throbber
THE EFFECT OF PRESCRIPTION DRUG
`
`ADVERTISING ON DOCTOR VISITS
`
`TOSHIAKI IIZUKA
`
`Graduate School of International Management
`Aoyama Gakvin University
`Tokyo, Iapan
`toshi.iizuka@gmail.com
`
`GINGER ZHE JIN
`
`Department of Economics
`University of Maryland
`College Park, MD
`jin@econ.umd.edu
`
`The dramatic increase of direct—to—consumer advertising (DTCA) of prescrip-
`tion drugs created intensive debates on its effects on patient and doctor
`behaviors. Combining 1994-2000 DTCA data with the 1995-2000 National
`Ambulatory Medical Care Surveys, we examine the effect of DTCA on doctor
`visits. Consistent with the proponents’ claim, we find that higher DTCA
`expenditures are associated with increased doctor visits, especially after the
`Food and Drug Administration clarified DTCA rules in August 1997. After
`1997, every $28 increase in DTCA leads to one drug visit within 12 months.
`We also find that the market—expanding effect is similar across demographic
`groups.
`
`1.
`
`INTRODUCTION
`
`The year 1997 witnessed an important change in direct-to-consumer
`advertising (DTCA) of prescription drugs. Prior to 1997, any DTCA that
`contained both brand name and medical claims must disclose a ”brief
`
`summary” of drug effectiveness, side effects, and contraindications.
`Consequently, TV advertising was prohibitively expensive, and DTCA
`was largely limited to newspapers and magazines. A small number
`
`We thank the editors, two anonymous referees, Thomas Hubbard, Scott Stern, Timothy
`Hannan, Iudy Hellerstein, Bill Evans, Seth Sanders, Iohn Rust, Robert Maness, and the
`participants at the NBER 2003 I0 meeting for constructive comments and suggestions.
`We also thank Kathryn Aikon for helping us interpret the FDA rules, and Catherine Burt
`for guiding our usage of the NAMCS data. We are Very grateful to TNS Media Intel-
`ligence/ Competitive Media Reporting (CMR) for generously providing the advertising
`data for this study. All errors remain ours.
`
`© 2005 Blackwell Publishing, 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA, and 9600 Garsington Road,
`Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK.
`Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume 14, Number 3, Fall 2005, 701-727
`
`ALL 2068
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS V. ALLERGAN
`IPR2016-01128
`
`1
`
`ALL 2068
`MYLAN PHARMACEUTICALS V. ALLERGAN
`IPR2016-01128
`
`

`

`702
`
`Iournal of Economics <9’ Management Strategy
`
`of the prescription drug ads that aired on TV included only brand
`names without describing their indications. This tradition changed
`drastically after August 1997, when the Food and Drug Administration
`(FDA) clarified that pharmaceutical firms can use DTCA on TV that
`contain both brand name and indications without a ”brief summary.”
`Following the clarification, DTCA expenditures increased from $800
`million in 1996 to $2.5 billion in 2000. As of 2000, DTCA accounted for
`2.5% of the overall mass media ad spending in the United States. The
`top promoted drug—Vioxx—spent $146 million in DTCA, beating Pepsi
`Cola, Budweiser Beer, and most automobile manufacturers (NIHCM,
`2001).
`
`The effects of prescription drug advertising are controversial.
`Proponents argue that DTCA primarily has a market-expanding effect:
`the ads inform consumers of new treatment options and, therefore,
`generate new doctor visits. If true, this could improve patient welfare,
`because many diseases are underdiagnosed. Opponents argue, how-
`ever, that DTCA has a business-stealing effect that misleads patients
`into demanding heavily advertised drugs, leading to inappropriate drug
`use and the unnecessary purchase of expensive drugs. Not surprisingly,
`pharmaceutical firms support the former position, while insurers and
`medical providers generally agree with the latter view.2 Clearly, the heart
`of the debate is the distinction between the market-expanding versus
`business-stealing effects of advertising, a familiar issue in economics
`literature (e.g., Roberts and Samuelson, 1988; Gasmi et al., 1992).
`This paper contributes to the growing literature that investigates
`the effects of DTCA on the demand for prescription drugs.3 We focus our
`analysis on one type of market-expanding effect, namely, the extent to
`which DTCA affects patients’ visits to the doctor. For this study, we use
`nationally representative, patient-level data that cover all classes, which
`allows us to generalize the effect of DTCA beyond specific categories
`studied by previous papers (e.g., Berndt et al., 1995; Calfee et al., 2002;
`Wosinska 2002; Rosenthal et al., 2003).4 In addition, we exploit a rich,
`
`1. DTCA still needs to include a ”major statement” of the most important risks and
`refer consumers to other sources for more comprehensive information.
`2. Both sides of the debates are well documented. See I-Iolmer (1999, 2002) for a
`summary of the proponents’ position, and Hollon (1999) and Wolfe (2002) for a summary
`of the opponents’ position. See, also, the debate on the role of DTCA by several authors
`published in the February 26, 2003, issue of Health Affairs. In response to these debates,
`the FDA held a public hearing in September 2003 to review its policy on DTCA.
`3. In addition to the economics literature we discuss here, a number of surveys have
`been conducted in order to understand consumer and doctor responses to DTCA. For
`example, the FDA conducted surveys on DTCA in 1999 and 2002. Prevention Magazine
`(1998-2000) has also conducted surveys on DTCA annually since 1998. Gonul et al. (2000)
`analyze one of those surveys conducted by Scott-Levin, a pharmaceutical information
`company, and find that consumers and doctors value DTCA differently depending on
`ongoing needs for health care, degree of experience, and exposure to DTCA.
`4. We discuss these papers in more detail in the next section.
`
`2
`
`

`

`Prescription Drug Advertising
`
`703
`
`patient-level dataset and provide new insights into the heterogeneous
`responses to DTCA. The question of whether DTCA has a business-
`stealing effect is addressed in a companion paper (Iizuka and ]in, 2004).
`Combining 1994-2000 monthly DTCA data with the 1995-2000
`National Ambulatory Medical Care Surveys (NAMCS), we estimate
`the effect of DTCA on doctor visits using a nonlinear least-squares
`regression with drug-class-fixed effects and allow DTCA to depreciate
`over time. We find that higher DTCA expenditures are associated with
`increased doctor visits and that this relationship is stronger after the
`1997 clarification. Specifically, after the clarification, every $28 increase in
`monthly DTCA expenditures leads to one patient visit within 12 months,
`and the effect concentrates on the visits that result in prescription drugs.
`In terms of heterogeneous responses to DTCA, we find that the market-
`expanding effect does not vary across demographic groups.
`The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses
`the background and reviews the literature. After a data description
`in Section 3, we set up the empirical model in Section 4 and report
`estimation results in Section 5. Our conclusion is offered in Section 6.
`
`2. BACKGROUND AND RELATED LITERATURE
`
`The large increase of DTCA after the 1997 FDA clarification has created
`a controversy over the effects of DTCA. From a social planner’s per-
`spective, DTCA will improve consumer welfare if its benefits outweigh
`the costs. One benefit that proponents suggest is the market-expanding
`effect of DTCA. For example, DTCA may inform untreated patients of
`existing or new drug treatments and encourage them to seek medical
`help via office visits. This effect could be substantial because a number
`of leading diseases, such as diabetes, high cholesterol, and high blood
`pressure, are underdiagnosed and undertreated (Holmer, 1999). Holmer,
`who represents the pharmaceutical industry, further asserts, ”DTCA
`merely motivates patients to learn more about medical conditions and
`treatment options and to consult their physicians, but once the dialogue
`is started, the physician's role is preeminent” (p. 381).
`On the other hand, most opponents of DTCA worry about the
`business-stealing effects of DTCA. They are concerned that, once un-
`derinformed patients watch DTCA, they may demand inappropriate
`therapies from doctors and increase the cost of treatment. For example,
`Hollon (1999), who provides a doctor's perspective, argues that ”by
`creating consumer demand, [DTCA] undermine the protection that
`is a result of requiring a physician to certify a patient’s need for a
`prescription drug” (p.382). Cohen (1990) also argues that DTCA may
`encourage people to try more expensive drugs though cheaper, but
`equally effective, drugs may be available.
`
`3
`
`

`

`704
`
`Iournal of Economics 8 Management Strategy
`
`This paper contributes to the debate by providing a detailed
`analysis of the market-expanding effects of DTCA in outpatient office
`visits. We not only examine an aggregate market-expanding effect,
`but also examine the distribution of this effect among patient groups.
`Understanding the heterogeneous effects of DTCA is important because
`not all market-expanding effects are welfare improving. For example,
`moral hazard may encourage insured patients who watched DTCA to
`visit doctors ”too often,” because they do not bear all the costs of the
`visit (and the costs of resulting treatment). In such cases, DTCA may
`or may not improve welfare even if DTCA has a market-expanding
`effect.
`
`Our paper complements the few academic studies on DTCA. On
`the demand side, the earliest paper examining the effect of DTCA
`on prescription drugs is Berndt et al. (1995). They used the data for
`antiulcer drugs for 1977-1994, which precedes the surge of DTCA in
`the late 1990s.5 Calfee et al. (2002) estimated a monthly time-series
`regression of total statin drug prescriptions on advertising expenditures
`during 1995 and 2000. They found that advertising had no statistically
`significant effect on new statin prescriptions or renewals, but television
`advertising increased the proportion of cholesterol patients who had
`been successfully treated. Rosenthal et al. (2003) investigated the effects
`of DTCA and detailing on the aggregate sales of prescription drugs,
`using monthly data for five therapeutic classes between August 1996
`and December 1999. They found that DTCA has a significant effect on
`total class sales, but does not have any significant impact on market
`shares within each class. Our study builds upon these studies by using
`nationally representative, patient—level data that cover substantially
`larger number of therapeutic classes. Because of the advantage of the
`data, the conclusion of our paper is more applicable to a broader class
`of prescription drugs.
`Wosinska (2002) also examined the effect of DTCA on the demand
`
`for cholesterol-reducing drugs, using individual prescription claim data
`between 1996 and 1999. She finds that DTCA may affect the demand for
`an individual brand positively, but only if that brand is on the third-party
`payer's formulary. Similarly, using the NAMCS data as in the current
`paper, Iizuka and ]in (2004) examined the business-stealing effect of
`DTCA in nonsedating antihistamines. This paper is different from those
`papers because, while the above references are concerned about the
`
`5. In related research, Ling et al. (2002) examined the spillover of DTCA between
`prescription and over—the-counter (OTC) segments. Using data for antiulcer drugs, many
`of which switched from prescription to the OTC market in the late 1990s, they found small
`but significant spillovers from prescription to the OTC market for some brands, but not
`vice versa.
`
`4
`
`

`

`Prescription Drug Advertising
`
`705
`
`effect of advertising once patients arrived at doctor offices, that is, the
`business-stealing effect of DTCA, this paper examines whether DTCA
`brings potential patients to doctor offices, that is, the market-expanding
`effect of DTCA.
`
`On the supply side, Rosenthal et al. (2002) analyzed the industry-
`wide trends for DTCA and found that DTCA is highly concentrated on
`a subgroup of products and the spending fluctuates over time. Iizuka
`(2004) examined the determinants of DTCA and found that DTCA tends
`
`to concentrate in classes that involve fewer competitors. He also found
`that drugs that are new, of high quality, and for undertreated diseases
`are more frequently advertised. Our finding that DTCA of prescription
`drugs has a market-expanding effect on the demand side complements
`their findings.
`This paper also contributes to the body of literature that em-
`pirically distinguishes the market-expanding effect from the business-
`stealing effect of advertising [see Bagwell (2001) for a broad overview
`of classic papers on the economics of advertising, and King (2003) for
`a study on the disagglomeration and growth of the US advertising-
`agency industry]. An ad is viewed as market expanding when it purely
`increases total market size and business-stealing when it solely shifts
`market share among brands. Roberts and Samuelson (1988), for exam-
`ple, found that cigarette advertising has a significant market-expanding
`effect, but not a business-stealing effect. In contrast, Gasmi et al. (1992)
`found that advertising in the carbonated soft-drink industry is primarily
`characterized as business stealing.
`Finally, we recognize that the demand effect of direct-to-doctor
`advertising (i.e., detailing promotion) has been examined in earlier
`literature. Hurwitz and Caves (1988) looked at a cross-section of 56
`
`off-patent drugs and found that detailing promotion has a positive
`effect on the market shares between branded and generic drugs. Rizzo
`(1999) looked at the demand for antihypertension drugs for 1988-1993
`and found that detailing promotion lowers price sensitivity. Gonul
`et al. (2001) showed that detailing and free samples affect physician
`prescription behavior for an undisclosed therapeutic class. Azoulay
`(2002) found that, in addition to detailing promotion, scientific evidence
`from medical literature affected the diffusion pattern of antiulcer drugs.
`However, none of these papers looked at the effect of advertising
`directed to consumers. To be sure, this is mainly because DTCA in-
`creased its significance only recently, after the FDA clarification in
`1997. Moreover, because we are interested in the patient’s decision
`to visit a doctor rather than the doctor's decision to choose a specific
`drug, it is natural to focus on drug advertising that is oriented toward
`consumers.
`
`5
`
`

`

`706
`
`Iournal of Economics <9’ Management Strategy
`
`3 . DATA
`
`We combine individual-level data from the 1995-2000 NAMCS with
`
`the 1994-2000 monthly DTCA data from the TNS Media Intelli-
`gence/ Competitive Media Reporting (CMR). Each year since 1993,
`NAMCS has collected a national representative sample of individual
`visits to office-based physicians. For each office visit, NAMCS provides
`patient demographics, insurance status, physician specialty, time spent
`with the patient, diagnoses, dispositions, and prescription choices, if
`any.6 Although NAMCS has been constructed by stratified sampling
`each year, the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention only provide
`detailed sampling information for 1995 and beyond. To make sure the
`aggregate counts of office visits are nationally representative, we focus
`on 1995-2000.
`
`In comparison, the DTCA data provides the total DTCA expen-
`ditures for every prescription drug advertised via direct-to-consumer
`channels. Specifically, CMR monitors advertising outlays in units and
`dollars for several different media, including network TV, cable TV,
`newspapers, and magazines. The DTCA dollars reflect the typical costs
`of buying such elements as television time and print space.7 Our DTCA
`data covers 1 year longer than the period covered by the NAMCS data,
`so we can estimate the long-lasting effect of DTCA on patient visits.
`The DTCA and NAMCS data are matched by drug names and the
`month during which the advertising and physician office visits took
`place.8
`Our unbalanced panel data contain a total of 7,824 observations
`covering 151 drug classes over 72 months. Defining class-month as
`the unit of observation, we include a class-month in the sample if at
`least one visit (either drug or nondrug) occurred in that class and that
`month. To keep the sample stable, this sample construction applies to
`all regressions.9 A drug class is defined by the four-digit National Drug
`Code (NDC).1° Some classes do not appear in all months because some
`diseases are seasonal, and the NDC has added or deleted a few four-digit
`class codes between 1995 and 2000.
`
`6. See Cherry et al. (2001) and Burt (2002) for more detailed description of NAMCS.
`7. However, they may not reflect the discounts typically given to large buyers who
`bundle various products’ ads with one advertising agency.
`8. In rare cases where NAMCS assigns different drug class codes to the same drug
`across years, we use the 2000 NDC definition.
`9. As a result, some class-months may have zero drug visits in our sample, because
`we only observe nondrug visits in that class-month and vice versa.
`10. For example, hyperlipidemia (which includes cholesterol reducing drugs), ace
`inhibitors, and calcium channel blockers belong to separate four-digit NDC categories.
`
`6
`
`

`

`Prescription Drug Advertising
`
`707
`
`4. EMPIRICAL MODEL
`
`4.1
`
`SPECIFICATION
`
`Suppose all drugs in therapeutic class k treat disease k. If DTCA has
`raised consumer awareness of treatment options, greater exposure to
`DTCA in class k should encourage more consumers at the risk of disease
`k to visit doctors. However, it is quite possible that a DTCA of a specific
`drug motivates an individual to visit the doctor, but he or she ends up
`getting a different drug within the same therapeutic class. Therefore, we
`look at the effects of DTCA at the class level rather than at the individual
`
`drug level. We use therapeutic class and drug class interchangeably.
`Following this logic, the ideal model will link an individual’s
`exposure to DTCA in drug class k with his or her decision to visit
`the doctor's office for disease k. Unfortunately, the DTCA data are not
`individual specific, and the NAMCS data only record those patients who
`choose to visit doctors. To overcome these difficulties, we use NAMCS’
`sampling weights to calculate the total number of patient visits by class
`and time. Specifically, we estimate the following model:
`
`VISITk[ = (Xk + [313 + QKT + }\.1(’q[r
`
`+ ybSUMDTCAkt(1 — A1-"TER;)
`
`+ y,, SUMDTC/lkt X AFTER;
`
`+ ektl
`
`where VISIT,“ stands for the number of outpatient office visits related
`to drug class k at month t, and SLIMDTCAM stands for the discounted
`sum of DTCA of class k up to month t. AFTER, is a dummy equal to
`1 if month t is after the FDA clarification (August, 1997), 0 otherwise.
`The key coefficients, )4, and ya, denote the marginal effect of S LIMDTCA
`on VISIT before and after the clarification. ark and fit are drug-class and
`time-fixed effects, respectively. The other terms, OKT and A.K,qfr, further
`control time trends and are discussed in Section 4.2. 6k, is the error term.
`The definition of S LIMDTCA and VISIT requires more discussion.
`First, it may be reasonable to expect that the effect of DTCA would last
`for more than 1 month but depreciate over time. To capture the long-
`lasting effect of advertising, we define SUMDTCA in the following way:
`t
`
`SUMDTC/lk, = Z 8“iDTCAkt,
`'=0
`
`where 6 denotes the monthly depreciation rate to be estimated in the
`empirical analysis, and DTCA“ is the total DTCA expenditures reported
`for class k in month t. Because our DTCA data starts in January 1994,
`
`7
`
`

`

`708
`
`Iournal of Economics 8 Management Strategy
`
`we treat all the DTCA before January 1994 as zero. Although this
`treatment is motivated by our limited data, given the small amount
`of DTCA before 1994, the omission of the data prior to 1994 is unlikely
`to affect estimation results. In fact, results do not change if we impute the
`before-1994 DTCA from the aggregate DTCA amount reported by
`CMR.“ The discount factor 8 enters the model nonlinearly, so we
`estimate the whole model by nonlinear least squares.
`Second, we define our dependent variable, VISIT, in five different
`ways: drug visits, RX visits, OTC Visits, nondrug visits, and all visits. A
`Visit is counted as an RX visit of class k if it results in any prescription in
`class k. If a visit results in no prescription drug but at least one over-the-
`counter drug in class k, it is referred to as an OTC visit. Drug Visits are
`the sum of RX and OTC visits. If a Visit leads to no treatment or nondrug
`treatment, it is categorized as a nondrug visit. All visits are the sum of
`drug visits and nondrug visits. If a visit involves more than one class,
`we count it as one visit for each relevant class.
`
`Drug visits, RX visits, and OTC visits are well defined as NAMCS
`provides a drug class code for each drug that was prescribed or men-
`tioned by a doctor during each visit. In contrast, the definition of non-
`drug visits (and all visits, accordingly) involves a technical challenge:
`no therapeutic class code exists for nondrug visits. To address this issue,
`using drug visits observations, we create a mapping between a diagnosis
`and the most common drug class associated with the diagnosis. Specif-
`ically, we construct the mapping in the following way. First, we create a
`subsample of NAMCS visits that have a single diagnosis and at least one
`prescription or OTC drug. We focus on single-diagnosis visits to ensure
`that we can establish the link from a specific diagnosis to drug classes.
`Then, using the subsample, we identify the most common drug class
`for each diagnosis. This is done for each year separately, allowing drug
`treatment of specific disease to change over time. After this procedure,
`we are able to associate each diagnosis with a specific drug class and
`count the number of nondrug visits by drug class.”
`Because the purpose of this paper is to examine the effect of DTCA
`on physician office visits, it is theoretically correct to use all visits (i.e.,
`drug visits + nondrug Visits) as the dependent Variable. However, the
`nondrug visit definition as described above generates a fair amount of
`
`11. The imputation is implemented in the following way: if drug class k advertised at
`dollars in a specific month of 1994, we define the DTCAk in the corresponding month
`of 1993 as x - TOTALDTC93 /TOTALDTC94. The same imputation applies to any year
`between 1989 and 1993. The aggregate DTCA numbers are taken from "Prescription Drug
`Advertising Soars through Third Quarter; Expected to Top $1 Billion in 1998,” PR Newswire,
`December 30, 1998.
`12. NAMCS provides up to three diagnosis codes for each visit, so a nondrug visit
`may be linked to, at most, three drug classes.
`
`8
`
`

`

`Prescription Drug Advertising
`
`709
`
`noise and, therefore, results for nondrug visits are merely suggestive.”
`For this reason, we report the results of drug Visits as our main results.
`Nonetheless, main results stay the same even when all visits are used
`as the dependent variable. We show these results in Section 5.4.
`Finally, note that both VISIT and S LIMDTCA enter the specification
`linearly. We choose the linear—linear specification over alternatives due
`to the following reasons. First, as we show in Section 5.4, the linear-
`linear specification dominates the linear—log specification. Similarly, the
`log—linear specification dominates the log—log specification (by a small
`margin). Second, we prefer linear—linear over log—linear because log-
`linear forces us to drop or artificially modify Visit counts when these
`numbers are zero. This happens frequently when we break down the
`Visits by nondrug, RX, and OTC, or by patient groups. To avoid the
`sample selection problem, we use the linear—linear specification as our
`primary specification. To further address the concern of zero advertising,
`we rerun the linear—linear regression on advertising classes only. As a
`robustness check for the nonlinear estimate of depreciation, we also
`rerun the linear—linear regression using the depreciation rate estimated
`in Berndt et al. (1995). As showed in Section 5.4, basic results are robust
`regardless of specification.
`
`4.2 IDENTIFICATION
`
`Aggregate VISITH and SLIMDTCAM raise several econometric concerns.
`For example, a class with a large number of potential patients naturally
`has more patient visits. In the meantime, drug companies may also
`allocate large advertising budgets to large drug classes. Therefore, a
`high correlation between DTCA and patient Visits would not necessarily
`imply a causal effect. Moreover, as manifested by the concentration of
`DTCA in a small number of drug classes, drug companies may intention-
`ally select which classes to advertise. To address these concerns, we use
`class-fixed effect oak to control for time-invariant cross-class differences,
`a full set of month dummies fit to account for over-time fluctuation
`common for all drug classes, HKT for class-specific time trends, Where
`T denotes the number of months between the visit month and January
`1994, and A4K’qfr for class-specific seasonality. 6 and A are specific to an
`aggregated drug class K, defined by two-digit NDC classes.”
`
`13. NAMCS data not only record drug mentions that are directly related to diagnosis,
`but also include drug refills that may be irrelevant to the current diagnosis. To minimize
`the noise, we restrict the reference group to patients with a single diagnosis in the same
`calendar year.
`14. There are 21 two-digit NDC classes, such as ”cardiovascular-renal drugs” and
`"gastrointestinal agents.” In theory, the model is still implementable if we define 9 and A
`by four-digit NDC class. In reality, the model with four-digit trends yields qualitatively
`similar results in the coefficients of SLIMDTCA, but the depreciation rate 6 becomes
`
`9
`
`

`

`710
`
`Iournal of Economics 8 Management Strategy
`
`After all these controls, the effect of DTCA is mainly identified
`from over-time variations within each drug class. Still two reasons to
`suspect endogenous SLIMDTCAM exist. First, if the advertising budget
`is proportional to sales revenue and somehow patient visits correlate
`with sales revenue, reverse causality will reinforce a positive correlation
`between VISIT and S LIMDTCA and, therefore, overestimate y. Second,
`as the Pharmaceutical Manufacturing and Research Association claimed
`(Holmer, 1999, 2002), drug companies may devote much DTCA to
`underdiagnosed classes. Although class-fixed effects partially control
`for such selection bias, it is still possible that, for a specific drug class
`over time, drug companies commit to high DTCA expenditures when
`the actual number of visits is relatively low. This negative correlation
`will imply a downward bias in y.
`To address the endogeneity problem, we use the same drug com-
`panies’ DTCA expenditures in other ”unrelated” drug classes DTCA_kt
`as an instrument for DTCA“. We define class —k ”unrelated” to class k
`if (1) k and —k do not belong to the same two-digit NDC class and (2)
`the correlation of patients getting any drug (including over the counter)
`in the two-digit NDC classes K and —K at the same time is smal1.15 The
`latter ensures that we do not include the DTCA of complementary drugs
`in the instrument.
`
`For example, cholesterol-reducing drugs involve four major drug
`companies—Bristol-Myers Squibb (for Pravachol), Merck (for Zocor),
`Pfizer (for Lipitor), and Novartis AG (for Lescol). These four companies
`also produce and advertise prescription drugs in other classes; for in-
`stance, Novartis’s Habitrol targets smoking, Bristol-Myer’s Zerit targets
`HIV, Merck's Fosamax targets Osteoporosis, and Pfizer's Viagra targets
`erectile dysfunction. If class k refers to cholesterol reducing, DTCA_kt
`is defined as the sum of DTCA that these four drug companies spent
`on all the other classes excluding those under the same two-digit NDC
`class (metabolic/ nutrients) or under related two-digit NDC classes (e.g.,
`cardiovascular—renal drugs).
`We argue that DTCA across classes is correlated within the same
`company, either because the company pursues a particular marketing
`strategy for all products or because different drugs are subject to a
`common constraint in the advertising budget. After controlling for drug-
`class-fixed effects and time trends, we assume unobserved factors that
`drive changes in patient visits are uncorrelated across two classes, unless
`both belong to the same two-digit NDC class or they are under different
`two-digit NDC classes but often used on the same patients. By this
`
`unstable, often reaching the boundary of 1 or 0. We suspect this is because the four-digit
`trends absorb too many variations.
`15. After examining the distribution of correlation across two-digit classes, we use
`correlation = 0.1 as the cut-off point.
`
`10
`
`10
`
`

`

`Prescription Drug Advertising
`
`711
`
`assumption, the only way for DTCA_kt to influence VISIT“ is through
`DTCA”. Berndt et al. (1995) pursued a similar identification strategy.
`To further justify the validity of the instrument, we note that 90%
`of all the classes with positive DTCA“ also have positive DTCA_k¢.
`Moreover, the correlation of DTC/lkt and DTCA_kt are significant and
`positive in all years. If we regress DTCA,‘; on class-fixed effects and
`time trend (i.e., all exogenous variables), including DTCA-” on the
`right-hand side would improve the within-class R2 from 11% to 14%.
`The coefficient of DTCA_kt is also positive and highly significant in the
`first stage regression.” These statistics suggest that DTCA-,“ is a valid
`instrument for DTCA“. Because SLIMDTCA is defined as a discounted
`sum of current and past DTCA, we use DTCA_kt as instrument for
`DTCA“, DTCA_k(,_1) as instrument for DTCAk(t_1), and so on.
`The extent to which our instrument solves the endogeneity prob-
`lem depends on the validity of assumptions. Should one of the assump-
`tions fail, our results are better interpreted as a statistical association
`rather than a causal relationship between doctor visits and DTCA.
`Bearing this in mind, we proceed to the next section, which reports
`our results.
`
`5. RESULTS
`
`We start this section by describing the data and showing the results for
`drug visits. Then, we report the effect of DTCA on drug visits by patient
`groups. The final subsection conducts robustness checks and provides
`additional estimation results.
`
`5.1 DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS
`
`Table I summarizes the dataset. As noted before, we have an unbal-
`
`anced panel dataset with 7,824 observations covering 151 classes over
`72 months between 1995 and 2000. A unit of observation is drug class-
`month. The first block of Table I summarizes DTCA data. As Rosenthal
`
`et al. (2003) and Iizuka (2004) showed, DTCA often concentrates in a few
`drug classes. In our data, on average, only 20.8% of classes advertise in a
`typical month." Conditional on positive advertising, the average DTCA
`expenditures are $3.84 million per class per month.
`The second block of Table I shows the number of visits by different
`visit definitions. By far the majority of NAMCS visits are drug visits,
`especially RX visits. Nondrug visits and OTC visits account for smaller
`
`16. P-statistics is 236.00, with p-Value equal to 0.
`17. This number has increased over time. In 1995, only 10 classes advertised via DTC
`channels. This number increased to 30-35 in 2000. During the 6 years from 1995 to 2000,
`67 classes have ever advertised through DTC channel(s).
`
`11
`
`11
`
`

`

`712
`
`Ioarnal of Economics 8 Management Strategy
`
`TABLE I.
`
`SUM MARY STATISTICS
`
`DTCA data
`
`Dummy =1 if DTCA>0
`DTCA ($ million)
`DTCA ($ million) conditional on DTCA>0
`Visit data
`
`Drug visits (million)—visits that lead to any drug mention(s)
`RX visits (million)—visits that lead to any prescription drug
`(RX) mention(s)
`
`OTC visits (million)—visits that lead to any otc drug
`mention(s) and no RX
`
`Nondrug visits (million)—visits that lead to no drug mention
`All visits (million) ( = drug visits + nondrug visits)
`Drug visits by demographics and doctor types
`Drug visits (million)—belongs to an HMO?
`Drug visits (million)—patient age265?
`Drug visits (million)—who pays for the visit?
`Self
`
`Govemment-sponsored program
`Private insurer
`
`Total OBS
`Total number of classes
`
`Mean
`
`Std. Dev.
`
`0.208
`0.799
`3.836
`
`0.778
`0.641
`
`0.406
`2.960
`5.516
`
`0.984
`0.875
`
`0.137
`
`0.406
`
`0.417
`1.275
`
`0.296
`0.390
`
`0.104
`
`0.413
`0.593
`
`0.226
`1.004
`
`0.202
`0.258
`
`0.051
`
`0.293
`0.433
`
`7,824
`151
`
`Note: A unit of observation is four—digit NDC class—month. For each observation, the count of visits takes into account
`the NAMCS sampling weights. The data in an unbalanced panel show some classes do not exist in all years due to
`seasonality or definition changes in the NDC.
`
`percentages of NAMCS visits. In the third block of the table, we provide
`a breakdown of drug visits by patient demographics. This shows that
`the majority of patients are non-HMO members, younger than 65 years
`old, and i

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket