throbber
TURNING GOLD TO LEAD: HOW PATENT ELIGIBILITY
`DOCTRINE IS UNDERMINING U.S. LEADERSHIP IN INNOVATION
`
`Kevin Madigan* & Adam Mossoff**
`
`Compared to other countries, the United States has long had a “gold
`standard” patent system. The U.S. has led the world in securing stable and
`effective property rights in cutting-edge innovation; most recently, in
`protecting biotech and computer software inventions. Presenting
`information from a database of 17,743 patent applications recently filed in
`the U.S., China, and Europe, this Essay explains how this “gold standard”
`designation is now in serious doubt. Many of these applications represent
`pioneering, life-saving inventions, such as treatments for cancer and
`diabetes. Although all 17,743 patent applications were rejected in the U.S.
`as ineligible for patent protection, 1,694 of them were granted by the
`European Patent Office, by China, or both. The cause of the U.S. rejections
`is the Supreme Court’s recent spate of decisions that upended patent
`eligibility doctrine, especially as it has been applied to high-tech and
`biotech innovation. The U.S. patent system is increasingly mired in legal
`uncertainty, except for the firm knowledge derived from data on the
`massive numbers of invalidations of issued patents and of rejections of
`patent applications. In addition to highlighting some of the 1,694
`inventions that were denied patent protection in the U.S., this Essay
`discusses this new legal uncertainty in the U.S. patent system, how this is a
`key change from the innovation-spurring approach of the U.S. patent
`system in the past, and what this means for the U.S. as other jurisdictions
`like China and the European Union become forerunners in securing the
`new innovation that drives economic growth and flourishing societies.
`
`INTRODUCTION
`
`Over the past ten years, the United States patent system has been
`transformed by new legislation,1 regulatory actions,2 and numerous
`
`* Legal Fellow, Center for the Protection of Intellectual Property, Antonin Scalia Law School at George
`Mason University. The authors would like to thank Robert Sachs and David Kappos for providing them
`with the database of patent applications that is reported on in this Essay.
`** Professor of Law, Antonin Scalia Law School at George Mason University.
`1 See generally Leahy-Smith America Invents Act, Pub. L. No. 112-29, 125 Stat. 284 (2011) (codified
`in scattered sections of 35 U.S.C.).
`2 See Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm’n, FTC Finalizes Settlement in Google Motorola Mobility Case,
`(July 24, 2013), https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/press-releases/2013/07/ftc-finalizes-settlement-
`google-motorola-mobility-case (discussing the FTC’s approval of Google/Motorola merger, in which
`the FTC required Google to commit to the non-enforcement its standard essential patents); see also
`
`Voip-Pal Ex. 2096
`IPR2016-01198 and IPR2016-01201
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`decisions by the United States Supreme Court addressing all areas of patent
`doctrine. These widespread and systematic changes have affected
`infringement remedies,3 licensing activities,4 and what types of inventions
`and discoveries are eligible for patent protection,5 among many other patent
`rights and doctrines. Inventors, universities, and companies working in the
`U.S. innovation economy have faced more than a decade of extensive legal
`changes to the patent system,6 and this constantly morphing legal landscape
`has created extensive uncertainty for all stakeholders.
`These many disruptive legal changes raise the question whether the
`U.S. still can lay claim to being the “gold standard” patent system as
`compared to the rest of the world.7 This concern is particularly salient in
`patent eligibility doctrine. In four decisions issued between 2010 and 2014,
`
`Letter from Renata B. Hesse, Acting Assistant Att’y Gen., U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Antitrust Division, to
`Michael A. Lindsay, Esq., Dorsey & Whitney LLP (Feb. 2, 2015), https://www.justice.gov/atr/response-
`institute-electrical-and-electronics-engineers-incorporated (approving under the antitrust laws the
`Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers, Inc. (“IEEE”)’s rules prohibiting enforcement of
`standard essential patents declared in this standard-setting organization).
`3 See eBay, Inc. v. MercExchange, LLC, 547 U.S. 388, 392–93 (2006) (holding that an injunction is not
`presumptively available to patent-owners on a finding of infringement); see also Samsung Elec. Co. v.
`Apple Inc., 137 S. Ct. 429, 434–36 (2016) (holding that damages must be limited to the particular value
`of a component, and not the market value of a device comprising this component).
`4 See Impression Prods, Inc. v. Lexmark Int’l, Inc., 137 S. Ct. 1523, 1533 (2017) (holding that any and
`all sales of a patented product by the patent-owner regardless of the conditions imposed on the sale
`automatically terminates all patent rights); MedImmune, Inc. v. Genentech, Inc., 549 U.S. 118, 137
`(2007) (holding that a licensee can challenge the validity of the licensed patent in court without having
`to be liable for infringement by first violating the license agreement).
`5 See Alice Corp. v. CLS Bank Int’l, 134 S. Ct. 2347, 2360 (2014) (holding that a computer program for
`facilitating complex international financial transactions is an abstract idea and cannot be patented); see
`also Ass’n for Molecular Pathology v. Myriad Genetics, Inc., 133 S. Ct. 2107, 2117 (2013) (holding
`that isolated DNA for laboratory and medical uses is an unpatentable natural phenomenon); Mayo
`Collaborative Servs. v. Prometheus Labs., Inc., 566 U.S. 66, 72–73 (2012) (holding that a diagnostic
`medical treatment for an autoimmune disorder is an unpatentable discovery of a law of nature); Bilski v.
`Kappos, 561 U.S. 593, 609 (2010) (holding that a business method for hedging investment risk is an
`abstract idea and not a patentable invention).
`6 There have also been numerous bills introduced in Congress each year, which have entailed extensive
`and expensive lobbying fights and policy debates. See, e.g., Venue Equity and Non-Uniformity
`Elimination Act of 2016, S. 2733, 114th Cong. (2016); Innovation Act, H.R. 9, 114th Cong. (2015);
`Innovation Act, H.R. 3309, 113th Cong. (2013); Saving High-Tech Innovators from Egregious Legal
`Disputes Act of 2013, H.R. 845, 113th Cong. (2013).
`7 See Ashley Gold et al., Lee Staying on as Patent Chief Under Trump Administration, POLITICO (Jan.
`19, 2017), http://www.politico.com/blogs/donald-trump-administration/2017/01/michelle-lee-patent-
`office-chief-to-stay-on-233847 (quoting Adam Mossoff that “the U.S. has lost its ‘gold standard’ patent
`system—it no longer promises stable, effective property rights to innovators”); David Kappos et al.,
`From Efficient Licensing To Efficient Infringement, N.Y. L.J. (Apr. 4, 2016),
`http://www.newyorklawjournal.com/id=1202753754690/From-Efficient-Licensing-to-Efficient-
`Infringement?slreturn=20170307103946 (“The recent degradation of the U.S. patent system will test the
`long history of economic prosperity associated with strengthening, rather than weakening, intellectual
`property rights.” (footnote omitted)); Joff Wild, Sadly, Michelle Lee is Wrong to Believe the US IP
`System is Gold Standard and That it Works for the Little Guy, INTELL. ASSET MGMT. (Dec. 15, 2013),
`www.iam-media.com/blog/Detail.aspx?g=ce27a358-7b3f-4fe5-b8fe-4cc7e73fd515 (discussing PTO
`Director Michelle Lee’s designation of the US patent system as the “gold standard” and stating that
`“[w]hen Lee talks about the amount of innovation the US produces showing that the US system is the
`gold standard, she is talking about the past.”).
`
`
`
`2
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the Supreme Court created a new legal test for determining whether an
`invention or discovery fundamentally counts as a technological innovation
`worthy of a patent under § 101 of the Patent Act.8 Unfortunately, as
`commentators have pointed out, this legal test is rife with indeterminacy,
`creating substantial doubt as to whether long-term research and
`development (“R&D”) expenditures can be recaptured through stable and
`effective property rights in technological innovation.9
`
`This recent legal development raises an important question about
`whether the U.S. is surrendering its long-held position as the world leader
`in promoting and securing new technological innovation. This is
`significant, because other countries are neither standing still nor following
`the U.S. lead this time. Other jurisdictions, such as in Europe and China,
`are now granting patents for the same or related inventions and discoveries
`that are being rejected in the U.S. as ineligible for patent protection. This
`raises the question of whether these countries are positioning themselves to
`bypass the U.S. as the forerunners of innovation, especially in the research-
`intensive sectors of the innovation economy, such as in the life sciences,
`biotech, and high tech.
`
`This Essay contributes to this critical policy question by offering
`some empirical data on the impact of the new patent eligibility doctrines on
`existing patents and on patent applications. It presents statistics on patent-
`eligibility decisions in U.S. courts and at the United States Patent and
`Trademark Office (“PTO”), and it presents for the very first time
`information from a database of 17,743 recently filed patent applications in
`the U.S., the European Patent Office (“EPO”), and China.10 All of these
`patent applications were rejected (and then abandoned) in the U.S. on the
`ground that they are ineligible for patent protection under § 101, but 1,694
`of them were granted by the EPO, in China, or by both. These 1,694 patent
`applications rejected by the PTO raise the specter of the U.S. losing its gold
`standard status, as many of these patent applications represent innovative
`
`
`8 See cases cited supra note 5.
`9 See, e.g., Brief of 19 Law Professors as Amici Curiae in Support of Petition for Writ of Certiorari at
`13, Sequenom, Inc. v. Ariosa Diagnosis, Inc., 136 S. Ct 2511 (2016) (No. 15-1182), 2016 WL 1605521
`(detailing how the Supreme Court’s new test for patent eligibility is both indeterminate and overly
`restrictive).
`10 This database was compiled by Robert Sachs, a Partner at Fenwick & West, and David Kappos, a
`Partner at Cravath, Swaine & Moore LLP and former Director of the PTO. An earlier version of this
`database obtained by the authors was limited in scope, and this resulted in previous drafts mistakenly
`reporting that 1,728 patent applications had been granted in China and by the EPO but had been denied
`in the U.S. The database has since been updated and the correct numbers are reported here. The 17,743
`patent applications is a subset of 48,586 total patent applications that received a § 101 rejection in initial
`or final office actions and then were abandoned between August 1, 2014 and September 27, 2017. The
`17,743 applications received final rejections by the PTO as patent ineligible. The database can be
`accessed here: https://cpip.gmu.edu/wp-content/uploads/sites/31/2017/10/Madigan-Mossoff-Turning-
`Gold-to-Lead-Final-Dataset.pdf. For questions about the database, please contact Robert Sachs at
`RSachs@fenwick.com.
`
`
`
`3
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`and life-saving inventions in the life sciences and biotech, such as
`diagnostic cancer treatments, medical devices, and ultrasound imaging.11
`
`In addressing this concern about the U.S. conceding its gold
`standard patent system to China and Europe, increasingly voiced by many
`lawyers and commentators, this Essay explains how and why this matters.
`First, it details why the U.S. has been referred to as having a gold-standard
`patent system relative to other countries. Second, it briefly explains the four
`recent patent-eligibility decisions by the U.S. Supreme Court. Third, it
`presents statistics and other empirical data on how the Court’s patent-
`eligibility doctrine has been applied by the PTO and the courts, with
`reference to some examples from the database of 17,743 patent
`applications.
`
`
`THE GOLD STANDARD PATENT SYSTEM IN THE U.S.
`
`I.
`
`
`The U.S. has long been regarded as the world leader in securing
`
`property rights in technological innovation, granting patents for the next
`wave of discoveries when the rest of the world hesitates. Professor Zorina
`Kahn, a leading economic historian, concludes that the U.S. patent system
`has been successful precisely because it consistently secured legal
`protection for the fruits of inventors’ labors.12 This truth is confirmed by the
`spread of patent laws across the world throughout the nineteenth and early
`twentieth centuries that were explicitly modeled on the U.S. system.13 This
`pattern of U.S. leadership in securing patents in the next wave of
`innovation continued up through the two most recent technological
`revolutions of our modern era: the biotechnology and high-tech revolutions.
`
`
`Biotechnology
`
`A.
`
`
`In 1980, the Supreme Court held in Diamond v. Chakrabarty14 that
`
`a genetically modified bacterium is a patentable innovation under § 101 of
`
`
`11 See infra note 81 and accompanying chart.
`12 B. Zorina Kahn, Trolls and Other Patent Inventions: Economic History and the Patent Controversy in
`the Twenty-First Century, 21 GEO. MASON L. REV. 825, 855 (2014) (describing how “[i]ntellectual
`property institutions were successful in the United States largely because they ensured open access to
`creative individuals, decentralized decision making and extensive markets for technology, and strong
`legal enforcement of such rights”); see also Adam Mossoff, A Brief History of Software Patents (and
`Why They’re Valid), 56 ARIZ. L. REV. SYLLABUS 62 (2014) (explaining how the U.S. patent system has
`succeeded because it secured property rights in the new innovation that has come about with each new
`era, whether in the Industrial Revolution or in the Digital Revolution).
`13 See Kahn, supra note 12, at 854–55 (discussing how intellectual property rights played a prominent
`role in the nineteenth century in the U.S. overtaking other nations as a leader in industry and
`technology, which led to “many countries voluntarily adopting the distinctive U.S. rules and
`standards”).
`14 447 U.S. 303 (1980).
`
`
`
`4
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the Patent Act.15 Although largely forgotten today, this was a time in which
`the patentability of the cutting-edge, innovative discoveries in the nascent
`biotech revolution was highly controversial.16 The Chakrabarty Court
`definitively settled the question in the U.S.: pioneering work by scientists
`and innovators in the U.S. should be promoted and protected by the patent
`system.17 Commentators widely recognize that Chakrabarty was a key
`factor in spurring the explosive growth in the biotech industry in the
`ensuing decade in the U.S.18
`The Charkrabarty Court’s recognition that the products of biotech
`
`research are patentable, especially when such products are living organisms
`or represent the building blocks of life, paved the way for dramatic
`advances in the life sciences and in medical treatment, such as in cancer
`research. One prominent example is the invention of the “oncomouse” in
`the 1980s. After the Chakrabarty decision, researchers at Harvard Medical
`School created a mouse that was genetically prone to cancer by giving it a
`gene that causes tumor growth, leading to invaluable opportunities to
`research new treatments for cancer.19 Following the Chakrabarty precedent,
`the U.S. was the first country to secure a patent in this radical biotech
`innovation in 1988.20
`
`The genetic modification of living organisms has been
`controversial,21 and as a result of this controversy, other countries initially
`refused to secure this innovation with patents. For fifteen years, the
`oncomouse patent application languished in the European Patent Office,
`mired in a legal quagmire of a series of rejections, court appeals, and
`remands back to the EPO for re-examination of the patent application; the
`
`15 Id. at 310.
`16 Id. at 316 (detailing a “parade of horribles” from Nobel Laureates and other scientists about the
`dangers of biotech research, who argued that it should not be patentable).
`17 Id. at 316–17. The Court recognized that biotech innovation like the genetically modified bacteria at
`issue in this case is a patentable invention “precisely because such inventions are often unforeseeable.”
`Id. at 316. This was a significant insight by the Court, because this is the function of the patent
`system—to promote and secure dynamic innovation. See Adam Mossoff, A Simple Conveyance Rule for
`Complex Innovation, 44 TULSA L. REV. 707, 729 (2009) (discussing Chakrabarty and other cases as
`exemplifying the purpose of the patent system in securing unpredictable innovation precisely because
`innovation is unpredictable).
`18 See, e.g., ROBERT PATRICK MERGES & JOHN FITZGERALD DUFFY, PATENT LAW AND POLICY 76 (5th
`ed. 2011) (noting that Chakrabarty was “extremely important for the then-nascent biotechnology
`industry because it established that the fruits of the industry’s research . . . would be eligible for
`patenting”); see also John Edward Schneider, Microorganisms and the Patent Office: To Deposit or Not
`to Deposit, That is the Question, 52 FORDHAM L. REV. 592, 592, 594 (1984) (noting that the “revolution
`in biotechnology is one of the most important developments affecting industry in the twentieth century”
`and that Chakrabarty “spurred the increased commercial interest in biotechnology” (footnotes
`omitted)).
`19 Bioethics and Patent Law: The Case of the Oncomouse, WIPO MAGAZINE, June 2006, at 16,
`http://www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/wipo_magazine/en/pdf/2006/wipo_pub_121_2006_03.pdf.
`20 U.S. Patent No. 4,736,866 (issued Apr. 12, 1988).
`21 See, e.g., Bioethics and Patent Law, supra note 19 (discussing ethical concerns regarding transgenic
`technology).
`
`
`
`5
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`EPO finally relented and granted the patent in 2004, almost two decades
`after the U.S. patent had been issued.22 Even worse, after a similar multi-
`decade legal fight, some countries rejected outright the patent application
`on the oncomouse, such as Canada’s final rejection of the patent application
`in 2002.23 Although the EPO ultimately ceded to the patenting of this
`innovation, its decision to do so decades after the U.S. was significant for
`the development of a domestic biotech industry in the U.S. By first
`securing property rights in the fruits of biotech research, the U.S. became
`the birthplace of the biotech revolution.24 Europe lost the competitive and
`commercial edge in biotechnology to the U.S., which had the foresight to
`protect a new and innovative industry. This new industry both
`revolutionized modern medical research and healthcare treatments and
`brought economic growth to the many U.S. cities in which these new
`companies sprouted and flourished.25
`
`B.
`
`
`Software Programs
`
`In the early days of digital computing, there was great uncertainty
`
`surrounding what exactly constituted a software program and whether these
`programs represented a patentable invention.26 This confusion was obvious
`in 1972 in Gottschalk v. Benson27 when the Supreme Court denied patent
`protection for a software program, asserting that the patent claimed merely
`a “mathematical formula” and thus was unpatentable as an “abstract idea.”28
`At the time of Benson, digital computers were still in their infancy as
`consumer products, as it was a decade before the Personal Computer
`(“PC”) Revolution of the 1980s. Thus, the legal and technological
`confusion reflected in Benson about the nature of software innovation was
`
`
`22 See id. at 17 (explaining how in 2004 the EPO “concluded that the usefulness of the oncomouse in
`furthering cancer research satisfied the likelihood of substantial medical benefit, and outweighed moral
`concerns about suffering caused to the animal”).
`23 See Harvard Coll. v. Canada (Commissioner of Patents), [2002] 4 S.C.R. 45, 46, 122 (Can.) (finding
`that “[a] higher life form is not patentable because it is not a ‘manufacture’ or ‘composition of matter’
`within the meaning of ‘invention’” in [Canada’s] Patent Act”).
`24 See Life Sciences and Biotechnology—A Strategy for Europe: Communication from the Commission
`to the European Parliament, the Council, the Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the
`Regions, at 14–15, COM (2002) [hereinafter Life Sciences and Biotechnology]; see also CLAUDE
`BARFIELD & JOHN E. CALFEE, BIOTECHNOLOGY AND THE PATENT SYSTEM: BALANCING INNOVATION
`AND PROPERTY RIGHTS 24–29 (2007) (discussing the especially crucial role patent protection has
`played in biotechnological innovation).
`25 See Life Sciences and Biotechnology, supra note 24, at 14–15 (discussing Europe’s “fragile”
`biotechnology sector and noting that “the US biotechnology industry started earlier, produces more than
`three times the revenues of the European industry, employs many more people (162,000 against around
`60,000), is much more strongly capitalized and, in particular, has more products in the pipeline”).
`26 See generally Mossoff, supra note 17 (discussing this early history and controversy); see also
`MERGES & DUFFY, supra note 18, at 134–35, 154–58.
`27 409 U.S. 63 (1972).
`28 Id. at 71–72.
`
`
`
`6
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`perhaps understandable.29 Still, Justice William Douglas’s opinion in
`Benson was unfortunate, because it inserted into patent law a fundamental
`misunderstanding about computer programs. It would be nearly ten years
`before a more careful and better-informed Supreme Court corrected this
`initial misstep.
`In 1981, the Supreme Court held in Diamond v. Diehr30 that a
`
`computer program was not automatically an “abstract idea” or “algorithm”
`that precluded patent protection.31 Consistent with the Chakrabarty decision
`the year before, the Diehr Court recognized that the use of a computer
`software program to operate a machine for a useful purpose—in this case, a
`manufacturing process for curing rubber—was technological innovation
`deserving of legal protection in the patent system.32 The key was
`recognizing how the software program functioned in creating new
`technological innovation; in the technical terms of patent law, the Diehr
`Court reaffirmed a basic precept of patent law that all patent claims must be
`evaluated as a whole as to their nature and function as new, useful, and
`nonobvious inventions.33
`
`In the ensuing PC Revolution in which software programs became
`separate commercial products that served particular and useful functions for
`consumers who purchased them in the marketplace, the courts’
`understanding of the nature of software innovation and its patent eligibility
`also evolved. In the 1990s, the Court of Appeals of the Federal Circuit thus
`recognized that software programs represented the equivalent of a digital
`machine.34 If a mechanical typewriter was a patentable invention in the
`analog world of the Industrial Revolution in the nineteenth century, then a
`word processor is a patentable invention as a digital machine in the high-
`tech revolution of the late twentieth century. In their specific technological
`and commercial contexts, a typewriter and a word processor program are
`each a valuable machine that serves a specific function for end-users. Thus,
`as cutting-edge innovation, each invention is precisely what the patent
`system is supposed to promote and secure to inventors and to the
`companies that deploy these products and services in the marketplace. 35
`
`
`29 See Mossoff, supra note 12, at 70 n.29.
`30 450 U.S. 175 (1981).
`31 Id. at 184–89.
`32 See id. at 187 (“[A] claim drawn to subject matter otherwise statutory does not become nonstatutory
`simply because it uses a mathematical formula, computer program, or digital computer.”).
`33 Id. at 192 (finding that “when a claim containing a mathematical formula implements or applies that
`formula in a structure or process which, when considered as a whole, is performing a function which the
`patent laws were designed to protect (e. g., transforming or reducing an article to a different state or
`thing), then the claim satisfies the requirements of § 101”).
`34 In re Alappat, 33 F.3d 1526, 1545 (Fed. Cir. 1994).
`35 See Brief of Ten Law Professor as Amici Curiae in Support of Plaintiff-Appellee at 9–10, Trading
`Techs. Int’l, Inc. v. CQG, Inc., 675 Fed. App’x 1001 (Fed. Cir. 2017) (No. 2016-1616), 2016 WL
`401711; Mossoff, supra note 12, at 80 (warning that “[t]o restrict the patent system to only the valuable
`
`
`
`
`7
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`The court decisions in Diehr, Chakrabarty, and Alappat, among
`
`others, meant that innovators knew the fruits of their inventive labors
`would be secured to them under U.S. law. Despite fluctuations over time in
`the specific legal protections provided to innovators in the U.S., the patent
`system has generally secured stable and effective property rights in the new
`innovation that drove the Industrial Revolution, the Biotech Revolution,
`and the Digital Revolution.36 For this reason, it rightly earned the “gold
`standard” designation compared to the rest of the world. But this “gold
`standard” designation is now open to question, as the U.S. has retreated in
`recent years from ensuring that its patent system is properly forward
`looking in promoting and securing new technological innovation in the
`twenty-first century.
`
`II.
`
`
`THE NEW PATENT ELIGIBILITY JURISPRUDENCE
`
`Between 2010 and 2014, the Supreme Court issued four decisions
`
`that have dramatically restricted the scope of inventions that can receive
`patent protection: Bilski v. Kappos,37 Mayo Collaborative Services v.
`Prometheus Laboratories, Inc.,38 Association for Molecular Pathology
`(“AMP”) v. Myriad Genetics,39 and Alice Corp. v. CLS Bank
`International.40 These four decisions have significantly impacted the U.S.
`patent system. First, they each respectively restricted the scope of
`patentable inventions, and thereby incrementally chipped away at the
`innovation gains achieved by Chakrabarty, Diehr, and other prior court
`decisions. The totality of these four decisions is a substantial restriction on
`the scope of what counts as a patentable invention. Second, and far worse,
`they have injected tremendous legal uncertainty into the U.S. patent system,
`undermining the ability of inventors, universities, venture capitalists, and
`companies to make long-term investment decisions in R&D.41 This Part
`will briefly review these decisions and detail their impact on the U.S.
`innovation economy.
`
`analog machines and processes of the nineteenth century is to turn the patent system on its head—
`denying today’s innovators the protections of the legal system whose purpose is to promote and secure
`property rights in innovation”).
`36 See generally Stephen Haber, Patents and the Wealth of Nations, 23 GEO. MASON L. REV. 811 (2016)
`(surveying all of the historical and economic research that overwhelmingly proves that patents are a key
`factor in promoting innovation and economic growth).
`37 561 U.S. 593 (2010).
`38 566 U.S. 66 (2012).
`39 133 S. Ct. 2107 (2013).
`40 134 S. Ct. 2347 (2014).
`41 See generally Joan Farre-Mensa et al., What is a Patent Worth?: Evidence from the U.S. Patent
`“Lottery”, (Nat’l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 23268, 2017),
`https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2704028 (finding causal connection between a
`startup’s ownership of a patent and its ability to obtain venture capital funding, and thus finding a causal
`connection between patents and the ultimate market success of a startup company).
`
`
`
`8
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`A.
`
`
`Bilski v. Kappos
`
`In 2010, the Supreme Court addressed for the first time whether
`
`new and useful business methods are patentable inventions as a “process”
`under § 101 of the Patent Act.42 Despite an extensive legal and policy
`debate about the patent eligibility of business methods,43 the Bilksi Court
`held that they are an invented process capable of being patented (as long as
`they met the other patentability requirements).44 While the Bilski Court
`emphasized that business method patents are not unpatentable per se,
`provoking a strident “dissent” on this issue by Justice John Stevens,45 the
`Court ultimately concluded that the business method in this case was in fact
`an “abstract idea” and thus unpatentable.46 In reaching this decision, the
`Court provided no legal guidance on how to determine what counts as an
`unpatentable “abstract idea,” creating an ambiguous legal precedent that
`has provided no guidance to stakeholders in the high-tech industry as to
`how it might be applied to their inventive work-product. Unsurprisingly,
`commentators bemoan how Bilski started a legal practice of mass
`invalidation of patents on software, business methods, and diagnostic
`methods with vague or conclusory court opinions,47 which only picked up
`speed in the ensuing years.
`
`
`
`42 35 U.S.C § 101 (2012) (“Whoever invents or discovers any new and useful process, machine,
`manufacture, or composition of matter, or any new and useful improvement thereof, may obtain a patent
`therefor, subject to the conditions and requirements of this title.” (emphasis added)).
`43 Compare Michael Risch, Everything is Patentable, 75 TENN. L. REV. 591, 609–11 (2008) (arguing
`that business methods are patentable) with Robert P. Merges, As Many as Six Impossible Patents Before
`Breakfast: Property Rights for Business Concepts and Patent System Reform, 14 BERKELEY TECH. L.J.
`577, 581 (1999) (arguing that business methods should not be patentable).
`44 Bilski v. Kappos, 561 U.S. 593, 604 (2010) (“This Court’s precedents establish that the machine-or-
`transformation test is a useful and important clue, an investigative tool, for determining whether some
`claimed inventions are processes under § 101. The machine-or-transformation test is not the sole test for
`deciding whether an invention is a patent-eligible ‘process.’”).
`45 See id. at 613–57 (Stevens, J., concurring). Justice Stevens’ opinion is nominally styled as a
`concurrence, because he agreed with the decision that the patent in this case was an unpatentable
`abstract idea, but the substance of his opinion is a lengthy, wide-ranging dissent from the Bilski Court’s
`holding that business methods are patentable inventions.
`46 Id. at 611.
`47 See, e.g., Edward Van Gieson & Paul Stellman, Killing Good Patents to Wipe out Bad Patents:
`Bilski, the Evolution of Patentable Subject Matter Rules, and the Inability to Save Valuable Patents
`Using the Reissue Statute, 27 SANTA CLARA COMPUTER & HIGH TECH. L.J. 403, 404 (2010) (referring
`to the Bilski decision as “amorphous” and thus predicting that it “has now set the stage for years of
`Federal Circuit litigation defining the scope of patentable subject matter for software and business
`method patents”); Daniel A. Tysver, Are Software and Business Methods Still Patentable After the
`Bilski Decisions?, BITLAW, http://www.bitlaw.com/software-patent/bilski-and-software-patents.html
`(last visited Aug. 13, 2017) (claiming that “some of the software and business method patents issued by
`the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office over the last twenty years are no longer valid under
`the Bilski decisions” and that “[u]nfortunately, we don't have a clear understanding of the dividing line
`between patentable software and business method inventions and unpatentable ideas”).
`
`
`
`9
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`B. Mayo Collaborative Services v. Prometheus Laboratories, Inc.
`
`
`Two years later, the Supreme Court further narrowed the scope of
`
`patentable subject matter in the life sciences and biotech industry when it
`held that a patent on a medical treatment method was invalid because it was
`a “law of nature.”48 Unlike in Bilski, the Mayo Court was not faced with a
`fundamental question as to whether medical treatment methods are
`patentable inventions—they clearly are—but the Mayo Court concluded in
`this case that th

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket