with Centocor.
`d. Partnered with Lilly.
`e. Partnered with Roche
`
`f. Partnered with Biogen.
`
`g PertnNerl with Amgen end Ortho
`
`h. Partnered with Biogen.
`Partnered with Berliex.
`
`HANDBOOK OF BEST PRACTICES 11805
`
`Sanofi/Regeneron Ex. 1043, pg 1075
`
`Merck Ex. 1043, pg 1101
`
`

`
`FELDMAN, COLAIANNI & LIU
`
`California taken only financial considerations
`imo accoum, it is likely chat they would have
`opted for much higher royalty rates or a more
`lucrative limited-use exclusive license. Stanford
`made very pragmacic decisions about pricing
`its imellectual property. In addition, it !Tlight
`have had to aggressively litigate instead of play(cid:173)
`ing a defensive litigation strategy. Moreover, the
`process was not finished once the first licensing
`agreement was formulated; Stanford made prag(cid:173)
`matic decisions and proved flexible, adapting its
`licensing strategies as circumstances changed.
`Had it nor been for Stanford's enlightened
`licensing practices, the Cohen-Boyer technology
`might have been placed in the public domain
`where the technology could have remained un(cid:173)
`developed or in the laboratories of large estab(cid:173)
`lished pharmaceutical companies. Or it might
`have been licensed exclusively and the rise of a
`Gioledmulugy induslry miglH have Geen delayed
`for years or decades. Small companies gained le(cid:173)
`gitimacy through licensing the Cohen-Boyer pat(cid:173)
`ents, making it easy for the companies to attract
`funding and strategic alliances. Hundreds of small
`biotech firms were founded on the recombinant
`DNJ\ technology, some of which have grown
`into large and successful firms. In total, 2,442
`known products were developed from the recom(cid:173)
`binant DNA technology, among them drugs to
`mitigate the effects of heart disease, lung disease,
`anemia, HIV-AIDS, cancer, diabetes, and numer(cid:173)
`ous other diseases and disorders. Stanford and
`the University of California received a quarter of
`a billion dollars that was used to fund internal
`research and provide infrastructure. It would be
`interesting to trace how those funds were actually
`used and what additional benefits may thus have
`been generated.
`Stanford University's licensing program still
`provides a reference point for the future prac(cid:173)
`tices of university technology transfer. While
`the amount of licensing revenue received and
`the value of the commercial product generated
`are awe inspiring, it should be remembered that
`this process was neither easy nor straightforward.
`The Stanford OTL was very creative and adaptive
`in designing their licensing program. They never
`
`lost sight of their larger goals co society and to the
`scientific enterprise.
`
`ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
`This work was supported in part by the Center for Public
`Genomics, Duke University, undergrantP50-HG003391
`from Lhe Nacional Hwnan Genome Research InsLiLULe
`and che C'.S. Department of Energy.
`
`MARYANN P. FELDMAN. Jv!iller Distinguished ProfoSJor in
`Higher Education, Institute of Higher Education, University
`of Georgia, 2024 1\Ieigs Hall, Athens. GA. 30602, U.S.A.
`mfi:ldmanCii>uga.edu
`
`ALES SANDRA COLAIANNI, Center for Genome Ethics, Law,
`andPoliCJ; Duke University, P.O. Box97082, North Building,
`Research Drive, Durham, NC 27708. U.SA. cac28@duke.
`edu
`
`CONNIE KANG Ll U, joseph r. Rotman School of Management,
`Univer.rity ofToronto, 105 St. George Street, Toronto, Ontario,
`M5S 3F6, Canada. connie liu07 @mtman utomnto ca
`
`Previously. individual faculty members had been able
`to file patents, negotiating the IP (intellectual proper(cid:173)
`ty) rights with the federal agency that had sponsored
`the research.
`
`Hughes 55. 2001. Making Dollars out of DNA
`The First Major Patent in Biotechnology and the
`CormnercialiLa lion ur Molecular Biology, 1914-1980.
`Isis 92·541-75·
`
`Feldman MP, A Colaianni and C
`Commercializing
`Cohen-Buyer:
`Unpublished
`
`Liu. 2006.
`1980-1997
`
`4
`
`"The Patent Office often requires terminal disclaimers
`to prevent an applicant seeking to extend patent life
`from filing continuation applications" See Reimers N
`1987. Tiger by the Tail. Chemtech 17(8)464-71.
`
`The OTL did recognize and account for, in
`their
`subsequent l1cens1ng programs, the possibility that
`a research institution would develop a commercially
`useful transformant (a cell modified by recombinant
`DNA techniques) that would then be licensed or sold
`to a company. The OTL would then require any such
`company to take out a I icense on the patents.
`
`6
`
`The Wisconsin Alumni Research Foundation (WARF).
`in 2002, signed its first licensing agreement, for stem
`cells, with a commercial provider and also signed
`license agreement permitting U.C.-San
`a separate
`Francisco, an academic provider listed on the NIH
`registry, to distribute human embryonic stem cells
`worldwide for use in research.
`
`7 Letter from Donald Fredrickson to Robert Rosenzweig.
`dated 2 March 1978. Obtained from: United States.
`Office of the Director, NIH. Recombinant DNA Research:
`Documents Relating to "NIH Guidelines for Molecules,"
`
`1806J HANDBOOK OF BEST PRACTICES
`
`Sanofi/Regeneron Ex. 1 043, pg 1 076
`
`Merck Ex. 1043, pg 1102
`
`

`
`CHAPTER 17.22
`
`June 1976 to November 1977- Department of Health,
`Education, and Welfare (DHEW).
`
`8
`
`Ibid
`
`9 Ku K. 1983 Licensing DNA Cloning Technology.
`Presented at the LES USA/Canada Central/Western
`Regiona I Meeting, Scottsdale, Arizona, February. A copy
`was obtained from the Stanford University OTL, 17
`August 2004.
`
`10 Amgen was grandfathered into th1s version of the
`l1cens1ng terms.
`
`11 Com pi led from OTL Archives.
`
`HANDBOOK OF BEST PRACTICES 11807
`
`Sanofi/Regeneron Ex. 1 043, pg 1 077
`
`Merck Ex. 1043, pg 1103

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket