throbber
PATENT AND TRADEMARK OFFICE
`
`David Lnngdtm. Hmrr'rmiisl and l'uhqrArh'mvr
`Fenwick ‘l’u, Hermann-ifs!
`William l-Iawk‘ Emnnmifi!
`
`(Jule. Dripnly (Ihr'qua'momfs!
`Andrew A
`Asrnt Tcsfayesus. Ecmmmisr
`I
`
`UNITEDSTATES
`
`ALL 2105
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS V. ALLERGAN
`|PR2016-01127, -01128, -01129, -01130, -01131 & -01132
`
`Economics & Statistics
`Administrationf ='
`
`.
`' Trademark. Office
`
`Justin Antonipillai
`
`Michelle K. Lee
`
`Com-ascfor to the Secretary
`Delegated Duties of the Under St‘CI'cltll‘y
`for Economic {Wm-s
`
`Jun-mm for
`Undcr' Secretary qf
`Ir-iteliecuml Property and szfcctor.
`[.18. Palm! and ’l-‘rmlanmrk Office
`
`JOINT PRO'lECT TEAM
`
`Robert Rubinovitz, l'l'epury Cht'quwm'rmist
`
`Alan C. h'larco'. ChiqfEcbmmrfsf
`
`ALL 2105
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS V. ALLERGAN
`IPR2016-01127, -01128, -01129, -01130, -01131 & -01132
`
`

`

`lntellectual Property and the U.S. Economy: 2016 Update
`
`ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
`The Project Team would like to thank Vikrum Aiyer, Alexander Beck, David Carson, Amy Cotton,
`Edward Elliot, lim Hirabayashi, Amanda Myerg Nicholas Pairolero, Sandy Phetsaenngam, Shi-
`ra Perlmutter, Bridget Petruczok, Roy Rabindranath, Patrick Ross, and Daina Spencer from the
`USPTO; Nikolas Zolas and Cynthia Davis Hollingsworth from the Census Bureau; Thomas How-
`ells, Gabriel Medeiros, and Amanda Lyndaker from the Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Ryan
`Noonan and Rodolfu Telles from the Economics and Statistics Administration\ Ofice of the Chief
`Economist for their valuable contributions to this report.
`
`Executive Summary
`Innovation and creative endeavors are indispensable elements that drive economic growth and
`sustain the competitive edge of the U.S. economy. The last century recorded unprecedented
`improvements in the health, economic well-being, and overall quality of life for the entire U.S.
`population.' As the world leader in innovation, U.S. companies have relied on intellectual prop-
`erty (IP) as one of the leading tools with which such advances were promoted and realized. Pat-
`ents, trademarks, and copyrights are the principal means for establishing ownership rights to the
`creations, inventions, and brands that can be used to generate tangible economic benefits to their
`owner.
`
`In 2012, the Department of Commerce issued a report titled Intellectual Property and the U.S.
`Economy: Industries in Focus (hereafter, the 2012 report). The report identified the industries
`that rely most heavily on patents, trademarks, or copyrights as iP-intensive and estimated their
`contribution to the U.S. economy. It generated considerable interest and energized other agencies
`and organizations to produce similar studies investigating the use and impact of IP across coun-
`tries, industries, and firms.
`
`This report builds on the 2012 version by providing an update on the impact of IP on our econo-
`my and a fresh look at the approach used to measure those results. The update continues to focus
`on measuring the intensity of IP use, and its persistent relationship to economic indicators such
`as employment, wages, and value added. While our methodology does not permit us to attribute
`those differences to IP alone, the results provide a useful benchmark. Furthermore, this and other
`studies together make clear that IP is a major part of a robust and growing economy.
`
`Accordingly, in an effort to provide a more comprehensive analysis, this report also incorporates
`findings from other studies that target similar research questions but apply different methodol-
`ogies. Overall, we find that IP-intensive industries continue to be an important and integral part
`of the U.S. economy and account for more jobs and a larger share of U.S. gross domestic product
`(GDP) in 2014 compared to what we observed for 2010, the latest figure available for the 2012
`report. We discuss these and other results in more detail below.
`
`I
`
`Gordon 2016.
`
`ALL 2105
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS V. ALLERGAN
`IPR2016-01127, -01128, -01129, -01130, -01131 & -01132
`
`

`

`lntellectual Property and the U.S. Economy: 2016 Update
`
`il
`
`Principal Findings
`. IP-intensive industries continue to be a majot integral and growing part of the
`U.S. economy.
`. This report identifies 81 industries (from among 313 total) as IP-intensive. These IP-inten-
`sive industries directly accounted for 27.9 million jobs in 2014, up 0.8 million from 2010.
`. Trademark-intensive industries are the largest in number and contribute the most employ-
`ment with 23J million jobs in20l4 (up from 22.6 million in 2010). Copyright-intensive
`industries supplied 5.6 million jobs (compared to 5.1 million in 2010) followed by pat-
`ent-intensive industries with 3.9 million jobs (3.8 million in 2010),
`. While jobs in IP-intensive industries increased between 2010 and 2014, non-lP-intensive
`jobs grew at a slightly faster pace. Consequently, the proportion of total employment in
`IP-intensive industries declined slightly to 18.2 percent (from 18.8 percent in 2010).
`. In contrast, the value added by IP-intensive industries increased substantially in both total
`amount and GDP share between 2010 and2}I4.IP-intensive industries accounted for
`$6.6 trillion in value added in2014, up more than $1.5 trillion (30 percent) from $5.06
`trillion in 2010. Accordingly, the share of total U.S. GDP attributable to IP-intensive in-
`dustries increased from 34.8 percent in 2010 to 38.2 percent in2014.
`. While IP-intensive industries directly accounted for 27.9 million jobs either on their pay-
`rolls or under contract in 2014, they also indirectly supported 17.6 million more supply
`chain jobs throughout the economy. In total, IP-intensive industries directly and indirectly
`supported 45.5 million jobs, about 30 percent of all employment.
`r Private wage and salary workers in IP-intensive industries continue to earn significantly
`more than those in non-IP-intensive industries. In2}L4,workers in IP-intensive indus-
`tries earned an average weekly wage of $1,3L2,46 percent higher than the $896 average
`weekly wages in non-lP-intensive industries in the private sector. This wage premium has
`largely grown over time from 22 percent in 1990 to 42 percent in 2010 and 46 percent in
`2014. Patent- and copyright-intensive industries have seen particularly fast wage growth
`in recent years, with the wage premium reachingT4 percent and 90 percent, respectively,
`in2014.
`
`a
`
`a
`
`The educational gap between workers in IP-intensive and other industries observed in
`2010 virtually disappeared by 2015. The share of workers in IP-intensive industries with a
`bachelor's degree or higher fell from 42.4percent in 2010 to 39.8 percent in 2015, whereas
`that percentage increased from 34.2 percent to 38,9 percent for workers in non-IP-inten-
`sive industries.
`
`Revenue specific to the licensing of IP rights totaled $ 1 15.2 billion in 2012, with 28 indus-
`tries deriving revenues from licensing.
`
`ALL 2105
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS V. ALLERGAN
`IPR2016-01127, -01128, -01129, -01130, -01131 & -01132
`
`

`

`lntellectual Property and the U.S. Economy: 2016 Update
`
`ill
`
`a
`
`o
`
`Total merchandise exports of IP-intensive industries increased to $842 billion in20L4
`from $775 billion in 2010. However, because non-IP-intensive industries'exports in-
`creased at a faster pace, the share of total merchandise exports from IP-intensive indus-
`tries declinedto 52 percent in2014 from 60 percent in 2010.
`
`Exports of service-providing IP-intensive industries totaled about $81 billion rn 2012 and
`accounted for approximately 12.3 percent of total U.S. private services exported in 2012.
`
`ALL 2105
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS V. ALLERGAN
`IPR2016-01127, -01128, -01129, -01130, -01131 & -01132
`
`

`

`lntellectual Property and the U.S. Economy: 2016 Update
`
`lv
`
`1 3 7 7 B 9
`
`. .10
`,. 10
`
`. ..12
`..14
`.. 19
`,, '21
`..22
`..23
`. .27
`
`, ,30
`.,31
`
`., ,31
`
`., ,31
`..32
`.,34
`..35
`..38
`,,39
`.,46
`. .47
`, .53
`
`Table Of Contents
`
`Executive Summary
`l. lntroduction,..,,
`ll, The 2012 Report and Related Studies
`lll. ldentifying lP-lntensive industries. , ,
`
`Patents. . . .
`
`Trademarks
`
`Copyrights,
`lV, lP-lntensive lndustries in the Economy.,,.,,.
`
`Employment
`
`Total Employment Supported by lP-intensive lndustries
`
`lP-lntensive PayrollJobs by State
`
`Average wages.
`
`Education.
`
`Value added
`
`lP Revenue.
`
`Foreign trade. .
`V, Conclusion, , ,
`
`Appendix.
`
`Patents
`
`Fractional vs, Whole Patents Counts
`Methodology ... ..
`
`Trademarks
`
`Trademark lntensity
`
`Top 50 Trademark Registering Companies
`
`Random Sample of All Trademark Registrations . . . , ,
`
`Copyrights.
`
`Combined List of lP-intensive industries. . . .
`
`REFERENCES
`
`ALL 2105
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS V. ALLERGAN
`IPR2016-01127, -01128, -01129, -01130, -01131 & -01132
`
`

`

`lntellectual Property and the U.S. Economy: 2016 Update
`
`1
`
`l. lntroduction
`"Whether through the music or movies that inspire us, the literature that moves
`us) or the technologies we rely on each day, ingenuity and innovation serve as the
`foundation upon which we will continue to grow our economies and bridge our
`cultural identities."
`
`-President Barack Obama, April26, 2016
`Innovation and creative endeavors are indispensable elements that drive economic growth and
`sustain the competitive edge of the U.S. economy. The last century recorded unprecedented im-
`provements in the health, economic well-being, and overall quality of life for the entire U.S. pop-
`ulation as technological innovation in medicine and groundbreaking scientific advances in many
`fields were realized.z Tremendous advances in worker productivity boosted individuals' earning
`capacity. This allowed consumers to purchase and enjoy the abundant supply of new products
`and increasingly diverse creative works of art. As goods and services became more accessible,
`they were distinctively marked so buyers could readily select products that meet their individual
`preferences.
`Intellectual property (IP) has been a vital instrument for achieving such advances throughout our
`nation's history. A growing number of U.S. and international studies demonstrate the important
`role of IP in economic activity. This report shows that lP-intensive industries continue to be a
`major, integral and growing part of the U.S. economy. We find that the 81 industries designated
`as IP-intensive directly accounted for 27.9 million jobs and indirectly supported an additional
`17,6 million jobs in2014. Together, this represented 29.8 percent of all jobs in the U.S' The total
`value added by IP-intensive industries amounted to 38.2 percent of U.S. GDP and IP-intensive
`industries paid 47 percent higher weekly wages compared to other industries. Further, at $842
`billion the merchandise exports of IP-intensive industries made up 52 percent of total U.S. mer-
`chandise exports. Exports of service-providing IP-intensive industries totaled about $81 billion
`in2012, accounting for I2.3 percent of total U.S. private exports in services.
`IP incentivizes the creation of new goods and services by conferring exclusive rights to their
`creators. While inventions typically are a product of ingenious endeavors that require long, per-
`sistent, and meticulous effort, subsequent duplication and use of such innovations are often less
`costly. Patents add to the incentive that inventors have to invest in costly research and develop-
`ment (R&D) by providing the opportunity to reap the rewards of their innovations, In the words
`of Abraham Lincoln, the patent system "added the fuel of interest to the fire of genius in the
`discovery and production of new and useful thingsJ'3 Similarly, copyrights provide the frame-
`work that incentivizes authors to create literary, artistic, musical, dramatic, cinematic, and other
`works by granting them the exclusive right to engage in the activities that derive economic bene-
`
`Gordon 2016.
`
`Nicolay and Hay 1905, 113.
`
`2 -
`
`t
`
`ALL 2105
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS V. ALLERGAN
`IPR2016-01127, -01128, -01129, -01130, -01131 & -01132
`
`

`

`lntellectual Property and the U.S. Economy: 2016 Update
`
`2
`
`fits from their work. Thus, patents and copyrights serve as tools to stimulate individual, firm, and
`industry level entrepreneurial ventures that feed into economic activities nationwide.
`
`To further exploit the potential of their competitive advantage, producers need effective ways
`to indicate to consumers the reliability of their products' source. A trademark "makes effective
`competition possible in a complex, impersonal marketplace by providing a means through which
`the consumer can identify products which please him and reward the producer with continued
`patronagel'a
`
`Patents, trademarks, and copyrights are the principal means for establishing ownership rights
`to the creations, inventions, and brands that can be used to generate tangible economic benefits
`to their owner. In2012, the Department of Commerce issued a report titled Intellectual Proper-
`ty and the (1.5. Economy: Industries in Focus. Produced jointly by the Economics and Statistics
`Administration (ESA) and the United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO), the report
`aimed to identify the industries that rely most heavily on patents, trademarks, or copyrights as
`IP-intensive and estimate the contribution of those industries to the U.S. economy. It generated a
`substantial amount of interest in the IP community, both domestically and abroad, and motivat-
`ed other agencies and organizations to produce similar studies investigating the use and impact
`of IP across countries, industries, and firms.
`
`This update of the 2012 report has two purposes. First, we duplicate the methodology of the 2012
`report to examine how the economic contribution of U.S. IP-intensive industries has evolved.
`Second, we review related studies that have been completed since 20L2, and discuss the contribu-
`tions of the different methods, The latest results bolster the 2012 findings, confirming - across a
`range of methodologies - the importance of IP in the economy. In fact, the relative contribution
`of IP-intensive industries generally increased in the last several years. We describe these and oth-
`er results in more detail in Section IV below.
`
`This report attempts to understand the ways in which IP is used across different industries. Our
`methodology aims to measure the intensity of IP use, but does not directly measure the extent to
`which IP incentivizes the creation of new goods and services, We find differences in employment,
`wages, value added, and other outcomes that are correlated with IP use, although our method-
`ology does not permit us to attribute those differences to IP alone. As in any area of research, no
`single study will yield the complete picture.
`
`This is why it is important for policy-makers and researchers to consider multiple methodologies
`for understanding how IP functions in the economy. We are encouraged that other organizations,
`agencies, and governments have been energized to replicate, extend, or supplement the work
`done in the 2012 report. Taken together, these contributions significantly advance our knowledge.
`Persistent research with a solid empirical foundation will continue to provide the evidence upon
`which good policy can rest. The evidence to date demonstrates that IP is an important part of a
`robust and growing economy.
`
`4
`
`Smith v. Chanel, lnc.402F.2d 562,566 (9'h Cir. 1968)
`
`ALL 2105
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS V. ALLERGAN
`IPR2016-01127, -01128, -01129, -01130, -01131 & -01132
`
`

`

`lntellectual Property and the U.S, Economy: 2016 Update
`
`3
`
`ll. The 2Ol2 Report and Related Studies
`It is instructive to evaluate the methodology and results of the 2012 report in the context of the
`related research completed since the first report's release. The 20L2 report identified IP-intensive
`industries, and compared those industries to other industries across a number of different di-
`mensions. The methodology consisted of identifying IP-intensive industries based on the use of
`IP. According to that report, intellectual property protection affects commerce throughout the
`economy by:
`. Providing incentives to invent and create;
`. Protecting innovators from unauthorized copying;
`. Facilitating vertical specialization in technology markets;
`' Creating a platform for financial investments in innovation;
`. Supporting entrepreneurial liquidity through mergers, acquisitions, and IPOs;
`' Supporting licensing-based technology business models; and
`. Enabling a more efficient market for trading in technology and know-how.
`All of these mechanisms combine to determine the value of IP to individuals and firms and the
`contribution of IP to the economy. Analyzing and measuring all the ways in which IP impacts
`the economy is beyond the scope of any individual report. However, a number of studies quanti-
`fying the economic impact of IP-intensive firms have emerged since the pubiication of the 2012
`report. We are encouraged to see continued interest in research that builds upon, challenges, and
`provides alternative methodologies to the2012 report.
`
`This section reviews a selected group of studies that targeted similar research questions to the
`20L2 report and which were published after that time. The European Patent Office and the Office
`for Harmonization in the InternalMarket (OHIM) published a comparable report in 2013 using
`European Union (EU) data.s 6It relies on similar methodologies to identify intellectual proper-
`ty rights (IPR) intensive industries in Europe and quantifies their contribution to the European
`economy in the 2008-2010 period. The study finds that IPR-intensive industries generated €4.7
`trillion worth of economic activity, which amounted to almost 39o/o of EU GDP. Furthermore, the
`study finds that IPR-intensive industries directly employed 56.5 million Europeans, which ac-
`counted for almost 26% of all,jobs for the period. The similarity in the findings serves to further
`reinforce the core message of the 2012 report that IP-intensive industries are an integral part of
`the economy.
`
`While these reports quantifli the contribution of IP-intensive industries in the economy, there is
`justified skepticism as to how accurately the employment and value added outcomes can be at-
`
`As of March 2016, OHIM is known as the European Union Intellectual Property Office,
`
`EPO and OHIM 2013.
`
`5 6
`
`ALL 2105
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS V. ALLERGAN
`IPR2016-01127, -01128, -01129, -01130, -01131 & -01132
`
`

`

`lntellectual Property and the U.S' Economy: 2016 Update
`
`4
`
`tributed to IP itself. For cxample, the fact that we observe significant employment in IP-intensive
`industries does not inform us about the contribution of IP to economic growth because employ-
`ment in non-IP-intensive industries is a viable alternative. The reports also study the wage differ-
`entials between IP-intensive and non-IP-intensive industries. Both reports show that IP-intensive
`industries pay higher wages than other industries. While this wage premium is noteworthy, we
`cannot conclude that the wage differential is due to IP'
`
`In 2015, OHIM issued a second report, relying on firm-level data to compare firms that own
`IPRs to those that do not.7 The report considers a representative sample of over 130,000 Euro-
`pean firms and studies their economic outcomes, taking into account whether they own patents,
`trademarks, or designs. The study finds that IPR-owning firms earn, on average, 29 percent more
`in revenue per employee and pay, on average, 20 percent more in wages. This difference is even
`more significant for small and medium enterprises that own IPRs as they earn32 percent more
`in revenue, on average, per employee compared to their counterparts with no IPRs. While this
`study does not identify the causal impact of IPRs, it provides detailed evidence of a high correla-
`tion between IPR-ownership and economic performance.
`The methodology in the 2015 OHIM study addresses a limitation in the way the earlier reports
`defined IP-intensive industries. The previous reports measure IP-intensity at the industry-level
`based on the aggregate volume of IP relative to employment. They then designate an industry
`as IP-intensive or non-IP-intensive based on whether the IP to employment ratio falls above or
`below the average for all industries. There are reasonable, alternative measures of IP intensity;
`including a ratio of IP to gross output, research and development, or value added. But data lim-
`itations, such as data sensitivity and the absence of legal requirements on producers to record
`and report on internal activities, preclude access to data at the level of detail needed to systemat-
`ically employ such measures. The 2015 OHIM report successfully overcomes these limitations by
`developing detailed IP-to-firm data necessary for conducting a disaggregated analysis comparing
`IPR-owning with non-IPR-owning firms in Europe.
`
`USPTO and U.S. Census researchers have recently constructed patent-to-firm data to enable
`similar analysis for the U.S.s The authors match data on owners and inventors of U.S. patents
`issued between 2000 and 2011 to U.S. Census Bureau data on firms and workers. Using this com-
`prehensive database, the authors analyzepatent-intensive firms and their contribution to the U.S.
`economy. They find that patenting firms represent only 1 percent of U,S. firms (2000-201 1 ) but
`are among the largest in the economy, accounting for 33 percent of employment. Patenting firms
`create more jobs than their non-patenting counterparts of the same age across all age categories
`except the very youngest (firms <1 year old). The authors also find that most patenting firms are
`small businesses. But; because they patent less frequently, the majority of U.S. patents are held by
`a few large, prolific patenting firms. Lastly, they find that while the manufacturing sector is par-
`
`OHIM 2015.
`Graham etal.2015.
`
`7 8
`
`ALL 2105
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS V. ALLERGAN
`IPR2016-01127, -01128, -01129, -01130, -01131 & -01132
`
`

`

`lntellectual Property and the U.S. Economy: 2016 Update
`
`5
`
`ticularly patent intensive with more than 6 percent of firms owning a Patent between 2000 and
`2011, the majority of patenting firms are in the services and wholesale sectors.
`A handful of recent academic papers have also attempted to measure the impact of IP on firm
`performance. One recent notable contribution uses detailed USPTO data to study whether pat-
`ents have a causal impact on the growth potential of startups.e The authors find that patents do in
`fact "help startups create jobs, grow their sales, innovate, and eventually succeed" and that a delay
`in a patent grant can retard the benefit of each of these.ro 1r
`Another line of research uses surveys to study the role that IP plays in the economic performance
`of firms as well as their innovative efforts. A recent study surveys over 6,000 American manufac-
`turing and service sector firms to evaluate the extent to which firms that introduce new products
`in the market outsource innovation to specialized firms. It finds that between2007 and 2009, 16
`percent of manufacturing firms introduced a new product in their industry, Of these innovators,
`42 percentreported patenting their most significant new product, though there is considerable
`variation across industries and firms. More R&D-intensive industries, i.e., those with above
`average share of firms investing in R&D, tend to patent new products at higher than average
`rates. Roughly 63 percent of large manufacturing firms reported patenting their most significant
`new product innovation, compared to only 47 percent of medium firms and 36 percent of small
`fi.rms.12
`The UK Intellectual Property Office published another survey based study in20l2 that aims to
`quantify the extent to which patents increased expenditure in R&D. Using data from the UK in-
`novation survey and linked data on firm performance, the authors estimate the patent profit pre-
`mium, meaning the additional returns to R&D that can be attributed to patent protection.'' They
`find that patent premiums are positive and provide incentives to invest in R&D, though estimates
`vary by type of firm and industry, Estimated patent premiums are lower for smaller firms and
`firms outside biotech and pharmaceutical industries. However, premium and incentive effects are
`comparable for young and older firms, indicating that patent protection can incentivize R&D for
`new as well as established innovators.
`
`9
`
`Farre-Mensa et a\.2016. By employing an instrumental variables approach, the authors are able to identify a causal
`relationship, as opposed to a mere correlation.
`10 tbid,z.
`I I Note that some startups may prefer a delay in patent grant because a larger share of its overall economic value may be
`realized later in the patent term or during the period of time that is accrued due to patent term adjustment.
`12 Arora et al.2016.
`13 Arora et al.2012.
`
`ALL 2105
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS V. ALLERGAN
`IPR2016-01127, -01128, -01129, -01130, -01131 & -01132
`
`

`

`lntellectual Property and the U.S. Economy: 2016 Update
`
`6
`
`Taken together, these contributions significantly advance our knowledge about the role of IP in
`the economy. An important direction of future work is exploiting even more granular data and
`seeking methods to identify causal links between IP and economic performance. Survey based
`studies, which can be designed to target specific research questions, will also continue to improve
`our understanding about the extent to which IP contributes to the economy. And it is critical that
`policy-makers consider scientific research standards when evaluating evidence with policy mak-
`ing implications.
`
`ALL 2105
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS V. ALLERGAN
`IPR2016-01127, -01128, -01129, -01130, -01131 & -01132
`
`

`

`lntellectual Property and the U,S, Economy: 2016 Update
`
`7
`
`lll. ldentifying lP-lntensive industries
`As in the 2012 report, IP-intensity for an industry is defined as the count of its intellectual prop-
`erty for a given period of time relative to the industry's total employment. An industry is desig-
`nated as IP-intensive if its IP-count to employment ratio is higher than the average for all indus-
`tries considered, Dividing IP-counts by employment is one approach to adjust for differences in
`industry size, which makes industries more comparable. However, there are other alternatives.
`For instance, IP-counts could be normalizedby capital holdings, research and development ex-
`penditures, value added, or gross output. In addition, other methods are available for differenti-
`ating between IP-intensive and non-IP-intensive industries.la To maintain consistency and allow
`comparisons to the 2012 report, this update follows the methodologies applied previously but
`expands coverage to the 2009-2013 period.'s
`
`Patents
`
`The USPTO grants utility, plant, and design patents that give the grantee the right to exclude
`"others from making, using, offering for sale, or selling the invention throughout the United
`States or importing the invention into the Unites Statesl'r6 Using the U.S. Patent Classification
`(USPC) scheme, patents are classified in over 450 patent "technology classes" that distinguish
`their inventive content.rT rs The USPTO maintains a general concordance between its technology
`classifications and 30 North American Industry Classification (NAICS) codes. The concordance
`enables analysts to associate utility patents with these NAICS coded industries.'e We rely on
`NAICS-based patent counts for 2009 to 2013 to identifr patent-intensive industries.2o This ap-
`proach strictly limits the patent analysis to the manufacturing sector because the concordance
`only associates patents with manufacturing industries. Non-manufacturing industries, such as
`construction, utilities, and information, may rely on utility patents, but these industries are not
`captured by the patent-NAICS concordance. We calculate a measure of industry patent "intensity"
`defined as the ratio of total patents over the five years in a NAICS category to the average payroll
`
`14
`
`l5
`l6
`t7
`
`l8
`
`19
`
`For example, analyzingthe differences by deciles or even evaluating a continuous function are possible alternative
`approaches that may prove informative.
`Detailed description of the methodology is provided in the Appendix.
`3s U.S.C. $ l5a(aXl).
`Utility patents may be classified into more than one technology class but are organized accot'ding to their primary clas-
`sification.
`While it does not affect any of the results in this report, it is worth noting that official use of the USPC was discontin-
`ued in January of 2015. Patents are now classified using the Cooperative Patent Classification (CPC) scheme.
`This concordance was created by the USPTO with financial support from the National Science Foundation. Because no
`similar concordances to NAICS are available for plant or design patents, only utility patents are used in our analysis.
`for rnore infornration on utility patents, For an overview
`See wwrv.uspto.gov/web/offices/aclido/oeipltaflall_tech.htm
`of NAICS, see www.census,gov/eos/www/naics/index.html.
`
`20
`
`See wrvw.uspto.gov/web/offices/aclido/oeipltafldatalmisc/patenting_trends/info_ptrends2008.txt.
`
`ALL 2105
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS V. ALLERGAN
`IPR2016-01127, -01128, -01129, -01130, -01131 & -01132
`
`

`

`lntellectual Property and the U.S. Economy: 2016 Update
`
`8
`
`employment by industry.2r Because employment reflects the overall size of an industry, dividing
`patent counts by employment normalizes patenting activity with respect to industry size.22 This
`approach evens the playing field, so that the most patent-intensive industries are defined not as
`the ones with the most patents, but rather as those with the most patents per worker.
`Nearly all the industries identified as patent-intensive in the 2012 report are also designated as
`such for the2009-2013 period. One industry, resin, synthetic rubber, fibers, and artificial and
`syntheticf.bers andfilaments (NAICS 3252), did not make the cutoffin the current report. In
`addition, some changes occurred in the rank-order of these industries, For example, semiconduc-
`tor and other electronic componenfs (NAICS 3344) was previously designated as the third most
`patent-intensive industry, but dropped to fifth place. However, based on the close similarity in
`the list and rank-order of patent-intensive industries across reports, it appears that patent-inten-
`sity at the industry level is quite persistent over time.23
`
`Trademarks
`A trademark is defined as "a word, phrase, symbol, or design, or a combination thereoi that iden-
`tifies and distinguishes the source of the goods of one party from those of othersl'2a Through ex-
`clusive rights of use, trademarks confer legal protection that enables companies to communicate
`to consumers the quality characteristics of their products and services and recoup investments
`therein.
`
`As in the 2012 report, this study uses three different approaches to identify trademark-intensive
`industries.2s The first approach, as with patents, measures the trademark-intensity of an industry
`based on the ratio of trademark counts to employment and designates those industries with an
`above average ratio as trademark-intensive. Starting with the complete set of trademark regis-
`trations, we matched publicly traded companies by their name to a separate database containing
`information on the firms' primary industry and number of employees. These data allowed us to
`calculate trademark intensity by industry for the matched firms. The second approach uses the
`USPTO's listing of top 50 trademark registering companies (which, unlike the first approach,
`include both private and public companies) from the Performance and Accountability Reports
`for 2009-2013 and identifies industries that appear repeatedly as trademark-intensive. To expand
`coverage for privately-held companies and for smaller and younger firms, the third approach
`draws a random sample of 300 registrations from the 194,326 trademark registrations in 2013 '
`We assign NAICS industry codes to the U.S. registrants in the sample and calculate the industry
`share of total registrations, labeling those with an above average share as trademark-intensive.
`
`2l Using a five-year period (in this case, years 2009-13) instead ofjust one year helps minirnize the chance that anoma-
`lies in any given year will skew our results,
`22 Value added and gross output are two altemative gauges of industry size; however, estimates at the level of detail need-
`ed for this analysis are not available due to data confidentiality limitations.
`23 A detailed discussion of the methodology and a table of results are provided in the Appendix.
`24 U.S. Patent and Trademark Office 2016. We use the term trademark to encompass both trade and service tnarks.
`25 These methodologies are discussed in detail in the Appendix.
`
`ALL 2105
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS V. ALLERGAN
`IPR2016-01127, -01128, -01129, -01130, -01131 & -01132
`
`

`

`lntellectual Property and the

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket