throbber
1
`
`I
`
`
`
`Competition has long been viewed as a force that leads to an ideal solution of the
`economic performance problem, and monopoly has been condemned through
`much of recorded history for frustrating attainment of the competitive ideal. To
`
`The welfare Adam Smith, the vital principle underlying a market economy’s successful func-
`tioning was the pursuit of individual self-interest, channelled and controlled by
`competition. As each individual strives to maximize the value of his own capital,
`said Smith, he
`
`EC0110n1iCS Of
`
`Competition and
`
`. necessarily labours to render the annual revenue of the society as great as
`.
`.
`M0n0p01Y he can. He generally, indeed, neither intends to promote the public interest,
`nor knows how much he is promoting it.
`.
`.
`. [H]e intends only his own gain,
`and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an
`end which was no part of his intention.‘
`
`Smith’s “invisible hand” is the set ofmarket prices emerging in response to compet-
`itive forces. When these forces are thwarted by “the great engine of .
`.
`. monop-
`oly,” the tendency for resources to be allocated “as nearly as possible in the propor-
`tion which is most agreeable to the interests of the whole society” is frustrated?
`Much of Smith’s detailed analysis is obsolete. Yet his arguments on the efficacy
`of free competition remain intact, a philosophical lodestar to nations relying upon
`a market system of economic organization. Economists have, to be sure, amended
`their view of competition since Smith's time, and they have developed more ele-
`gant models of how competitive markets do theirjob of allocating resources and
`distributing income. One objective of this chapter is to survey these modern
`views. In addition, we shall examine some of the qualifications and doubts that
`have led to the partial or complete rejection of Smith’s gospel in many parts of the
`world.
`
`Competition Defined
`
`We must begin by making clear what is meant by competition in economic analysis.
`Two broad conceptions, one emphasizing the conduct of sellers and buyers and
`the other emphasizing market structure, can be distinguished. Adam Smith’s
`widely scattered comments, dealing with both conduct and structural features,
`typify the dominant strain of economic thought during the eighteenth and nine-
`teenth centuries.3 On the conduct side, Smith considered the essence of competi-
`tion to be an independent xtriving for patronage by the various sellers in a market.
`The short-run structural prerequisites for competitive conduct were left ambig-
`uous. Smith observed that independent action might emerge with only two sellers,
`but it was more likely (that is, collusion among the sellers was less likely) with
`
`1. Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Cauxer oft/ze Wealth
`ofNati(m.t (New York: Modern Library edition, 1937), p. 4-23.
`2. Smith, Wealth ofNationJ, pp. 594-595. See also pp. 61, 14-7,
`and 712.
`
`3. For admirable surveys of the development of economic
`thought on the nature of competition, see George J. Stigler, “Per-
`feet Competition, Historically Contemplate-d,",/ournal ofPolitical
`Economy, vol. 65 (February 1957), pp. 1-17; M. Clark, Compe-
`
`tition ax a Dynamic Procerx (Washington: Brookings, 1961), Chap-
`ters 2 and 3; Paulj. McNulty, "A Note on the History of Perfect
`Competition,”Journal ofPolitieal Economy, vol. 75, Part 1 (August
`1967), pp. 395-399; and idem, “Economic Theory and the Mean-
`ing of Competition,” Quarterlyjournal ofEconomies, vol. 82 (No-
`vember 1968), pp. 639-656.
`
`WCK1075
`Page 1
`
`
`
`WCK1075
`Page 1
`
`

`
`The Welfare Economics of Competition and Monopoly
`
`19
`
`turn has served as a model for many other nations. Asjames Madison wrote (un-
`der the pseudonym Publius) in Federalist Paper No. 10, nothing was more impor-
`tant to a well-constructed union than avoiding the imposition on all citizens of
`measures favored by narrow factions.9 Factions, continued Madison, arise most
`frequently from the unequal distribution of property, pitting the wishes of “a
`landed interest, a manufacturing interest, a mercantile interest, a moneyed inter-
`est, with many lesser interests” against the common good. The best way to avoid
`faction-dominated outcomes, said Madison, was to keep the individual factions so
`small and diverse that they would be “unable to concert and carry into effect
`schemes of oppression.”
`A closely related benefit is the fact that competitive market processes solve the
`economic problem impersonally, and not through the personal control of entrepre-
`neurs and bureaucrats. There is nothing more galling than to have the achieve-
`ment of some desired objective frustrated by the decisions of an identifiable indi-
`vidual or group. Who, on the other hand, can work up much outrage about a
`setback administered by the impersonal interplay of competitive market forces?
`A third political merit of a competitive market is its freedom of opportunity.
`When the no-barriers-to-entry condition of perfect competition is satisfied, indi-
`viduals are free to choose whatever trade or profession they prefer, limited only by
`their own talent and skill and by their ability to raise the (presumably modest)
`amount of capital required.
`
`The Efficiency of Admitting the salience of these political benefits, our main concern nonetheless
`Competitive Markets will be with the economic case for competitive market processes. Figure 2.1(b)
`reviews the conventional textbook analysis of equilibrium in a competitive indus-
`try, and Figure 2.1(a) portrays it for a representative firm belonging to that indus-
`try. Suppose we begin observing the industry when the short-run industry supply
`curve is S], which embodies the horizontal summation of all member firms’ margi-
`nal cost curves. The short-run marketequilibrium price is OP], which is viewed as
`a parameter or “given” by our representative firm, so the firm’s subjectively-
`perceived demand curve is a horizontal line at the level OP1. The firm maximizes
`its profits by expanding output until marginal cost (MC) rises into equality with
`the price OP,. It produces OX1 units of output and earns economic profits — that
`is, profits above the minimum return required to call forth its capital investment
`— equal to the per-unit profit GC1 times the number of units of output OX1.
`Because economic profits are positive for the representative firm, this cannot be a
`long-run equilibrium position. New firms attracted by the profit lure will enter the
`industry, adding their new marginal cost functions to the industry’s supply curve,
`and existing firms will expand their capacity, so the industry supply curve shifts to
`the right. Entry and expansion will continue, augmenting output and driving the
`price down, until price has fallen into equality with average total cost (ATC) for
`
`7. See Williamj. Baumol, John C. Panzar, and Robert D.
`Willig, Contextable Markets and the Theory oflnduxtry Structure (New
`York: Harcourt Brace jovanovich, 1982).
`i
`8. US. v. Bexxer Mfg. Co , 96 F. Supp. 304- (1951), affirmed 343
`U.S. 4-44» (1952).
`
`9. The Fedemlixt Papers, Mentor Book edition (New York: New
`American Library, 1961), pp. 77-84.
`
`WCK1075
`Page 2
`
`
`
`WCK1075
`Page 2
`
`

`
`
`
`a. Firm
`
`b. Industry
`
`1?
`
`#9
`
`S1
`
`20 Chapter 2
`
`
`
`0
`
`X2 X1
`
`Output
`
`0
`
`Z1 Z2
`
`Output
`
`Figure 2. 1
`Equilibrium under Pure
`
`
`
`Competition
`
` the representative firm. '0 In the figures shown, this zero-profit condition emerges
`with the short-run supply curve S2, yielding the market price OP2. The represen-
`
`
`tative firm maximizes its profits by equating marginal cost with new price OP2,
`barely covering its unit costs (including the minimum necessary return on its capi-
`tal) at the output OX2.
`The long-run equilibrium state of a competitive industry has three general
`properties with important normative implications:
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`a. The cost ofproducing the last unit of output — the marginal cost — is equal
`to the price paid by consumers for that unit. This is a necessary condition for profit
`maximization, given the competitive firm’s perception that price is unaffected by
`its output decisions. It implies efficiency of resource allocation in a sense to be
`explained momentarily.
`b. With price equal to average total cost for the representative firm, economic
`(that is, supra-normal) profits are absent. Investors receive a returnjust sufficient
`to induce them to maintain their investment at the level required to produce the
`
`industry’s output efficiently. Avoiding a surplus return to capital is considered
`desirable in terms of the equity of income distribution.
`c. In long-run equilibrium, each firm is producing its output at the minimum
`point on its average total cost curve. Firmslthat fail to operate at the lowest unit
`cost will incur losses and be driven from the ‘industry. Thus, resources are em-
`ployed at maximum production efficiency under competition.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`One further benefit is sometimes attributed to the working of competition, al-
`though with less logical compulsion. Because of the pressure of prices on costs,
`
`
`entrepreneurs may have especially strong incentives to seek and adopt cost-saving
`
`technological innovations. Indeed, if industry capacity is correctly geared to de-
`
`
`mand at all times, the only way competitive firms can earn positive economic
` profits is through innovative superiority. We might expect therefore that techno-
`WCK1075
`
`Page 3
`
`
`
`
`
`WCK1075
`Page 3
`
`

`
`The Welfare Economics of Competition and Monopoly 21
`
`logical progress will be more rapid in competitive industries. However, doubts
`concerning the correctness of this hypothesis will be raised in a moment.
`
`‘The Inefficiency of Monopolists and monopolistic competitors differ from purely competitive firms in
`Monopoly Pricing
`only one essential respect: They face a downward-sloping demand curve for their
`output. Given this, the firm with monopoly power knows that to sell an additional
`unit (or block) of output, it must reduce its price to the customer(s) for that unit;
`and if it is unable to practice price discrimination (as we shall generally assume,
`unless otherwise indicated), 11 the firm must also reduce the price to all customers
`who would have made their purchases even without the price reduction. The net
`addition to the nondiscriminating monopolist’s revenue from selling one more
`unit of output, or its marginal revenue,
`is equal to the price paid by the marginal
`customer, minus the change in price required to secure the marginal customer’s
`patronage multiplied by the number of units that would have been sold without
`the price reduction in question.” Except at prices so high as to choke off all de-
`mand, the monopolist always sacrifices something to gain the benefits of increased
`patronage: the higher price it could have extracted had it limited its sales to more
`eager customers. When demand functions are continuous and smooth, marginal
`revenue under monopoly is necessarily less than price for finite quantities sold.
`When the monopolist’s demand function can be represented by a straight line,
`marginal revenue for any desired output is given by the ordinate of a straight line
`intersecting the demand curve where the latter intersects the vertical axis, and
`with twice the slope of the demand curve, as illustrated in Figures 2.2(a) and
`2.2(b).13 We will normally use straight-line demand curves in subsequent illustra-
`tions because they make it easier to get the geometry of their associated marginal
`revenue curves exactly right.
`Now the profit-maximizing firm with monopoly power will expand its output
`
`only as long as the net addition to revenue from selling an additional unit (the
`marginal revenue) exceeds the addition to cost from producing that unit (the mar-
`ginal cost). At the monopolist’s profit-maximizing output, marginal revenue
`equals marginal cost. But with positive output, marginal revenue is less than
`price, and so the monopolist’s price exceeds marginal cost. This equilibrium con-
`dition for firms with monopoly power differs from that of the competitive firm.
`For the competitor, price equals marginal cost; for the monopolist, price exceeds
`marginal cost. This difference has important implications to which we shall return
`in a moment.
`
`10. We assume perfect imputation of all factor scarcity FCIJLS
`here. If the imputation process is imperfect, only the marginal
`firm — the firm just on the borderline between entering and not
`entering — will realize zero economic profits.
`11. The logic of price discrimination will be explored in
`Chapter 13.
`12. Generally, for the monopolist price is a function P = f(Q) of
`the quantity Q_sold. Total sales revenue R = PQ. Marginal rev-
`enue is the change in total revenue associated with a unit change
`in quantity sold, thus, MR = dR/dQ = P + Q(dP/dQ). P in
`
`the MR expression is the price paid by marginal consumers; dP/
`dQ_is the change in price necessary to attract them (usually with a
`negative sign); and Qcorresponds approximately to the quantity
`that would be sold without the price reduction.
`13. Proof: Let the demand curve have the equation
`F = a — bQ_, where Qis the quantity demanded. Total revenue
`R = PQ = aQ — bQ’. Marginal revenue dR/dQ, = a — 2bQ_.
`At Q = 0, P = MR. The slope (—2b) of the marginal revenue
`function is twice the slope (—b) of the demand curve.
`
`WCK1075
`Page 4
`
`
`
`WCK1075
`Page 4
`
`

`
`1 I I
`
`|I
`
`|
`1
`I
`
`1|
`
`' T
`
`.
`
`‘ II
`
`
`
`22 Chapter 2
`
`21. Pure monopolist
`
`b. Monopolistic competitor
`$
`
`LRMC
`
`Output
`
`P4
`
`LRATC
`
`D
`
`MR
`
`MR
`
`0
`
`X4
`
`Figure 2.2
`Equoiormm ‘moor Monopoly
`
`The competitive enterprise earns zero economic profit in long-run equilib-
`rium. Is the firm with monopoly power different? Perhaps, but not necessarily.
`Figure 2.2(a) illustrates one of the many possible cases in which positive monopoly
`profits are realized: specifically, the per-unit profit margin P3C3 times the number
`of units OX3 sold. As long as entry into the monopolist’s market is barred, there is
`no reason why this profitable equilibrium cannot continue indefinitely. Figure
`2.2(b), on the other hand, illustrates the standard long—run equilibrium position of
`a monopolistic competitor. 14 The crucial distinguishing assumptions are that mo-
`nopolistic competitors are small relative to the market for their general class of
`differentiated products and that eiitry into the market is free. Then, if positive
`economic profits are earned, new firms will squeeze into the industry, shifting the
`typical f1rm’s demand curve to the left until, in long-run equilibrium, it is tangent
`to the firm’s long-run unit cost function LRATC. The best option left for the firm
`then is to produce output OX4, where marginal revenue equals marginal cost (as
`in any monopolistic situation) and the average revenue or price OP4 is barely suf-
`ficient to cover unit cost. Thus, while firms with monopoly power may secure mo-
`
`nopoly profits, they need not, especially under the plausible conditions of monop-
`olistic competition.
`We found earlier that in long-run equilibrium, the purely and perfectly com-
`petitive firm produces at minimum average total cost. Is this true also of the mo-
`nopoly? Many textbooks imply that it is not, or that it will be true only by acci-
`
`
`
`.
`
`
`
`dent.AgainconsiderFigure2.2(a).Itassumesthatthemonopolistoperatesunder
`
`constant long-run cost conditions; that is, that plants (or plant complexes) de-
`signed to produce at high outputs give rise to roughly the same cost per unit as
`those designed to produce at low outputs. We shall see in Chapter 4- that many
`real-world cost functions exhibit this property over substantial output ranges. If
`so, the firm will invest in a plant complex characterized by the short-run cost func-
`tion SRATC, with minimum short-run unit costs identical to the minimum long-
`
`
`
`WCK1075
`
`Page 5
`
`WCK1075
`Page 5
`
`

`
`
`
`
`Market Structure,
`
`Patents, and
`
`Technological
`
`Innovation
`
`Making the best use ofrcsources at any moment in time-. is itnportattt. But in the
`long run, it is dynamic perfo1‘11ianctt that counts. As we observed in Chapter 2, an
`output handicap eunounting to 10 percent ofgross national product owing to static
`inefficiency is surtnotmtctl in twenty years ifthe output growth rate can be raisccl
`through more rapid technological progress from 3.0 to 3.5 percent. Or if the
`growth rate can be increased to 4.0 percent, the initial disadvantage is twercotne
`in 10.6 years.
`To Atlam Smith, the pin factory was the epitome ofstatic efliciency.‘ Through
`ntechaniztation and the division of labor, an average output per worker of‘l-,800
`pins per day could be achieved in the 17703. Two centuries later, thanks to count-
`less technological che'tnge.<:, output per worker had risen to 800,000 pins per day.”
`The increase scents E1Slt)I.ll1(lll'Ig‘ at first glance, but it implies an average annual
`work-dzty productivity growth rate nfonly 2.56 pert:ent per year—a rate snatched
`by many indu.-ttrie:-: over sul)st2tntial periods of time,
`From the time of Smith's successor Uavicl Ricartlo, and especially after the
`Neoclassical breakthrough of the 18703, until well into the twentieth century, the
`rnainstrcain ol‘(non-Maritizm) economic theory exhibited remarkably little sensi-
`tivity to the importance of t.'ZOI‘l'1[.)(J'l1I‘I(l productivity growth through technological
`innovation. Emphasis was on the result of combining labor and capital with
`prodttction funtttiom; olian essentially static character. Not until the 19503 (lid
`technological change become more than a side-show attraction. For the shot that
`signaled a revolution in economic thought, Robert Solow received the Nobel
`Prize.3 He set out to measure the extent to which increases in the amount of
`capital employed were responsible for the rise of U.S. nonfarm output per labor
`hour between 1909 and 194-9. To the surprise of economists mired in the static
`tradition, he found that lI‘lCI't‘)Icl8t:(l capital intensity £tCCCIl.ll‘tlf?El for only 12.5 per-
`cent (later corrected to 19 percent) of the I1'l(Ea.SL1I‘C(l growth in output per work
`hour. The rest ofthe observed {.79 percent average annual protluctivity gain was
`evidently attributable to irnprovententfs in protlttction practices and equipment
`(technological cltang: in the strictest! :it*.I1.*i{£) and to the iticreascd ability of the
`labor force. In El. SLll)S€'C]ut‘.l1l extension,
`l‘i(lW'z1l‘(l Denison cstimatetl that 13 per~
`cent of the gain in output per worker between 1929 and I982 could be cretlitetl to
`increased capital
`intensity, 34 percent
`to improved work force education, 22
`percent to the greatt.-1' l‘(:ElllZEll.lOl1{Jl_SL'2!lC ecottonties, i'll1(l6B percent to advances in
`scientilic and teclmological knowlcclge, broadly con.strued.‘* Although one can
`quibble with the detailed cst.itrtat.es, it is hztrtl to dispute the main thrust oi'Solow's
`and Denison’s conclusion: that the growth of output per worker in the United
`States (and also in other industrialized lands5) has come predominantly from the
`
`1- Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Cause; of the
`Wealth ofNationr t" I 776), Book I, Chapter 1.
`2. Clifford F. Pratten, “The Manufacture of Pins,"_]oumal of
`Elittmmir Literature, vol. I8 (March 1980), pp. 93-96.
`3- Robert M. Solow. “Technical Change and the Aggregate
`I "ldllttititl Function," Review ofEwn0mics and Stalixticx, vol. 39
`i“:8"-‘l ISM). pp. 312-320.
`.
`1
`'—llW}I!'<i F. Denison, Trend: in American Economic Growth,
`
`1929-1982 (Washington: Brookings, 1985) p. 30. The percent-
`ages add to more than 100 because there are also negative factors,
`for example, a decrease in hours worked by the average employee
`( — 25 percent) and the effects of government regulation ( -4
`percent).
`5. See, for example, Edward F. Denison,
`Differ (Washington: Brookings, 1967).
`
`I/Viz} Growth Rates
`
`WCK1075
`Page 6
`
`
`
`WCK1075
`Page 6
`
`

`
`622 Chapter 17
`
`The Basic Logic
`
`
`
`._s__._.________—_..__....:_.§..__,
`
`to the employing corporation, in whose name the patent is then issued. Thus, a
`distinction is made between corporate and “individual” patent grants. The share of
`all U.S. patents issued to individual inventors was 91 percent in 1901, 72 percent
`in 1921, 42 percent in 1940, 25 percent during the 1960s, and 18.5 percent during
`the early 1980s.
`
`The funds supporting invention and the commercial development of inventions
`are front-end “sunk” investments; once they have been spent, they are an irretriev-
`able bygone. To warrant making such investments, an individual inventor or cor-
`poration must expect that once commercialization occurs, product prices can be
`held above postinvention production and marketing costs long enough so that the
`discounted present value of the profits (or more accurately, quasi rents) will ex-
`ceed the value of the front-end investment. In other words, the investor must ex-
`pect some degree of protection from competition, or some monopoly power. The
`patent holder’s right to exclude imitating users is intended to create or strengthen
`that expectation. Patents also confer a property right which the original patent
`holder can sell, recouping its original investment and letting another entity exclu-
`sively commercialize the patented subject matter. Partial “sale” is also possible, for
`example, when the patent holder licenses others to exploit the invention and
`charges a royalty for the right.27
`The simplest case of a product innovation covered by patent protection is
`shown in Figure 17.1(a). If the product is really new and useful, it creates a wholly
`new demand curve D1 -one that did not exist previously. With an exclusive right
`to make and sell its product, the patent holder is a monopolist. It derives its margi-
`nal revenue MR1, equates marginal revenue with marginal production and distri-
`bution cost MC , and sets price OP1, realizing “monopoly” profits in the amount of
`rectangular area PIAXM. These are not pure profits, however, because the inno-
`vator’s sunk R&D costs must be taken intoaccount. To make that one-time lump
`sum consistent with Figure 17. 1(a), which is expressed in annual “flow” terms, let
`us assume that the innovator finances its R&D investment by taking out a
`seventeen-year mortgage whose annual payment obligation is given by the area of
`the inset rectangle I_]KL.23 If the patent monopoly lasts for seventeen years, the
`annual “profit” PIAXM will more than cover the annual R&D debt service cost,
`and the innovator will be well compensated for its efforts. It is not true, however,
`that the monopoly innovator is the only one to gain. The ordinates of demand
`curve D1 array the values diverse consumers place upon having the new pmrlucl
`to consume. The product’s availability on monopolized terms generates not only
`producer’s surplus PIAXM, but also c:m1:sur11::1's’ surplus BAP1. With linear de-
`mand and constant marginal production and (_li.<;lribution costs, as shown in Fig‘
`ure 17. 1(a), the monopolist is said to “appm|)ri;1u-." to itself only two-thirds of the
`total surplus its product creates.” The 1':-:n'1ai11i1'|g third goes to consumers.
`Suppose, however, that there were no patent protection and no other l:a:'1‘ic'I‘3
`to the imitation of the innovator’s invention. Then a scenario like the one shown 1“
`panel (b) of Figure 17.1 might unfold. Soon after the new product appears;
`peting firms will introduce their imitating products, squeezing the demand 55
`ule left for the original innovator to D2. With less residual demand, the ilIl1DV3mr
`.
`.
`.
`‘cc
`must derive a new marginal revenue function MR2 and set a new. lower P“
`
`WCK1075
`Page 7
`
`
`
`
`
`WCK1075
`Page 7
`
`

`
`
`
`
`
`SCHERER/ROSS
`
`WCK1075
`Page 8
`
`'
`
`
`
`WCK1075
`Page 8
`
`

`
`EC0NOM/STS /NCORPORA TED
`SUITE 600, 1233 20th STREET. N.W.
`WASHINGTON, 0.6‘. 20036
`
`Industrial Market Structure
`
`and Economic Performance
`
`Third Edition
`
`F.M. Scherer
`
`Harvard University
`
`David Ross
`
`Williams College
`
`Houghton Mifflin Company Boston
`Dallas
`Geneva, Illinois
`Palo Alto
`Princeton, NJ
`
`WCK1075
`
`Page 9
`
`I
`
`WCK1075
`Page 9
`
`

`
` Contents
`
`
`List of Figures
`x
`List of Tables
`xiii
`
`Preface
`
`xv
`
`Chapter 1
`Introduction
`1
`
`
`The Scope and Method of Industrial Organization Analysis
`An Introductory Paradigm
`The Role of Public Policies
`
`2
`4
`7
`
`Chapter 2 The Welfare Economics of Competition and
`Monopoly
`1 5
`
`
`Competition Defined
`
`The Case for Competition
`Qualifications and Doubts
`
`The Problem of Second Best
`
`Doubts Concerning the Profit Maximization Hypothesis
`Workable Competition
`Conclusion
`
`15
`
`18
`29
`
`33
`
`38
`52
`55
`
`Chapter 3
`Industry Structure
`57
`
`
`The Position of the Largest Corporations
`Concentration in Particular Markets
`
`The Diversification of American Corporations
`
`Vertical Integration in American Industry
`
`57
`70
`
`90
`
`94
`
`Chapter 4 The Determinants of Market Structure
`97
`
`
`Economies of Scale
`
`Stochastic Determinants of Market Structure
`
`The Impact of Government Policies
`
`:
`
`97
`
`141
`
`146
`
`Chapter 5 Mergers: History, Effects, and Policy
`153
` _Mj
`
`Broad Trends in Merger Activity
`
`The Motives for Merger
`
`Statistical Evidence on Merger Outcomes
`
`153
`
`159
`
`167
`
`WCK1075
`Page 10
`
`
`
`WCK1075
`Page 10
`
`

`
`
`
`vi Contents
`
`U.S. Policies toward Mergers
`Merger Policy in Other Nations
`Conclusion
`
`1 74
`194
`198
`
`199
`Chapter 6 Economic Theories of Oligopoly Pricing
` _________
`Oligopolistic Interdependence
`199
`The Contributions of Game Theory
`208
`Imperfect Information and Uncertainty
`215
`Dominant Firm Behavior
`221
`Conclusion
`226
`
`Appendix to Chapter 6
`The Quantity-Coumot Model
`The Cournot Model with Conjectural Variations
`The von Stackelberg Leader-Follower Model
`Forchheimer’s Dominant Firm Model
`
`227
`227
`229
`231
`233
`
`I
`
`I
`
`'
`
`|
`
`I
`
`Chapter 7 Conditions Facilitating Oligopolistic Coordination
`Overt and Covert Agreements
`Price Leadership
`Rule-of-thumb Pricing as a Coordinating Device
`Focal Points and Tacit Coordination
`Order Backlogs, Inventories, and Oligopolistic Coordination
`
`Appendix to Chapter 7
`
`235
`235
`248
`261
`265
`268
`
`2 75
`
`
`
`273 Conclusion
`
` 275
`Cartel Pricing When Costs Differ
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Chapter 8 Conditions Limiting Oligopolistic Coordination
`Number and Size Distribution of Sellers .;
`Product Heterogeneity
`’
`.
`Dynamic Implications of Cost Structures
`A Digression on Cutthroat Competition
`Lumpiness and Infrequency of Orders
`Secrecy and Retaliation Lags
`The Social Scene
`Conclusion
`
`277
`277
`279
`285
`294
`306
`308
`311
`315
`WCK1 075
`
`'
`
`
`
`
`
`Page 11
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`WCK1075
`Page 11
`
`

`
`
`
`Contents
`
`vii
`
`Chapter 9 Antitrust Policies Toward Price-Fixing
`Arrangements
`
`The Evolution of U.S. Law
`
`Remedies and Penalties in Price-Fixing Cases
`
`Antitrust Abroad: A Comparison
`
`The Per Se vs. Rule of Reason Question Revisited
`
`Oligopoly Pricing and the Conscious Parallelism Doctrine
`
`Price Leadership
`
`Trade Association Price and Cost Reporting Activities
`Conclusion
`
`3 1 7
`
`317
`
`325
`
`328
`
`335
`
`339
`
`346
`
`347
`352
`
`Chapter 10 The Dynamics of Monopoly and Oligopoly Pricing
`
`353
`
`Substitution and Long-Run Demand Functions
`
`Limiting Small-Scale Entry
`
`Deterring Large-Scale Entry
`
`Entry Deterrence Through Plant Location Strategy
`
`Entry Deterrence Through Product Differentiation
`
`Other Dynamic Influences Affecting Price
`Conclusion
`
`Chapter 11 Market Structure and Performance: Empirical
`Appraisal
`”
`‘
`
`Basic Paradigm
`Measurement Problems
`
`Cross-Section Studies
`
`Time Series Studies
`
`Conclusion
`
`353
`
`356
`
`374
`
`396
`
`404
`
`407
`410
`
`41 1
`
`412
`415
`
`426
`
`440
`
`446
`
`Chapter 12 Antitrust Policy Toward Monopoly Market
`
`'
`Structures
`449
`
`Monopoly and Monopolization
`
`The Emergence of a Rule of Reason
`The Alcoa Case and Its Aftermath
`Renaissance and Decline
`
`The Predatory Pricing Problem
`
`Proposals to Reform Sherman Act Section 2
`
`Policy toward Monopoly Positions Abroad
`
`449
`
`450
`453
`458
`
`468
`
`479
`
`483
`
`WCK1075
`Page 12
`
`
`
`WCK1075
`Page 12
`
`

`
`l
`|
`
`l
`
`'
`
`!
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`viii Contents
`
`Chapter 13 Price Discrimination
`Standard Theoretical Cases
`Types of Discrimination Found in Practice
`The Implications of Discrimination for Economic Welfare
`Antitrust Policies Toward Price Discrimination
`
`Chapter 14 Buyer Power and Vertical Pricing Relationships
`
`The Extent of Buyer Concentration
`The Exercise of Buyer Power: Theory
`Countervailing Power and Consumer Prices
`Conclusion
`
`Appendix to Chapter 14
`
`Chapter 15 Vertical Restraints: Law and Economics
`
`The Theoretical Paradox and Its Resolution
`Resale Price Maintenance in Theory and Practice
`Exclusive Franchising
`
`Exclusive Dealing, Requirements Contracts, and Tying
`Conclusion
`
`xv
`
`Chapter 16 Product Differentiation, Market Structure, and
`Competition
`
`489
`489
`491
`494
`508
`
`517
`
`51 7
`519
`527
`535
`
`537
`
`541
`
`541
`548
`558
`
`562
`569
`
`5 7 1
`
`Advertising, Information, and Persuasion
`Advertising, Image, and Monopoly Power
`The Role of Market Structure
`Market Structure and Product Variety
`Conclusion
`
`572
`580
`592
`600
`
`Chapter 17 Market Structure, Patents, and Technological
`Innovation
`*
`
`_
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Industrial Innovation
`The Logic ofPatent Protection
`The Links Between Market Structure and Innovation
`
`614
`621
`630
`
`
`j
`
`
`
`The Evidence
`Conclusion
`
`
`
`
`
`WCK1075
`
`Page 13
`
`644
`
`WCK1075
`Page 13
`
`

`
`Chapter 18 Market Structure and Performance: Overall
`Appraisal
`
`661
`The Welfare Losses Attributable to Resource Misallocation
`Other Inefficiencies
`
`Contents
`
`ix
`
`661
`
`Other Effects of Monopoly Power
`Conclusion
`
`Author Index
`
`Subject Index
`
`667
`
`679
`
`685
`
`687
`
`703
`
`WCK1075
`Page 14
`
`
`
`WCK1075
`Page 14

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket