throbber
Standards for Personal
`Communications in Europe
`and the United States
`
`David J. Goodman
`
`Program on Information Resources Policy
`
`Harvard University
`
`Cambridge, Massachusetts
`
`Center for Information
`Policy Research
`
`

`
`A publication of the Program on Information Resources Policy.
`
`Standards for Personal Communications in Europe and the United States
`David J. Goodman
`April 1998, P-98-1
`
`Project Director
`Anthony G. Oettinger
`
`The Program on Information Resources Policy is jointly sponsorod by Harvard University and the
`Center for Information Policy Research.
`
`Chairman
`Anthony G. Oettinger
`
`MQIUlging Director
`John C. B. LeGates
`
`David Goodman is Professor of Electrical and Computer Engineering at Rutgers University and
`Director of the Wireless Information Network Laboratory (WINLAB), a National Science Foundation
`Center at Rutgers. He performed the research for this report while he was a Research Associate at the
`Program in 1995, on sabbatical from Rutgers.
`
`Copyright© 1998 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College. Not to be reproduced in any
`form without written consent from the Program on Information Resources Policy, Harvard University,
`65 Rear Mt. Auburn Street, Cambridge MA 02138. (617) 495-4114. E-mail: pirp@deas.harvard.edu
`http://www .pirp.harvard.edu Printed in the United States of America. ISBN 1-879716-46-1
`
`Printing 5 4 3 2 1
`
`

`
`PROGRAM ON INFORMATION RESOURCES POLICY
`
`Harvard University
`
`Center for lnfonnation Policy Research
`
`Affiliates
`
`April1998
`
`AT&T Corp.
`Australian Telecommunications Users Group
`Bell Atlantic
`Bell Canada
`BellSouth Corp.
`The Boeing Company
`Cable & Wireless (U.K.)
`Carvajal S.A. (Colombia)
`Center for Excellence in Education
`Centro Studi San Salvador, Telecom ltalia
`(Italy)
`CIRCIT (Australia)
`Commission of the European Communities
`Computer & Communications Industry
`Assoc.
`CSC Index (U.K.)
`CyberMedia Group
`DACOM (Korea)
`Deloitte & Touche Consulting Group
`Dialog Corp.
`ETRI (Korea)
`European Parliament
`FaxNet Corp.
`First Data Corp.
`France Telecom
`Fujitsu Research Institute (Japan)
`GNB Technologies
`Grupo Clarin (Argentina)
`GTE Corp.
`Hearst Newspapers
`Hitachi Research Institute (Japan)
`IBM Corp.
`Intel Corporation
`Investment Company Institute
`Korea Telecom
`Lee Enterprises, Inc.
`Lexis-Nexis
`Lincoln Laboratory, MIT
`Litton Industries, Inc.
`Lucent Technologies
`John and Mary R. Markle Foundation
`Microsoft Corp.
`
`MicroUnity Systems Engineering, Inc.
`MITRE Corp.
`National Telephone Cooperative Assoc.
`NEC Corp. (Japan)
`The New York Times Co.
`Nippon Telegraph & Telephone Corp.
`(Japan)
`NMC/Northwestern University
`Pacific Bell
`Pacific Bell Directory
`Pacific Telesis Group
`The Post Office (U.K.)
`Raytheon Company
`Research Institute of Telecommunications
`and Economics (Japan)
`Revista Nacional de Telematica (Brazil)
`Samara Associates
`Scaife Family Charitable Trusts
`Siemens Corp.
`SK Telecom Co. Ltd. (Korea)
`Strategy Assistance Services
`TRW, Inc.
`UNIEMP (Brazil)
`United States Government:
`Department of Commerce
`National Telecommunications and
`Information Administration
`Department of Defense
`Defense Intelligence Agency
`National Defense University
`Department of Health and Human Services
`National Library of Medicine
`Department of the Treasury
`Office of the Comptroller of the Currency
`Federal Communications Commission
`National Security Agency
`United States Postal Service
`Viacom Broadcasting
`VideoSoft Solutions, Inc.
`Weyerhaeuser
`
`

`
`Acknowledgements
`
`The author gratefully acknowledges the following people who reviewed and commented
`critically on the draft version of this report. Without their consideration, input, and
`encouragement, this study could not have been completed:
`
`John A. A reate
`Gustave Barth
`Robert P. Bigelow
`Judson C. French
`Richard Frenkiel
`James Mikulski
`
`Michel Mouly
`Milton Mueller
`Marie-Bernadette Pnutet
`Alain Servantie
`Seo Jung Uck
`
`Four reviewers, in particular, helped me to correct some errors and otherwise improve
`the report. I thank Gustave Barth, James Mikulski , Michael Mooly, and Marie Pautet for their
`helpful suggestions.
`
`These reviewers and the Program's affiliates, however, are not responsible for or
`necessarily in agreement with the views expressed here, nor should they be blamed for any
`errors of fact or interpretation.
`
`The research for this report was conducted during 1995, while I was a research associate
`at the Program, on sabbatical leave from Rutgers University.
`
`

`
`Executive Summary
`
`In the 1990s, cellular and personal communications have been among the most dynamic
`areas of the economy, both in terms of markets and technology. As in other branches of
`information technology, the technology of personal communications is embodied in published
`standards. Standards for personal communications systems, however, are exceptional in
`several ways. For example:
`
`• They are directly influenced by government regulatory policy.
`
`• They are created before the underlying technology is mature.
`
`• Markets have accepted a proliferating number of standards rather
`than consolidating around one single standard.
`
`This report chronicles the history of cellular and personal communications standards in
`Europe and the United States. It then analyzes the standards in the context of economic
`theories developed since around 1980, with an emphasis on changes that have occurred since
`the early 1980s, when the first cellular systems reached the market, and on the differences
`between government policies in Europe and the United States. European governments have
`increasingly worked together to guide the creation and deployment of standards, while the
`United States government has taken a less active role than it did in the early 1980s. It can be
`argued that in the mid-1990s, European industry and consumers have been better served by
`government policies than their American counterparts have been.
`
`

`
`cisco Systems, Inc., Exhibit 1137
`Page 6
`
`
`

`
`Contents
`
`Acknowledgements
`
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`
`iv
`
`Executive Summary
`
`Chapter One
`
`Introduction . ... .. ............................ .
`
`v
`
`1
`
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
`Compatibility Specifications
`Chapter Two
`2.1 Standards in General
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
`2.1.1 Types of Standards . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
`2.1.2 Why Have Standards? Benefits and Some Costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
`2.2 Compatibility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
`2.2. 1 Methods of Achieving Compatibility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
`2.2.2 The Growing Importance of Compatibility Specifications . . . . . . . . . . 8
`2.2.3 The Economics of Compatibility
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
`2.2.4 Examples of Compatibility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`11
`2.3 Issues Addressed Here
`12
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`2.3 .1 Creation and Adoption of Standards . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`13
`2.3 .2 Status of Standards . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`14
`2.3.3 Figures of Merit for Standards
`15
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`2.3.4 Adoption of Standards . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`16
`
`17
`First-Generation Cellular Systems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`Chapter Three
`17
`3.1 The Cellular Idea
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`3.2 Introduction of Cellular Service into the United States
`19
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`3.2.1 Technology
`19
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`3.2.2 Radio Spectrum . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
`3.2.3 Operating Companies
`21
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`3. 3 Introduction of Cellular Service into Europe . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`23
`3.4 Stakeholders in Europe and the United States . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`24
`26
`3. 4. 1 Consumers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`3.4.2 Network Operators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`26
`3.4.3 Infrastructure Vendors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`27
`3.4.4 Subscriber Equipment Vendors
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
`3.4.5 Governments
`
`31
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`Second-Generation Cellular and PCS
`Chapter Four
`31
`4.1 Evolution of Technology in Europe
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`31
`4 .1.1 Motivation and Goals of GSM . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`32
`4.1.2 Technology Development by GSM . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`34
`4.1.3 GSM's Decisions and Deployment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`4.1.4 Other European Wireless Telecommunications Standards . . . . . . . . . 35
`4.2 The Evolution of Technology in the United States . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`36
`4.2. 1 NA-TDMA Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37
`4.2.2 The Development of Code Division Multiple Access (COMA)
`. . . . .
`39
`4.2.3 Intersystem Operations
`41
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`4.2.3 Narrowband AMPS (NAMPS)
`41
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`4.2.4 PCS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
`
`

`
`-viii -
`
`4 .3 Stakeholders in Europe and the United States . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`42
`45
`4.3. 1 Consumers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`4. 3. 2 Network Operators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46
`4. 3. 3 Infrastructure Vendors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46
`4.3.4 Subscriber Equipment Vendors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
`4.3.5 Government . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
`
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`Analysis of PCS Standards
`Chapter Five
`51
`51
`5.1 Creation of Standards . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`52
`5.2 Status . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`53
`5.3 Figures of Merit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`5. 3.1 Extrinsic Figures of Merit
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
`5.3.2 Intrinsic Figures of Merit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
`5.4 Adoption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56
`56
`5.4. 1 Equipment Vendors
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`5.4.2 Operating Companies
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`57
`5 .4. 3 Subscribers
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`59
`5.5 Relation of This Study to Theoretical Studies of Standards . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`59
`5.6 Implications for Public Policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`61
`
`Acronyms
`
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`
`63
`
`

`
`Illustrations
`
`Figures
`1-1
`
`3-1
`
`3-2
`
`4-1
`
`Tables
`3-1
`
`4-1
`
`4-2
`
`5-l
`
`Four Factors in Cellular Communications . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
`
`Elements of a Cellular System . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`
`18
`
`Cellular Stakeholders . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`
`26
`
`Global System for Mobile Communications (GSM) Architecture . . . . . . . . .
`
`33
`
`First-Generation Cellular Systems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`
`25
`
`Digital Cellular Systems in 1997
`
`. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`
`43
`
`Personal Communications Systems in 1997 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
`
`44
`
`Standards Widely Adopted in the United States and Europe . . . . . . . . . . . .
`
`52
`
`

`
`cisco Systems, Inc., Exhibit 1137
`Page 10
`
`
`

`
`Chapter One
`
`Introduction
`
`Since their birth in the early 1980s, cellular communications have proved a major
`success throughout the world. The public appetite for cellular telephones has consistently
`exceeded expectations of market analysts and fueled the rapid growth of service and
`equipment industries. Although the interplay of suppliers and consumers is common
`throughout the economy, two other factors have had an unusually strong influence on cellular
`communications: uncertainties about new technologies and government policy. As a
`consequence, the nature of cellular communications has been determined by the four factors
`illustrated in Figure 1-1, each of which influences all the others. This situation differs from
`other areas of information technology, for example video recording and personal computing,
`where the interaction of industry and consumers determines market growth in an environment
`of uniform government policy and predictable technology evolution. The situation portrayed
`in Figure 1-1 is complex. Moreover, the details of the interactions among the four factors are
`in a state of flux and differ considerably in different parts of the world.
`
`C 1998 President and Fellows of Harvard College. Program on Information Resources Policy.
`
`Figure 1-1
`
`Four Factors in Cellular Communications
`
`This report analyzes the relationship between government policy and the evolution in
`technology in Europe and the United States. The focus is on the standards that govern cellular
`communications and cellular's 1990s' counterpart, "personal communications." Usually,
`
`

`
`-2-
`
`personal communications are referred to as PCS, in which "S" stands for services or systems.
`PCS is presented to the public as cellular telephone service with frills, such as paging, voice
`mail, and calling number identification. To government regulators, PCS refers to frequency
`bands in which telephones operate. The cellular bands are around 450 megahertz (MHz), 850
`MHz, or 900 MHz, depending on national regulations. PCS bands are around 1900 MHz in
`the United States and Canada and around 1800 MHz in many other countries. For the most
`part, in this report the terms "cellular" and "PCS" are used as synonyms, because they share
`common technologies and in many respects are treated similarly by government regulators. In
`a few places (especially in Chapter Four), it is helpful to distinguish between services offered
`in the cellular and PCS frequency bands.
`
`As in other branches of information technology, PCS equipment must conform to
`established standards, but the creation and adoption of standards for PCS differ substantially
`from procedures in other application areas. There are two major, interrelated differences:
`
`• PCS standards were created before the conforming technologies were
`developed; and
`
`• there are many competing PCS standards.
`
`The striking effect of these differences is that the PCS industry, while mature commercially,
`remains a standards battleground, with an increasing, rather than decreasing, number of
`warring factions. This situation appears to be unique in information technology.
`
`This report documents the status of PCS standards in the United States and Europe
`during the past fifteen years since roughly 1980. Many of these issues addressed here are
`identified in a body of literature that has grown steadily since the mid-1980s in response to a
`recognition of the increasing economic importance of information technology standards. Most
`of the standards literature falls into two categories: case studies, such as this one, and analyses
`based on abstract models. This report is a case study of PCS that refers to the abstract models
`in order to explain some of the economic forces guiding the evolution of PCS.
`
`The report is aimed at two audiences. It offers members of the PCS community a
`context for analysis and decisonmaking relevant to the creation and adoption of standards.
`And to scholars with a general interest in standards, it offers another case study, distinguished
`in two ways: first, by the diversity of competing standards existing in a single industry, and,
`second, contrary to many other case studies, by describing issues still far from resolved. In
`this sense, PCS standards are a laboratory for examining hypotheses elsewhere deduced from
`abstract models or induced from retrospective case studies.
`
`Chapter Two presents a framework for examining standards in general, with a focus on
`compatibility specifications. This framework, largely derived from the standards literature,
`
`

`
`-3 -
`
`emphasizes criteria for judging the merits of specific standards. Chapters Three and Four
`describe the history of first- and second-generation PCS systems in Europe and North
`America. The striking differences in the status of standards in these two continents is in itself
`surprising. Moreover, since 1988 the situation has flip-flopped so that the status of second(cid:173)
`generation European standards resembles that of first-generation North American standards,
`and vice versa. Chapter Five uses the economics framework developed in Chapter Two to
`interpret the case studies presented in Chapters Three and Four. A principal conclusion is
`that, to date, the policies adopted in Europe in the 1980s have served consumers and industry
`better than policies in the United States.
`
`

`
`cisco Systems, Inc., Exhibit 1137
`Page 14
`
`

`
`Chapter Two
`
`Compatibility Specifications
`
`To establish a framework for examining PCS compatibility, compatibility specifications
`must first be placed in the general context of standards for products and services. There are
`many types of standards, each serving its own purposes. Compatibility specifications serve the
`purpose of interoperability. They insure that two or more products will function properly
`when part of the same system. Although the details of interoperability remain the fundamental
`purpose of compatibility specifications, specifications also address other goals that influence
`the value of standard products to their producers and consumers.
`
`2.1 Standards in General
`
`2.1.1 Types of Standards
`
`Another author, introducing standards to his readers, explained that when he began his
`investigation, "Standards of every kind started to appear everywhere. " 1 To prevent
`proliferation from obscuring the principal issues addressed here, this investigation begins with
`a definition that encompasses the scope of this report:
`
`Standards are formal rules that guide the manufacture of products and
`the delivery of services.
`
`Although this definition excludes, in the words of that author, "the way my wife and I write
`phone messages, "2 it still incorporates a wide variety of practices.
`
`To appreciate the wide range of issues addressed by standards, it is helpful to identify
`categories that refer to the principal purpose of a standard:
`
`1. Appearance, labeling
`2. Dimensions, such as size and weight
`3. Safety
`4. Quality
`5. Compatibility specifications
`
`1Yesha Y. Sivan, Knowledge Age Standards: Present Scope and Potential Use in Education (Cambridge, Mass:
`Harvard University Program on Information Resources Policy, P-96-1, March 1996), 7.
`
`2Ibid.
`
`

`
`-6-
`
`All of them could be observed while I was recently examining a compact disc (CD) player in
`a store. Like other components of an audio system, the CD player was in a black cabinet (1).
`The controls were labeled with the same icons that appear on other CD players ( 1). The disc
`player has the same width and depth as other stereo components (2). It carries an endorsement
`from Underwriters Laboratories, certifying that it meets electrical safety standards (3). "Eight(cid:173)
`times oversampling" in combination with an "18-bit digital-to-analog converter" indicate the
`quality of the audio signals (4). And, finally, the CD player is compatible with all my
`compact discs (5).
`
`2.1.2 Why Have Standards? Benefits and Some Costs
`
`Standards deliver a variety of benefits to industry and to the public at large. Appearance
`and labeling standards promote a company's image and help consumers understand the nature
`and function of a product. The benefits of safety and quality are obvious and inherent in the
`products and services they cover. Other benefits fall into the category of network economies
`and network externalities. 3 These are economic benefits that derive from wide adherence to
`standards, beyond the inherent benefits of the products and services to their users.
`Externalities can be positive or negative, depending on whether the total added benefit of one
`more unit is greater or less than the benefit to the person obtaining it.
`
`Dimensional standards are useful principally because they produce network efficiencies.
`There is nothing inherently optimum in stereo components that are 44 centimeters (em) wide
`and 29 em deep. However, wide adherence to this convention produces efficiencies in storage
`and display for retailers. It also serves consumers by stimulating the availability of
`inexpensive, space-efficient audio equipment furniture. Dimensional conventions promote
`efficiency of service and repair facilities. Car maintenance would be even more expensive
`than it is if each model were to come with its own size of spark-plug threads.
`
`Externalities can also be negative. For example, the batteries in portable electronic
`equipment increase the value of the equipment to its users but create disposal problems for the
`community at large. In some instances, the nature of the externality depends on how many
`similar products already exist. Citizens band (CB) radios at first had positive externalities.
`When there were few CB radios, the purchase of each new one gave existing owners new
`opportunities to communicate. But when the airwaves became congested, each new radio,
`although beneficial to its purchaser, added to the likelihood that other people would encounter
`congestion when they tried to use theirs.
`
`3In this context, the word "network" is used in the general sense of a collection of related goods and services.
`Elsewhere in this report the discussion refers extensively to communications networks consisting of electronic
`equipment that stores and transports information.
`
`

`
`-7-
`
`Even when they produce externalities that are positive in aggregate, standards can have
`negative side effects. By limiting variety, they can circumscribe efficiency and quality. Many
`stereo components could fit comfortably in boxes that are less than 44 em wide and 29 em
`deep. Smaller boxes would consume less metal for construction, and smaller boxes would be
`more economical to store and transport than standard ones. When standards become
`entrenched they can inhibit innovation. Someone may invent a better technique than Dolby for
`suppressing noise in audio tapes, but it would be hard to fmd a market for the new method in
`the presence of the "excess inertia"4 associated with the millions of tapes and tape players
`that conform to the Dolby standard.
`
`Some standards, such as the dimensions of audio equipment, embody a mixture of
`advantages and disadvantages. They are adopted when the pluses outweigh the minus. By
`contrast, compatibility specifications are often compelling. Whatever its color and size, a CD
`player that is incompatible with CD recordings would be useless. Similarly, compatibility of
`PCS system components is essential.
`
`2.2 Compatibility
`
`2.2.1 Methods of Achieving Compatibility
`
`The word "compatibility" implies a relationship between two or more different things.
`Gabel's book5 begins with an excellent discourse on the economic implications of
`compatibility. He points out that a standard is one way, but not the only way, of achieving
`compatibility. In some cases, compatibility is inherent in the relationship between separate
`properties of two things. He offers the example of tea and lemons. Other times, compatibility
`is achieved by means of an adaptor, which is an additional piece of equipment that allows two
`incompatible items to function together. To travelers, an electrical adaptor is a familiar means
`of making an appliance compatible with a local power source. Compatibility can also be
`achieved by gateways, which are products capable of conforming to more than one standard.
`An example of a gateway is a hair dryer that can be used with both European and North
`American electricity supplies. Gateway technologies, in the form of dual-mode cellular
`telephones, figure prominently among emerging cellular telephone products in North America.
`
`The focus of this report is on products that conform to formal compatibility
`specifications. Sometimes a specification describes only one part of a system, such as a
`television transmitter. In doing so, it implicitly establishes rules for manufacturing compatible
`
`4Joseph Farrell and Garth Sa loner, "Standardization, Compatibility, and Innovation, Rand Journal of Economics
`16, 1 (Spring 1985), 70-83.
`
`5H. Landis Gabel, Competitive Strategies for Product Standards: The Strategic Use of Compatibility Standards for
`Competitive Advantage (London: McGraw-Hill, 1991), Chapter 1.
`
`

`
`-8 -
`
`receivers. By contrast, a cellular phone standard typically contains rules for manufacturing
`groups of products that have to be mutually compatible.
`
`2.2.2 The Growing Importance of Compatibility Specifications
`
`Prior to roughly 1980, the creation of standards in teleconununications was, for the most
`part, a technical activity confmed to experts within one company or to small teams of
`specialists nominated by their employers. In the telecommunications industry, standards were
`typically produced by representatives of national monopolies. When a single company
`produced a specification, the task of the experts was to formulate recipes for producing
`products that conformed to existing technology. Committees spanning several companies,
`usually from different countries, had the task of ironing out differences between similar, but
`not identical, approaches. In the late 1990s, this situation is rare. Standards groups today are
`battlegrounds where company representatives assert the interests of their employers and work
`to block competitors from gaining an advantage. Several circumstances explain this
`transformation.
`
`Long-standing telecommunications monopolies are rapidly disappearing. Traditionally,
`companies like AT&T and government-owned post, telegraph, and telephone authorities
`(PTTs) set national standards. With their monopoly status gone, these companies no longer
`have the authority to dictate standards. Their competitors have a stake in the details of
`emerging standards, and often their interests are at variance with those of the former
`monopolies. This situation has opened the way for many more players in the standards arena,
`and for more contention, which together demand substantially more company resources.
`Twenty years ago, telecommunications standards were set by groups of experts working
`together to achieve a good technical solution. Today, standards are set by representatives of
`companies, each trying to obtain maximum advantage for their organizations.
`
`In the 1970s, IBM derived enormous wealth and power from its ownership of mainframe
`computing standards. Today, Microsoft and Intel together hold a similar advantage in the
`realm of personal computing. It is an interesting paradox that their monopolies in software
`and microelectronics emerged concurrently with the eclipse of the world's telecommunications
`monopolies. This situation attracts the attention of everyone in the information technology
`industries who recognize the critical importance of standards to their businesses. It engages
`the U.S. government. The executive branch works to restrain Microsoft by exercising antitrust
`oversight, while the courts define the limits of the power Intel derives from its intellectual
`property rights.
`
`Technologies have become increasingly complex and interdependent as the number and
`diversity of components that have to interact to produce an effective information system grow.
`In a system, the merits of each component depend not only on the quality of the particular
`
`

`
`-9-
`
`component but also on how it functions in the presence of all the other components.
`Compatibility standards govern the interfaces between system components and critically
`influence the quality of a system. With the increasing complexity of a system, the task of
`producing a standard that promotes the quality of the system and advances the interests of a
`specific company requires more and more company resources. In contrast to issues of trade
`and industry structure, which have attracted increased government attention, technical
`complexity has in many instances had the opposite effect. Where the government once played
`a role in determining standards, officials and politicians have decided that the issues are too
`complex to be decided by administrative means. Instead, they leave standards setting to
`"market forces," which can assert themselves in various ways, depending on the technology
`involved.
`
`The expansion of product markets to cover the entire world forces companies to be
`acquainted with standards beyond their home bases. They need to acquire expertise on
`existing standards and influence the creation of new standards that will govern their products.
`This situation also engages governments. Diplomats examine national standards ranging from
`the characteristics of rice to automobile pollution controls and argue about whether they really
`promote quality and safety or whether they serve as restraints to free trade.
`
`The globalization of communications networks also commands increased attention to
`standards. For a long time, international communications accounted for a small fraction of
`information traffic. Under the auspices of the International Telegraphic Union (ITU),
`monopoly telephone companies collaborated to establish technical interfaces (adaptors) that
`reconciled differences between the national networks. Relative to compatible products
`throughout an international network, adaptors incur penalties in efficiency and quality, but
`these were of little consequence when there was little international traffic. Anticipating the
`growth of international communications, in the 1960s telephone industries moved toward
`product standardization for digital telephony. In the 1990s, with international calling a
`conspicuous growth area for telephony and the worldwide Internet expanding rapidly, global
`standards no longer are a side issue. All the other factors that lead to increased standards
`activity come together in the international scene, where their complexity is compounded by
`the need to reconcile differing national and regional interests.
`
`2.2.3 The Economics of Compatibility
`
`The academic community, recognizing the growing importance of compatibility
`specifications in an information society, has since the mid-1980s taken increasing interest in
`compatibility. Studies of compatibility fall into two categories, case studies and economic
`models. Many of the economic models focus on the effects of positive externalities. They
`address the question of whether markets with network externalities are "efficient," in the
`
`

`
`- 10-
`
`classical economists' sense of producing socially optimal characteristics.6 Typically, a model
`describes a market containing products that conform to two or more competing standards,
`each with its own price. Owing to the presence of externalities, the value of a product to a
`consumer depends on the number of compatible products. Consumers choose among
`competing products on the basis of price and assumptions about the decisions of other
`consumers. 7 Other elements of mathematical models describe pricing policies of suppliers.
`Although the models differ with respect to details such as the nature of the information
`available to consumers,8 they generally imply that in the presence of positive extern

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket