throbber
Market value and patent citations
`
`Bronwyn H. Hall*
`
`Adam Jaffe**
`
`Manuel Trajtenberg***
`
`
`
`Abstract
`
`This paper explores the usefulness of patent citations as a measure of the “importance” of a firm’s
`
`patents, as indicated by the stock market valuation of the firm’s intangible stock of knowledge. Using
`
`patents and citations for 1963-1999, we estimate Tobin’s q equations on the ratios of R&D to assets
`
`stocks, patents to R&D, and citations to patents. We find that each ratio significantly impacts market
`
`value, with an extra citation per patent boosting market value by 3%. Further findings indicate that
`
`“unpredictable” citations have a stronger effect than the predictable portion, and that self-citations are
`
`more valuable than external citations.
`
`
`
`JEL Classification: O31, O38
`
`UC Berkeley, NBER, and IFS UC Berkeley, NBER, and IFS; Department of Economics 549
`
`Evans Hall, UC Berkeley, Berkeley, CA 9472—3880, USA; Tel. 1 510 642 3878;
`
`bhhall@econ.berkeley.edu
`
` *
`
`
`
`1
`
`PMC Exhibit 2022
`Apple v. PMC
`IPR2016-00754
`Page 1
`
`

`
`**
`
`Brandeis University and NBER; Brandeis University, Waltham MA 02554-9110, USA: 781-736-
`
`3451; ajaffe@brandeis.edu
`
`***
`
`Tel Aviv University, NBER, and CEPR; Eitan Berglas School of Economics, Tel
`
`Aviv University, Tel Aviv 69978, Israel; Tel. 972-3-640-9911; manuel@post.tau.ac.il
`
`
`
`This paper follows closely in the steps of the late Zvi Griliches and owes to him the underlying vision,
`
`method, and pursuit of data. The data construction was partially supported by the National Science
`
`Foundation, via grants SBR-9413099 and SBR-9320973. We are extremely grateful to Meg Fernando of
`
`REI, Case Western Reserve University, for excellent assistance in matching the patent data to Compustat.
`
`We also acknowledge with gratitude the comments received at numerous seminars, and from two
`
`referees.
`
`
`
`2
`
`PMC Exhibit 2022
`Apple v. PMC
`IPR2016-00754
`Page 2
`
`

`
`1. Introduction
`
`
`
`It is widely understood that the R&D conducted by private firms is an investment activity, the output of
`
`which is an intangible asset that can be labeled as the firm’s “knowledge stock.” If this asset is known to
`
`contribute positively to the firm’s future net cash flows, then the size of a firm’s knowledge stock should
`
`be reflected in the observed market value of the firm. This implies that a firm’s R&D investments should
`
`be capitalized in the firm’s market value. Further, since the output of the R&D investment process is
`
`stochastic, some of the R&D will result in the creation of more valuable knowledge capital; if this success
`
`is observable, then it should be reflected in greater market value bang for the R&D buck.
`
`
`
`Empirical testing of this formulation requires an observable proxy for R&D “success.” There is a
`
`considerable literature using counts of firms’ successful patent applications for this purpose. But the value
`
`of patent counts as a proxy for R&D success is severely limited by the very large variance in the
`
`significance or value of individual patents, rendering patent counts an extremely noisy indicator of R&D
`
`success. In this paper we utilize information on the number of subsequent citations received by a firm’s
`
`patents to get a better measure of R&D success. Further, because citations arrive over time, and can be
`
`distinguished by the identity of the citing organization, we can distinguish the impact of a firm’s patents
`
`on its market value according to the time path and source of subsequent citations.
`
`
`
`This project was made possible by the recently completed creation of a comprehensive data file on patents
`
`and citations, comprising all US patents granted during the period 1963-1999 (three million patents), and
`
`all patent citations made during 1975-1999 (about 16 million citations), as described in Hall, Jaffe, and
`
`Trajtenberg (2001).1 We construct on the basis of these data three measures of “knowledge stocks”: the
`
`
`1 The complete data are available in the NBER site at http://www.nber.org/patents/, and also in a CD
`included with Jaffe and Trajtenberg (2002). For purposes of this paper, we actually used a previous
`version of the data that extends only until 1996.
`
`3
`
`PMC Exhibit 2022
`Apple v. PMC
`IPR2016-00754
`Page 3
`
`

`
`traditional R&D and patent count stocks, and a citations stock. The last poses serious truncation problems,
`
`since citations to a given patent typically keep coming over long periods of time, but we only observe
`
`them until the last date of the available data; we apply correction methods developed elsewhere to deal
`
`with this and related problems. It is important to note that in this paper we look only at a simple
`
`“hedonic” (and hence snapshot-like) market value equation, and do not address the deeper dynamic forces
`
`at work, as discussed by Pakes (1985) – these will have to wait for future research.
`
`
`
`We estimate Tobin’s q “hedonic” equations on three complementary aspects of knowledge stocks: R&D
`
`“intensity” (the ratio of R&D stocks to the book value of assets), the patent yield of R&D (i.e., the ratio of
`
`patent count stocks to R&D stocks), and the average citations received by these patents (i.e., the ratio of
`
`citations to patent stocks). We find that each of these ratios has a statistically and economically significant
`
`impact on Tobin’s q. This confirms that the market values R&D inputs, values R&D output as measured
`
`by patents, and further values “high-quality” R&D output as measured by citation intensity.
`
`
`
`When we look in more detail at the aspects of citation patterns that are associated with higher market
`
`value, we find: (i) The value of high citation intensity is disproportionately concentrated in highly cited
`
`patents: firms having two to three times the median number of citations per patent display a 35% value
`
`premium, and those with 20 citations and more command a staggering 54% market value premium. (ii)
`
`There are wide differences across sectors in the impact of each knowledge stock ratio on market value.
`
`(iii) Market value premia associated with patent citations confirm the forward-looking nature of equity
`
`markets: at a given point in time, market value premia are associated with future citations rather than
`
`those that have been received in the past, and the portion of total lifetime citations that is unpredictable
`
`based on the citation history at a given moment has the largest impact. (iv) Self-citations (i.e., those
`
`coming from down-the-line patents owned by the same firm) are more valuable than citations coming
`
`from external patents, but this effect decreases with the size of patent portfolio held by the firm, as might
`
`be expected.
`
`4
`
`PMC Exhibit 2022
`Apple v. PMC
`IPR2016-00754
`Page 4
`
`

`
`
`
`The paper is organized as follows: section 2 discusses the rationale for the use of patent and citations data
`
`in this sort of research, and reviews previous literature. The data are described in section 3, along with a
`
`discussion of truncation and its remedies. Section 4 deals with the specification of the market value
`
`equation, and the construction of citation stocks, including the partition into past-future and predictable-
`
`residual citation stocks. The empirical findings are presented in section 5: starting with a “horse race”
`
`between R&D, patents, and citations, we proceed to estimate the preferred specification that includes the
`
`three ratios, add industry effects, experiment with the various partitions of the citations stock, and finally
`look at the differential impact of self-citations. Section 6 concludes with ideas for further research.
`
`
`
`2. Patents, citations, and market value: where do we stand?
`
`
`
`Patents have long been recognized as a very rich data source for the study of innovation and technical
`
`change. Indeed, there are numerous advantages to the use of patent data: each patent contains highly
`
`detailed information on the innovation; patents display extremely wide coverage in terms of technologies,
`
`assignees, and geography; there are already millions of them (the flow being of over 150,000 US Patent
`
`and Trademark Office [USPTO] patent grants per year); the data contained in patents are supplied entirely
`
`on a voluntarily basis, etc. There are serious limitations as well, the most glaring being that not all
`
`innovations are patented, simply because not all inventions meet the patentability criteria, and because the
`
`inventor has to make a strategic decision to patent, as opposed to relying on secrecy or other means of
`
`appropriability.2
`
`
`
`
`2 Unfortunately, we have very little idea of the extent to which patents are representative of the wider
`universe of inventions, since there is no systematic data about inventions that are not patented (see,
`however, Crepon, Duguet, and Mairesse, 1998). This is an important, wide-open area for future research.
`
`5
`
`PMC Exhibit 2022
`Apple v. PMC
`IPR2016-00754
`Page 5
`
`

`
`The large-scale use of patent data in economic research goes back to Scherer (1965), Schmookler (1966),
`
`and Griliches (1984).3 One of the major limitations of these research programs, extremely valuable as
`
`they had been, was that they relied exclusively on patent counts as indicators of innovative output.4
`
`However, it has long been recognized that innovations vary enormously in their technological and
`
`economic “importance” or “value,” and that the distribution of such “values” is extremely skewed. Thus
`
`simple patent counts are inherently limited in the extent to which they can capture such heterogeneity (see
`
`Griliches, Pakes, and Hall, 1987). The line of research initiated by Pakes and Schankerman (1984) using
`
`patent renewal data clearly revealed these features of the patent data. Patent citations suggested
`
`themselves as a means to tackle such heterogeneity (Trajtenberg, 1990; Albert et al., 1991), as well as a
`
`way to trace spillovers (Jaffe, Trajtenberg, and Henderson, 1993). In order to understand the role that
`
`patent citations have come to play in this context, we have to look more in detail into the patent document
`
`as a legal entity and as an information source.
`
` A
`
` patent awards to inventors the right to exclude others from the unauthorized use of the disclosed
`
`invention, for a predetermined period of time.5 For a patent to be granted, the innovation must fulfill the
`
`following criteria: (i) it has to be novel in a legally defined sense6; (ii) it has to be non-obvious, in that a
`
`skilled practitioner of the technology would not have known how to do it; and (iii) it must be useful,
`
`meaning that it has potential commercial value. If a patent is granted, an extensive public document is
`
`created. The front page of a patent contains detailed information about the invention, the inventor, the
`
`
`3 The work of Schmookler involved assigning patent counts to industries, whereas Griliches’ project
`entailed matching patents to a sample of Compustat firms. In both cases the resulting data used were
`yearly patent counts by industries or firms. Scherer’s project involved the creation of a “technology flow
`matrix” by industry of origin and industries of use.
`
`4 Of course, that is the best they could do at the time, given computer and data resources available.
`
`5 Whether or not this right translates into market power depends upon a host of other factors, including
`the legal strength of these rights, the speed of technical advance, the ease of imitation, etc.
`
`6 In the US that means “first to invent,” whereas in Europe and Japan it means “first to file.”
`
`6
`
`PMC Exhibit 2022
`Apple v. PMC
`IPR2016-00754
`Page 6
`
`

`
`assignee, and the technological antecedents of the invention, including citations to previous patents. These
`
`citations serve an important legal function, since they delimit the scope of the property rights awarded by
`
`the patent. Thus, if patent B cites patent A, it implies that patent A represents a piece of previously
`
`existing knowledge upon which patent B builds, and over which B cannot have a claim. The applicant has
`
`a legal duty to disclose any knowledge of the prior art (and thus the inventor’s attorney typically plays an
`
`important role in deciding which patents to cite), but the decision regarding which citations to include
`
`ultimately rests with the patent examiner, who is supposed to be an expert in the area and hence able to
`
`identify relevant prior art that the applicant misses or conceals.7
`
`
`
`Thus, patent citations presumably convey information on two major aspects of innovations.8 The first is
`
`linkages between inventions, inventors, and assignees along time and space. In particular, patent citations
`
`enable the quantitative, detailed study of spillovers, along geographical, institutional, and related
`
`dimensions. The second is that citations may be used as indicators of the “importance” of individual
`
`patents, thus introducing a way of gauging the enormous heterogeneity in the “value” of patents.9 In this
`
`paper we concentrate on the latter aspect, with only a passing reference to citations as indicators of
`
`spillovers when dealing with self-citations.
`
`
`
`
`7 “During the examination process, the examiner searches the pertinent portion of the ‘classified’ patent
`file. His purpose is to identify any prior disclosures of technology…which anticipate the claimed
`invention and preclude the issuance of a patent; which might be similar to the claimed invention and limit
`the scope of patent protection…; or which, generally, reveal the state of the technology to which the
`invention is directed….If such documents are found they are made known to the inventor, and are ‘cited’
`in any patent which matures from the application…Thus, the number of times a patent document is cited
`may be a measure of its technological significance.” (Office of Technology Assessment and Forecast,
`1976, p. 167).
`
`8 Citations allow one also to probe into other aspects of innovations, such as their “originality,”
`“generality,” links to science, etc. – see Trajtenberg, Henderson, and Jaffe (1997).
`
`9 The two are of course related: one may deem more “important” those patents that generate more
`spillovers, and vice versa. Most research so far has treated these two aspects separately, but clearly there
`is room to aim for an integrative approach.
`
`7
`
`PMC Exhibit 2022
`Apple v. PMC
`IPR2016-00754
`Page 7
`
`

`
`There are reasons to believe that citations convey not just technological but also economically significant
`
`information: Patented innovations are for the most part the result of costly R&D conducted by profit-
`
`seeking organizations; if firms invest in further developing an innovation disclosed in a previous patent,
`
`then the resulting (citing) patents presumably signify that the cited innovation is economically valuable.
`
`Moreover, citations typically keep coming over the long run,10 giving plenty of time to dissipate the
`
`original uncertainty regarding both the technological viability and the commercial worth of the cited
`
`innovation. Thus, if we still observe citations years after the grant of the cited patent, it must be that the
`
`latter had indeed proven to be valuable.
`
` detailed survey of inventors provides some direct evidence on citations as indicative of the presumed
`
` A
`
`links across innovations (Jaffe, Trajtenberg, and Fogarty, 2000). A set of “citing inventors” answered
`
`questions about their patented inventions, about the relationship of these to previous patents cited in theirs
`
`as well as to technologically similar “placebo” patents that were not actually cited. A second set of
`
`(matched) “cited inventors” answered similar questions regarding the citing patents. The results confirm
`
`that citations do contain significant information on knowledge flows, but with a substantial amount of
`
`noise. The answers revealed significant differences between the cited patents and the placebos as to
`
`whether the citing inventor had learned anything from the cited patent, and precisely how and what she
`
`learned from it. However, as many as half of all citations did not seem to correspond to any kind of
`
`knowledge flow, whereas one-quarter of them indicate a strong connection between citing and cited
`
`patents.
`
`
`
`
`10 The mean backward citation lag hovers around 15 years (depending on the cohort), the median at about
`10, and 5% of citations go back 50 years and more. The forward lag is more difficult to characterize
`because of the inherent truncation, but looking at citations to the oldest cohort in the data, that of 1975,
`we see that even after 25 years citations keep coming at a non-declining rate (see Jaffe and Trajtenberg,
`2002, Ch. 13).
`
`8
`
`PMC Exhibit 2022
`Apple v. PMC
`IPR2016-00754
`Page 8
`
`

`
`There have been a small number of studies that attempted to validate the use of patent citations as
`
`indicators of economic impact or value. Trajtenberg (1990) related the flow of patents in computed
`
`tomography (CT) scanners, a major innovation in medical technology, to the estimated social surplus due
`
`to improvements in this technology.11 Whereas simple patent counts showed no correlation with the
`
`estimated surplus, citation-weighted patent counts turned out to be highly correlated with it, thus
`
`providing first-time evidence to the effect that citations carry information on the value of patented
`
`innovations. Recent work by Lanjouw and Schankerman (2003) also uses citations, along with other
`
`measures such as number of claims and number of countries in which an invention is patented, as a proxy
`
`for patent “quality.” They find that a composite measure has significant power in predicting which patents
`
`will be renewed and which will be litigated, thus inferring that that these indicators are indeed associated
`
`with the private value of patents. Harhoff et al. (1999) survey German patent holders of US patents that
`
`were also filed in Germany, asking them to estimate the price at which they would have been willing to
`
`sell the patent right three years after filing. They find that the estimated value is correlated with
`
`subsequent citations, and that the most highly cited patents are very valuable, with a single citation
`
`implying an average value of about $1 million. Giummo (2003) examines the royalties received by the
`
`inventor/patent holders at nine major German corporations under the German Employee Compensation
`
`Act and reaches similar conclusions.
`
`
`
`There is a substantial literature relating the stock market value of firms to various measures of
`
`“knowledge capital,” and in particular to R&D and patents, going back to the landmark research program
`
`initiated by Griliches and coworkers at the NBER.12 Hall (2000) offers a recent survey of this line of
`
`
`11 Consumer surplus was derived from an estimated discrete choice model of demand for CT scanners,
`based on purchases of scanners by US hospitals. Innovation manifested itself in the sale of improved
`scanners over time, i.e., scanners having better characteristics (e.g., speed and resolution).
`
`12 See, among others, Griliches (1981), Pakes (1985), Jaffe (1986), Griliches, Pakes, and Hall (1987),
`Connolly and Hirschey (1988), Griliches, Hall, and Pakes (1991), Hall (1993a), Hall (1993b), and
`Blundell, Griffith, and van Reenen (1999).
`
`9
`
`PMC Exhibit 2022
`Apple v. PMC
`IPR2016-00754
`Page 9
`
`

`
`work: the typical finding is that patent counts do not have as much explanatory power as R&D in a
`
`market value equation, but they do appear to add some information above and beyond R&D. A few
`
`papers have tried to incorporate patent citations as well, albeit in the context of small-scale studies: Shane
`
`(1993) finds that, for a small sample of semiconductor firms in 1977-1990, patents weighted by citations
`
`have more predictive power in a Tobin’s q equation than simple patent counts, entering significantly even
`
`when R&D stock is included. Citations-weighted patents also turned out to be more highly correlated with
`
`R&D than simple patent counts, implying that firms invest more efforts into patented innovations that
`
`ultimately yield more citations. Finally, Austin (1993) finds that citation-weighted counts enter positively
`
`but not significantly in an event study of patent grants in the biotechnology industry.
`
`
`
`3. Data
`
`
`
`For the purposes of this project we have brought together two large datasets and linked them via an
`
`elaborate matching process: the first is all patents granted by the USPTO between 1965 and 1996,
`
`including their patent citations; the second is firm data drawn from Compustat, including market value,
`
`assets, and R&D expenditures. The matching of the two sets (by firm name) proved to be a formidable,
`
`large-scale task, that tied up a great deal of our research efforts for a long time: Assignees obtain patents
`
`under a variety of names (their own and those of their subsidiaries), and the USPTO does not keep a
`
`unique identifier for each patenting organization from year to year. In fact, the initial list of corporate
`
`assignees of the 1965-1995 patents included over 100,000 entries, which we sought to match to the names
`
`of the approximately 6,000 manufacturing firms on the Compustat files, and to about 30,000 of their
`
`subsidiaries (obtained from the Who Owns Whom directory), as of 1989.13 In addition to firms patenting
`
`under a variety of names (in some cases for strategic purposes), the difficulties in matching are
`
`
`13 Since ownership patterns change over time, ideally one would like to match patents to firms at more
`than one point in time; however, the difficulties of the matching process made it impossible to aim for
`more than one match.
`
`10
`
`PMC Exhibit 2022
`Apple v. PMC
`IPR2016-00754
`Page 10
`
`

`
`compounded by the fact that there are numerous spelling mistakes in the names, and a bewildering array
`
`of abbreviations. As shown in Hall, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg (2001), we nevertheless succeeded in matching
`
`over half a million patents, which represent 50-65% (depending on the year) of all patents of US origin
`
`that were assigned to corporations during the years 1965 to 1995.14,15 Still, the results presented here
`
`should be viewed with some caution, since they might be affected by remaining matching errors and
`
`omissions.
`
`
`
`The Compustat data comprise all publicly traded firms in the manufacturing sector (SIC 2000-3999)
`
`between 1976 and 1995. After dropping duplicate observations and partially owned subsidiaries, and
`
`cleaning on our key variables, we ended up with an unbalanced panel of 4,864 firms (approximately
`
`1,700 per year). The firms are all publicly traded on the New York, American, and regional stock
`
`exchanges, or over-the-counter on NASDAQ. The main Compustat variables used here are the market
`
`value of the firm at the close of the year, the book value of the physical assets, and the book value of the
`
`R&D investment. The market value is defined as the sum of the common stock, the preferred stock,16 the
`
`long-term debt adjusted for inflation, and the short-term debt net of assets. The book value is the sum of
`
`net plant and equipment, inventories, and investments in unconsolidated subsidiaries, intangibles, and
`
`
`14 That is, the 573,000 matched patents compose 50-65% of all assigned patents (about one-quarter don’t
`have an assignee) granted to US corporate inventors. Since Compustat includes firms that are traded in
`the US stock market only, most US patents of foreign origin are obviously not matched. The percentage
`matched is rather high, considering that the matching was done only to manufacturing firms, and only to
`those listed in Compustat.
`
`15 In order to ensure that we picked up all the important subsidiaries, we examined and sought to assign
`all unmatched patenting organizations that had more than 50 patents during the period. A spot check of
`firms in the semiconductor industry suggests that our total patent numbers are fairly accurate, except for
`some firms for which we found a 5-15% undercount, due primarily to changing ownership patterns after
`1989 – see Hall and Ziedonis (2001).
`
`16 That is, the preferred dividends capitalized at the preferred dividend rate for medium risk companies
`given by Moodys.
`
`11
`
`PMC Exhibit 2022
`Apple v. PMC
`IPR2016-00754
`Page 11
`
`

`
`others (all adjusted for inflation).17 The R&D capital stock is constructed using a declining balance
`
`formula and the past history of R&D spending with a 15% depreciation rate (for details see Hall, 1990).
`
`
`
`Using the patents and citation data matched to the Compustat firms, we constructed patent stocks and
`
`citation-weighted patent stocks, applying the same declining balance formula used for R&D (also with a
`
`depreciation rate of 15%). Our patent data go back to 1964, and the first year for which we used a patent
`
`stock variable in the pooled regressions was 1975, so the effect of the missing initial condition (i.e.,
`
`patents prior to 1964) should be small for the patent variable. The fraction of firms in our sample
`
`reporting R&D expenditures each year hovers around 60-70%, and the fraction of firms with a positive
`
`patent stock lies in the same range.18 The yearly fraction of firms with current patent applications is about
`
`35-40%, the percentage dropping steeply by the end of period because of the application-grant lag.
`
`
`
`Dealing with truncation
`
`
`
`Patent data pose two types of truncation problems, one regarding patent counts, the other citation counts.
`
`The first stems from the fact that there is a significant lag between patent applications and patent grants
`
`(averaging lately about two years). Thus, as we approach the last year for which there are data available
`
`(e.g., 1995 in the data used here), we observe only a small fraction of the patents applied for that
`
`eventually will be granted.19 As shown in Appendix A, correcting for this sort of truncation bias is
`
`
`17 These intangibles are normally the goodwill and excess of market over book value from acquisitions,
`and do not include the R&D investment of the current firm, although they may include some value for the
`results of R&D by firms that have been acquired by the current firm.
`
`18 Even though there is substantial overlap between firms reporting R&D and those with patent stocks, the
`two sets are not nested: 19% of the firms with R&D stocks have no patents, while 13% of the firms with
`patent stocks report no R&D.
`
`19 Of course, the difficulty stems from the fact that we do not observe patent applications (and even if we
`did, we would not know which of them would eventually be granted), and that we date patents by their
`application rather than by their grant year.
`
`12
`
`PMC Exhibit 2022
`Apple v. PMC
`IPR2016-00754
`Page 12
`
`

`
`relatively straightforward, and essentially involves using the application-grant empirical distribution to
`
`compute “weight factors.” Thus, and using the results reported there, a patent count for, say, 1994 would
`
`be adjusted upwards by a factor of 1.166, implying that about 17% of the patents applied for in 1994 are
`
`expected to be granted after 1995, the last year of the data.
`
`
`
`Citation counts are inherently truncated, since patents keep receiving citations over long periods of time
`
`(in some cases even after 50 years), but we observe at best only the citations given up to the present, and
`
`more realistically only up to the last year of the available data. Moreover, patents applied for in different
`
`years suffer to different extents from this truncation bias in citations received, and hence their citation
`
`intensity is not comparable and cannot be aggregated. For recent patents the problem is obviously more
`
`acute, since we only observe the first few years of citations. Thus, a 1993 patent that received ten citations
`
`by 1996 (the end of our data) is likely to be a higher citation-intensity patent than a 1985 patent that
`
`received 11 citations within our data period. Furthermore, although our basic patent information begins in
`
`1964, we only have data on the citations made by patents beginning in 1976. Hence patents granted
`
`before 1976 experience truncation at the beginning of their citation cycle.20
`
`
`
`We address the problem of truncated citations by estimating the shape of the citation-lag distribution, i.e.,
`
`the fraction of lifetime citations (defined as the 30 years after the grant date) that are received in each year
`
`after patent grant. We assume that this distribution is stationary and independent of overall citation
`
`intensity. Given this distribution, we can estimate the total citations of any patent for which we observe a
`
`portion of its citation life simply by dividing the observed citations by the fraction of the population
`
`distribution that lies in the time interval for which citations are observed.21 In the case of patents for
`
`
`20 Thus, a 1964 patent that received ten citations between 1976 and 1996 is probably more citation-
`intensive than a 1976 patent that received 11 citations over that same period.
`
`21 The details of the estimation of the citation lag distribution and the derived adjustment to citation
`intensity are described in Hall, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg (2000), Appendix D, and further adjustment
`procedures are developed in Hall, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg (2001).
`
`13
`
`PMC Exhibit 2022
`Apple v. PMC
`IPR2016-00754
`Page 13
`
`

`
`which we observe the prime citation years (roughly years 3-10 after grant), this should give relatively
`
`accurate estimates of lifetime citations. On the other hand, when we observe only the first few years after
`
`grant (which is the case for more recent patents), the estimates will be much more noisy. In particular, the
`
`estimate of lifetime citations for patents with no citations in their first few years will be exactly zero,
`
`despite the fact that some of those patents will be eventually cited. Because of the increasing imprecision
`
`in measuring cites per patent as we approach the end of our sample period, our pooled regressions focus
`
`first on the 1976-1992 period, and then on the subset of years between 1979 and 1988.22
`
` first look at the data
`
` A
`
`
`
`Table 1 shows the sample statistics for the main variables used in the analysis, for the sample of
`
`observations analyzed in Tables 3 through 6: as expected, both market and book value, and the various
`
`knowledge stocks (R&D, patents, and citations), are extremely skewed, with the means exceeding the
`
`median by over an order of magnitude. The ratios R&D/Assets and Citations/Patents are distributed much
`
`more symmetrically, reflecting systematic size effects; however, the patent yield (Patents/R&D) retains a
`
`high degree of skewness and displays a large variance, indicating a rather weak correlation between the
`
`two stocks. Both the dependent variable (market to book value) and the candidate regressors in the
`
`models to be estimated exhibit a non-negligible amount of within variation, suggesting that there is
`
`interesting “action” in both the cross-sectional and the temporal dimensions.
`
`
`
`Figure 1 shows the total citation and patenting rates per real R&D spending in our sample. Patent counts
`
`are adjusted for the application-grant lag, and citation counts are shown both corrected and uncorrected:
`
`
`22 Another issue that arises in this context is that the number of citations made by each patent has been
`rising over time, suggesting a kind of “citation inflation” that renders each citation less significant in later
`years. In this paper we choose not to make any correction for the secular changes in citation rates, with
`the cost that our extrapolation attempts become somewhat inaccurate later in the sample. For a detailed
`discussion of this issue, and of econometric techniques to deal with it, see Hall, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg
`(2001).
`
`14
`
`PMC Exhibit 2022
`Apple v. PMC
`IPR2016-00754
`Page 14
`
`

`
`clearly, correcting for truncation has a dramatic impact on the series, particularly for recent years.
`
`Although the earlier years (1975-1985) show a steady decline in paten

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket