throbber
Medac Exhibit 2052
`
`Frontier Therapeutics V. Medac
`IPR2016-00649
`
`Page 00001
`
`Medac Exhibit 2052
`Frontier Therapeutics v. Medac
`IPR2016-00649
`Page 00001
`
`

`
`THE OXFORD HANDBOOK OF
`
`THE ECONOMICS
`
`OF THE
`
`BIOPHARMACEUTICAL
`
`INDUSTRY
`
`Page 00002
`
`Page 00002
`
`

`
`CONS ULTING EDITORS
`
`MICI-IAEL SZENBERG
`
`LUBIN SCHOOL OF BUSINESS, PACE UNIVERSITY
`
`LALL RAMRATTAN
`
`UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY EXTENSION
`
`Page 00003
`
`Page 00003
`
`

`
`THE OXFORD HANDBOOK OF
`
`THE ECONOMICS
`
`OF THE
`
`BIOPHARMACEUTICAL
`
`INDUSTRY
`
`Edited by
`
`PATRICIA M. DANZON
`
`AND
`
`SEAN NICHOLSON
`
`UNIVERSITY PRESS
`
`Page 00004
`
`Page 00004
`
`

`
`OXFORD
`UI\‘iV"3iRSI'l'Y PRESS
`
`Oxford University Press. Inc. publishes works that further
`Oxford Un iversity’s objective of excellence
`in research. scholarship, and education.
`Oxford New York
`
`Auckland Cape Town Dar es Salaam Hong Kong Karachi
`Koala Lu mpur Madrid Melbourne Mexico City Nairobi
`New Delhi Shanghai Taipei Toronto
`With offices in
`
`Argentina Austria Brazil Chile Czech Republic France Greece
`Guatemala Hungary
`Italy
`Iapan Poland
`Portugal Singapore
`South Korea Switzerland Thailand Turkey Ukraine Vietnam
`
`Copyright @ 2012 by Oxford University Press
`
`Published byottford University Press. Inc.
`198 Madison Avenue, New York, New York 1oo16
`www.oup.com
`
`Oxford is a registered trademark of Oxford University Press
`
`All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced,
`stored in a retrieval system. or transmitted, in any form or by any means,
`electronic. mechanical, photocopying, recording. or otherwise,
`without the prior permission ofoxford University Press.
`
`Library of Congress Cataloging—in-Publication Data
`The Oxford handbook of the economics of the biopharmaceutical industry!
`edited by Patricia M. Damon and Sean Nicholson.
`p. cm.
`Includes bibliographical references and indexes.
`ISBN 9,73-CI-I9-9}4199-5 (cloth :alk. paper)
`1. Pharmaceutical industry.
`2. Biopharmaceutics—-Economic aspects.
`I. Danzon. Patricia Munch. 1946-
`II. Nicholson, Sean.
`III. Title: Economics of the biopharmaceutical industry.
`HD9665.5.O94 zou
`338.4’;-615y—dc23
`2011040315
`
`135 7 9 8 6 4 2
`Printed in the United States of America
`on acid-free paper
`
`Page 00005
`
`Page 00005
`
`

`
`CONTENTS
`
`Contributors
`
`.
`
`Introduction
`PATRICIA M. DANZON AND SEAN NICHOLSON
`
`PART I PHARMACEUTICAL INNOVATION
`
`. R&D Costs and Returns to New Drug Development:
`A Review of the Evidence
`
`]osEpH AI DIMASI AND HENRY G. Gnanowsxr
`
`. Financing Research and Development
`SEAN NICHOLSON
`
`. Cost of Capital for Pharmaceutical, Biotechnology,
`and Medical Device Firms
`SCOTT E. HARRINGTON
`
`. The Regulation of Medical Products
`ANUP MALANI AND Torvms PHILIPSON
`
`.
`
`Incentives to Innovate
`DARIUS LAKDAWALLA AND NEERA] Soon
`
`. Patents and Regulatory Exclusivity
`REBECCA S. EISENBERG
`
`vii
`
`1
`
`21
`
`47
`
`75
`
`1oo
`
`143
`
`167
`
`PART II THE MARKET FOR PHARMACEUTICALS
`
`. Pricing and Reimbursement in US Pharmaceutical Markets
`ERNST R. BERNDT AND JOSEPH P. NEWHOUSE
`
`. Regulation of Price and Reimbursement for Pharmaceuticals
`PATRICIA M. DANZON
`
`201
`
`266
`
`Page00006
`
`Page 00006
`
`

`
`
`
`vi CONTENTS
`
`10. Drugs and Vaccines for Developing Countries
`ADRIAN Towse, ERIC KEUFFEL, HANNAH E. KETTLER,
`AND DAVID B. RIDLEY
`
`11. Insurance and Drug Spending
`MARK V. PAULY
`
`12. Consumer Demand and Health Effects of Cost—Sharing
`DANA P. GOLDMAN AND GEOFFREY F. IOYCE
`
`13. Measuring Value: Pharmacoeconornics Theory and Practice
`ADRIAN Towse, MICHAEL DRUMMOND,
`AND CORINNA SORENSON
`
`14. Price Indexes for Prescription Drugs: A Review of the Issues
`ANA AIZCORBE AND NICOLE NESTORIAK
`
`15. Empirical Evidence on the Value of Pharmaceuticals
`CRAIG GARTHWAITE AND MARK DUGGAN
`
`16. Promotion to Physicians and Consumers
`DoN KENKEL AND ALAN MATHIOS
`
`17. The Economics of Vaccines
`FRANK A. S1.oAN
`
`18. Mergers, Acquisitions. and Alliances
`HENRY G. GRABowsRr AND MARGARET KYLE
`
`Index
`
`302
`
`336
`
`365
`
`394
`
`438
`
`463
`
`493
`
`524
`
`552
`
`579
`
`Page 00007
`
`Page 00007
`
`

`
`
`
`CHAPTER 2
`
`R&D COSTS AND
`
`RETURNS TO NEW
`
`DRUG DEVELOPMENT:
`
`A REVIEW OF THE
`
`EVIDENCE
`
`IOSEPH A. DIMASI AND
`
`HENRY G. GRABOWSKI
`
`ECONOMIC analyses of research and development (R&D) costs and returns in
`pharmaceuticals have received prominent attention by scholars and policy
`makers. Investment cycles in pharmaceuticals span several decades. Trends in
`future R&D costs and returns shape the incentives for companies to pursue R8(D
`opportunities for new medicines. Economic studies provide a basis for evaluat-
`ing all the factors affecting R&D costs and returns and can be useful in assessing
`productivity changes in the pharmaceutical and hiopharmaceutical industries
`(Munos 2oo9). They also can be used to consider how various policy actions
`(e.g., price regulation) affect innovation incentives (Giaccotto et al. zoos; Vernon
`zoos).
`
`This chapter reviews the extensive literature on R&D costs and returns. The
`first section focuses on R&D costs and the various factors that have affected the
`trends in real R8<D costs over time. The second section considers economic stud-
`ies on the distribution of returns in pharmaceuticals for different cohorts of new
`drug introductions. It also reviews the use of these studies to analyze the impact
`
`Page 00008
`
`Page 00008
`
`

`
`“*--sun
`
`PHARMACEUTICAL INNOVATION
`
`3,.’/’—"—-’?—T
`&D costs and returns. The final section concludes and dis.
`for further research.
`
`of policy actions on R
`cusses open questififls
`
`PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY R&D Cosrs
`
`Estimates ofthe cost of developing new drugs have varied rnethodologically and
`in terms of coverage, but taken together, they paint a picture of substantially rising
`costs for more than half a century. The resource cost increases are dramatic, even
`after adjusting for inflation. This section briefly reviews the literature on pharma-
`ceutical R8rD costs and then describes some of the more recent results.
`
`Approaches to Estimating Pharmaceutical
`Industry R8rD Costs
`Early attempts to examine at least some of the costs of new drug development were
`quite limited in that they did not account for important aspects of the drug devel-
`opment process, such as non—drug-specific R&D, expenditures on drug failures.
`and the length of the development process and its relationship to opportunity
`costs. DiMasi et al. (1991) referenced and discussed the early economic iiterature
`on the R&D costs of new drug development. One of the earliest of these studies
`(SChnee 1972] examined data on 17 new chemical entities (NCEs) from the 19505
`and 19605 for a single firm. However, only out-of~pocket (cash outlay) costs were
`‘3°“5ld3TE'd {i.e., the time costs of R3(D investments were not evaluated), and nei-
`ther fixed discovery costs nor the costs ofdrug failures were counted. This was fol-
`lowed by several studies that also focused on individual drug out-of-pocket costs;
`taken together with the Schnee estimate of an average cost of $0.5 million per NCE.
`these Studies Slfsgested that R&D costs increased substantially from the 19505 to
`the1_:11,t1:196°S(1_\’Iu“d 197”? Balli’ 1971; Sarett 1974; Clymer 1970}.
`from E1:12:31);lliterature also included two attempts to develop R8rD cost estimates
`NCE:[Mund 1‘9‘gg‘1'*‘33?1_i*°31I1dustrydata on R?-3rD expenditures and lists 0fappt'0\’€d
`.
`7°‘ Ball)’ 1972)- These studies assumed fixed lag times between
`ttlflttstry R&D expenditures and new drug approvals. Although these approaches
`;:1I::::l)}1;acpounted for the costs of drug failures, neither of them included C3?‘
`approvals.
`or accounted for varying lag times between expenditures and
`(casgzpuliiarsi ptucly that attempted to capture the full costs of drug development
`Y
`or lnvesngallonal dmg failures as well as successes, fixed disc0V91'Y
`
`.
`
`Page 00009
`
`o costs
`
`-
`
`.
`
`Page 00009
`
`

`
`
`
`
`
`RSKD COSTS AND RETURNS TO NEW DRUG DEVELOPMENT 23
`
`and preclinical development costs. and time costs) was that of Hansen (1979). The
`study used Tufts Center for the Study of Drug Development (Tufts CSDD) survey
`data from a dozen pharmaceutical firms to obtain a random sample oftheir inves-
`tigational drugs and aggregate annual data on their R8rD expenditures broken
`down by development phase and compound source (self-originated or licensed—in).
`Hansen found an average capitalized cost 0f$54 million in 1976 dollars for develop-
`ment that occurred in the 1960s and up to the mid—1970s. As with most subsequent
`studies, Hansen estimated the R&D cost per approved drug, taking into consider-
`ation costs incurred on failed drugs and adjusting historical costs to take account
`ofthe opportunity costs oftime.
`Following the Hansen (1979) Study, Wiggins (1987) applied a regression analysis
`using ir1dustry—reported aggregate annual R&D expenditure data combined with
`the development time profile used by Hansen. Wiggins found a capitalized cost per
`approved new drug of $125 million in 1986 dollars for drugs approved from 1970
`to 1985. However, implicit in the analysis was the assumption ofa fixed lag rela-
`tionship for the time between R&D expenditures and ultimate new drug approval.
`This was not a shortcoming with the Hansen approach.
`Since Hansen's (1979) study, the survey approach has been dominant, with
`similar studies from DiMasi and associates that found increasingly higher R8rD
`cost estimates for later periods. Specifically, DiMasi et al. (1991) reported an aver-
`age R&D cost of $2.31 million in year 1987 dollars ($318 million in year 2000 dol-
`lars), and DiMasi et al. (2003) reported an average R3{D cost of $802 million in
`year 2000 dollars. Companion studies to these two survey-based articles exam-
`ined how R8(D costs varied by therapeutic category (DiMasi et al. 1995; DiMasi
`et al. 2004). Gilbert et al. (2003), using an internal Bain Consulting develop-
`ment model, found an estimate of $1.1 billion for 1995 to 2000 approvals, but
`the methodology was not described in any great detail and the results included
`launch costs. In two recent papers, Adams and Brantner (2006, 2010) attempted
`to validate the results reported by DiMasi et al. in 2003 using public data and
`found general support for them. Earlier, the Congressional Office of Technology
`Assessment concluded that the results in the 1991 DiMasi et al. study were rea-
`sonable (US. Congress, OTA 1993).
`The highest estimate to date in the literature of the expected, fully capital-
`ized cost of developing a single approved drug was $1.8 billion in year 2008 doi-
`lars (Paul et al. 2010). The authors obtained this resuit by using a mathematical
`model, some recent industry benchmark data on part of the process, and some
`internal data from a single firm. The most recent full capitalized R&D cost esti-
`mates based on industry survey data were reported by DiMasi and Grabowski
`(2007), although they focused on “biotech” drug development. The DiMasi et
`al. (2003) and DiMasi and Grabowski (2007) findings are discussed in some
`detail later in this chapter, along with some comparisons to the earlier findings
`to illustrate the extent to which pharmaceutical R8rD costs have changed over
`time.
`
`
`
`Page 00010
`
`Page 00010
`
`

`
`
`
`PHARMACEUTICAL INNOVATION
`3:....__—————————‘———~—-
`
`Risks, Times, and Costs for Traditional
`Pharmaceutical Industry R&D
`Figure 2.1 indicates how inflation—adlU5ted aggregate ind‘-l5l1'Y P1731"macefllical
`R&D expenditures have changed over a long period, measured against changes over
`the same period in the number of US new drug approvals (new chemical entities.
`or NCEs). Given that drug development phases are lengthy, spreading over many
`years (DiMasi et al. 1991), there is a substantial lag between when R8-(D expendi-
`tures are made and when new drugs get approved. Nonetheless, the data in Figure
`2.1 strongly suggest that average RSID costs have risen at a rapid rate over time. A
`more rigorous analysis is needed to assess just how high pharmaceutical RBID costs
`have been during any period and how rapidly they have risen over time. It is also
`instructive to look beneath an overall estimate of drug development cost to impor-
`tant aspects of the drug development process that contribute to that cost.
`
`Technical Risks
`
`One of the most important contributors to cost of drug development is the amount
`of resources that are devoted to drugs that fail in testing at some point in the devel-
`opment process. The series of studies begun with Hansen (1979) involved esti-
`mates of the likelihood that a drug that enters the clinical testing pipeline (i.e..
`phase 1) will eventually be approved for marketing by the US Food and Drug
`Administration (FDA) and estimates of attrition rates for drugs during the three
`clinical phases ofdeveloprnent. Hansen used a clinical approval success rate ofone
`in eight (12.5 percent). The second study in the series, DiMasi et al. (1991), found
`that the clinical approval success rate between the two study periods had increased
`substantially, to between one in five and one in four (2.3 percent). If nothing else
`had changed from one study period to the next, the estimated cost per approved
`
`_
`
`O
`R8<D Expenditures
`
`50
`
`45
`
`W‘
`5°. 99
`E U
`O m
`30 E 35
`-*1 3
`3 E
`3% E
`15 " "’
`
`so
`
`45
`
`m
`3
`3
`E
`3? 3°
`Lu
`'2‘
`Z 15
`
`0
`1963
`
`_
`
`I
`
`lI
`
`5
`i
`._
`
`196?
`
`E}
`
`
`9
`I
`'»-‘l
`1975
`I95’?
`1933
`193?
`199!
`1995
`1999
`2003
`2007
`F‘
`.
`Source’ Coulfule 2;1| New drug approvals and R8“) spendmg
`Ph»armace::lsl_)’I)1 gulls Center for the Study of Drug Development {CSDD) and
`Ica
`escarch and Manufacturers of America (PhRMA), 2oo9.
`
`__..u
`
`"“=--~——H
`
`Page 00011
`
`Page 00011
`
`

`
`
`
`RSID COSTS AND RETURNS TO NEW DRUG DEVELOPMENT
`
`25
`
`new drug, inclusive of the cost of failures, would have declined significantly. This
`did not happen because, as described later, out-of—pocl<et preclinical and clinical
`costs also increased substantially, as did average development times and the cost of
`capital. The result was a much higher full average cost estimate.
`The most recent study in the series, DiMasi et al. (2003), found that the success
`rate had worsened for drugs tested in humans between 1983 and 1994 relative to
`drugs tested on humans between 1970 and 1982, but only modestly. The estimate of
`the clinical approval success rate was 21.5 percent. The effect offailures on costs was
`modified somewhat by estimates showing that firms had terminated their clinical
`failures earlier. However, as discussed later, other factors contributed to produce a
`much higher full cost per approved drug for the most recent period.
`
`Development Times
`
`When the R&D process for pharmaceuticals is lengthy, development cycles will
`be an important indirect determinant of costs if cash flows are capitalized to the
`point at which revenues from the investment could be earned. As development
`times increase, so do capitalized cost estimates, other things equal. The time from
`synthesis ofa new compound to first testing in humans increased by 6.6 months,
`on average, between the Hansen (1979) study and the DiMasi et al. (1991) study.
`The time from first human testing to regulatory approval increased by almost 21
`months, on average, between the study periods. The extra 2.3 years in average total
`time from discovery to approval for the second study period accounted for approx-
`imately 24 percent oftbe increase in average costs between the studies.
`In contrast, changes in development times had little impact on the increase in
`average cost between the DiMasi et al. (1991) study and the most recent study in
`the series, DiMasi et al. (2003). Although the time from first testing in humans to
`regulatory approval declined by an average of 8.6 months between the two study
`periods, the total time from discovery to approval remained, on average, virtually
`identical at 11.8 years. The increase in the cost of capital had a much greater impact
`on total capitalized costs than did changes in development times.
`
`Opportunity Costs
`
`Industrial R&D expenditures are investments, and there are potentially long lags
`between when the expenditures are made and when any potential returns can be
`earned. The three survey-based studies we focus on here attempted to capture
`these time costs, which, together with the ot1t~of-pocket costs ofdevelopment, yield
`a measure ofthe opportunity costs ofbringing drugs from discovery to marketing
`approval. The approach is to capitalize costs to the point of first US approval using
`an appropriate discount rate. The discount rates used were estimates of the cost of
`capital for the pharmaceutical industry over the respective study periods. Average
`out—of-pocket costs by development phase were spread over average development
`times for each phase and capitalized to the point of marketing approval at the dis-
`count rate used for the study.
`
`Page 00012
`
`Page 00012
`
`

`
` 6
`
`PHARMACEUTICAL INNOVATION
`1./if/rme
`
`The real (i.e., inflation-adjusted) costs of capital used for the first two studies
`were 8 percent and 9 percent, respectively. The increase of one percentage paint
`accounted for 13 percent ofthe increase in costs between the first two studies. The
`gnmhinaiion of longer development times and a higher discount rate for the sec.
`and study accounted for 37 percent of the increase in average costs. As mentioned
`earlier, although there were some differences in development times between the
`second and third studies, the total development time was constant. Nonetheless.
`the estimated discount rate applied to the cash flows over the representative time
`profile was 2 percentage points higher for the third study (11 percent versus 9 per.
`cent). However, out-of-pocket costs increased enough that the time cost share of
`total capitalized cost remained virtually the same (50 percent for the third study.
`compared with 51 percent for the second).
`Figure 2.2 shows the primary results for the DiMasi et al. (2003) study. In year
`zooo dollars, the estimated preapproval capitalized cost per approved new drug
`was $802 million, with $403 million of that total accounted for by out-of-pocket
`cash outlays. Pharmaceutical R&D does not end with the approval of an NCE.
`Development often continues on new indications, new dosage strengths, and new
`formulations. The DiMasi et al. (2003) study provided an estimate of postapproval
`R&D costs. It found that approximately one-quarter of the total R8<D life—cycle
`cash outlays per approved new drug were incurred after a drug product contain-
`ing the active ingredient was first approved. Given that the analysis is focused on
`the point of first marketing approval, the postapproval costs must be discounted
`back in time to the date of marketing approval. Therefore, on a capitalized basis,
`postapproval R&D costs account for only 11 percent of the total life—cyc1e R&D cost
`per approved drug, $897 million.
`
`Cost Trends
`
`The three survey—based studies, taken together, demonstrate that pharmaceutical
`industry R&D costs increased dramatically over the first four decades of the mod-
`ern era of drug development-—that is, since enactment of the 1962 Amendments to
`
`(2000S)
`Millions
`
`Out-of—Pocket
`
`Capitalized
`
`El P°“'aPPm"31 U Pre-approval I Total
`
`Figure 2.2 Pharmaceutical Iife—cycle R&D costs.
`Source: From DiMasi et al. 2oo3.
`
`_,
`
`.
`
`'
`
`i
`
`'
`;
`
`i
`
`Page 00013
`
`Page 00013
`
`

`
`
`
`RSID COSTS AND RETURNS TO NEW DRUG DEVELOPMENT
`
`2)’
`
`Millions
`
`(2000S}
`
`Figure 2.3 Pharmaceutical R8cD costs gave increased substantially over lime.
`Source: From Dilvlasi et al. zoo}.
`
`the Food and Drug Cosmetic Act of 1938, which, for the first time in the United
`States, required proof of efficacy as well as safety. Figure 2.3 shows how preclini-
`cal, clinical, and total preapproval average costs increased across the three studies.
`Preclinical costs are all costs incurred prior to first human testing. This includes
`out~of-pocket discovery costs as well as the costs of preclinical development.
`Clinical costs include all R&D costs incurred from initial human testing to first
`ma rlceting approval.
`In constant dollars, total capitalized preapproval cost per approved new drug
`increased by a factor of 2.3 between the Hansen (1979) study and the DiMasi et al.
`(1991) study, and there was a similar increase of 2.5 between DiMasi et al. (1991)
`and DiMasi et al. (2003). However, at a more disaggregated level. there were sub-
`stantial differences. From the first to the second study, preclinical costs increased
`somewhat more than did clinical period costs. However, between the second and
`third studies, clinical cost per approved drug increased substantially more rapidly
`than preclinical cost (an increase of 349 percent for the former, compared with 57
`percent for the latter).
`The length of time between the study periods was not identical. We can
`get a more precise estimate of the rate of increase in costs across the studies by
`estimating the average endpoint for analysis in each study. The endpoint is the
`date of marketing approval. The first study roughly corresponded to develop-
`ment that yielded approvals during the 1970s, development for the second study
`mostly resulted in approvals during the 19805, and development for the most
`recent study was associated largely with 1990s approvals. DiMasi et al. (2003)
`found an average difference in approval dates of 9.3 years between the first and
`second studies and 13 years between the second and third studies. Using these
`time differences, we can calculate average annual rates ofincrease between the
`studies.
`
`Figure 2.4 indicates that the annual rate of increase in inflation-adjusted total
`out-of-pocket costs was relatively constant across the studies (7.6 percent between
`the first and second studies and 7.0 percent between the second and third studies).
`However, the rates of increase in overall costs mask substantial differences in how
`
`Page 00014
`
`Page 00014
`
`

`
`
`
`PHARMACEUTICAL INN0VAT1oN
`
`
`
`Preclinical
`Clinical
`Total
`‘I
`[5 191905 to 19303 approvals
`I 1980510 1990s approvals
`Figure 2.4 Annual growth rates for R&D out-of-pocket cost per approved new drug.
`Source: From DiMasi et al. 2oo3.
`
`costs changed over time for components ofthe R&D process. Figure 2.4 shows that.
`whereas preclinical costs continued to increase in real terms between the second
`and third studies, the rate of increase was less than one~third that between the first
`and second studies. On the other hand, the rate of increase in clinical period costs
`was dramatic for the most recent study—almost twice as fast as that between the
`first and second studies.
`
`Large-Molecule R&D Cost Metrics
`Almost all prior research on pharmaceutical R8rD costs has focused on synthetic,
`so-called small—molecule drugs, as opposed to biologics, or large-molecule drugs.
`Although some of the molecules for the DiMasi et al. (2003) sample were biolog-
`ics, the overwhelming majority of the drugs in the sample and in the pipelines of
`the survey firms at that time were small-molecule drugs. The study by DiMasi and
`Grabowski (2007) was the first to focus on so-called biotech molecules. Specifically.
`ll“? Sample the)’ used consisted ofapproximately equal numbers of recombinant pro-
`teins and monoclonal antibodies [mAbs). Although out—of-pocket clinical costs were
`Collected for a relatively small sample of large molecules (17), the other metrics used
`for the 503‘ analysis (development times and success and attrition rates) were deter-
`mined from large Samples. The same methodology used to estimate average costs
`for the three survey-based studies of traditional pharmaceutical firm development.
`described earlier, Was applied to the biotech sample.
`Figure 2-5 Shows some of the main results from the DiMasi and Grabowslti
`(WW) smdl" The average 0V€rall
`capitalized cost per approved new chemical
`entity was $1.2 billion for large molecules. The study also compared develop-
`ment costs for 5"‘-all and large molecules. First, the results from the DiMasi el Ell-
`
`H
`fl
`'
`
`:.
`I
`
`Page 00015
`
`Page 00015
`
`

`
`
`
`RSED COSTS AND RETURNS TO NEW DRUG DEVELOPMENT 29
`
`Millions
`
`(20055)
`
`Preclinical‘
`
`Clinical
`
`Total
`
`[I Biotech III Pharma I Pharma (time-adustcd)"
`
`Figure 2.5 Preapproval capitalized cost by new molecule type.
`Source: From Dilviasi and Gr-abowslti zoo}.
`
`(2003) study were adjusted upward for inflation, because the biotech results were
`expressed in constant 2.005 dollars. This yielded costs for the preclinical and clin-
`ical phases, and overall costs, that were significantly lower for traditional small-
`molecule development. However, the molecules used for the biotech analysis were
`ofa later vintage than the sample used for the 2003 study. The biotech sample was,
`in some sense, five years more recent. Consequently, the results from the DiMasi
`et al. (2003) study were not only adjusted for inflation but also extrapolated out
`five years using the growth rates implied by the differences between the second
`and third survey-based studies of traditional pharmaceutical development (see
`Figure 2.4). This produced an overall capitalized cost per approved new chemical
`entity for traditional pharmaceutical firm development similar to that for biotech
`development ($1.3 billion and $1.2. billion, respectively). However, there were sub-
`stantial differences by development phase. Clinical period costs were higher for
`traditional pharmaceutical development, but preclinical phase costs were higher
`for biotech development.
`
`Recent Metrics and Implications for R&D Costs
`
`The studies in the academic literature on the costs of new drug development cover
`the period from the 19305 to part ofthe first decade ofthe 21st century. However, it
`is interesting to at least consider the trends for R&D costs during more recent years
`and for the near future. Without new data on cash flows, we cannot be conclusive
`
`about such trends, but there are many metrics that have an impact on full costs
`that can be examined for recent years. Taken together, these metrics may strongly
`suggest a direction ofchange.
`
`Page 00016
`
`Page 00016
`
`

`
`PHARMACEUTICAL INNOVATION
`§2....c»»f——r*-=fi}--~
`
`_
`_
`_
`.
`Impact ofRisk and Time on Rd-D Costs
`Before we examine recent industry benchmark data, it is instructive to get a sense
`for the degree to which chaflgfls in “main 1(9)’ de"el°Pm*?m Parameters affect over-
`all costs. DiMasi (2002) W35 the firs‘ to Construct Various thought exp°rim°“l5
`that examined how much the capitalized cost per approved new drug changes in
`response to isolated changes in individual development phase lengths, equal pro-
`portionate changes for all development phase lengths simultaneously, individual
`c1inieal—phase attrition rates, and clinical approval success rates.
`Figure 2.6 is taken from the DiMasi (2002) study. It uses the results from the last
`survey—based study of traditional pharmaceutical industry development (Diiviasi
`et al. 2oo3) as the base against which changes are measured. The figure shows, in
`percentage terms, the extent to which full capitalized cost per approved new drug
`is reduced if the overall clinical approval success rate is increased from its base
`case value of 21.5 percent to 35 percent. The results indicate that cost per approved
`new drug can be reduced by approximately 30 percent if the approval success rate
`increases from approximately one in five to one in three.
`A similar improvement in average cost can be obtained instead from faster
`development times. Figure 2.7 shows that a 30 percent improvement in total capi-
`talized cost per approved new drug would occur if all development phases and the
`regulatory approval phase were simultaneously reduced by half, other things equal.
`Since this work, Paul et al. (zoro) has presented similar results for improvements in
`parameters of their mathematical model.
`
`Development Time, Success Rate, and Trial Complexity Trends
`
`Although comprehensive estimates of out—of—pocl<et cash flows for new drug R&D
`for recent years are not available, we can examine trend data for aspects of the
`development process that can be substantial determinants of changes in costs. As
`
`35%
`
`30%
`25%
`20%
`15%
`I 0%
`5%
`
`0%
`
`reduction
`Cost
`
`|I—..I1_I_L__|_Lt_|_LII._t_|__.|n||IIIt|
`e’.‘:?‘3?‘Jz9,s“3rr‘3%‘)d"39"'o*”z"°J*".:>“"
`“‘% ‘% ‘la is ‘‘‘s “is
`is is is "e ‘ta “ta '°‘e fie
`Success Rate
`
`_l
`E-Avewge P5359 905? +Phase cost adjusted for cost offailures
`F‘§“T¢ 1-5 C05! reductions from higher clinical success rates.
`Source: From DiMasi 2002.
`
`._.
`
`Page 00017
`
`;
`'
`
`i
`
`5
`5
`
`Page 00017
`
`

`
`REID COSTS AND RETURNS TO NEW DRUG DEVELOPMENT
`
`31
`
`30%
`
`Cost
`
`25%
`
`20%
`
`15%
`
`0%
`
`reduction
`
`..I—..
`
`lm * + rim I
`
`—l.
`
`'
`
`2l-
`
`=2
`E
`
`0%
`
`5%
`
`10% 15% 20% 25% 30% 35% 40% 45% 50%
`Phase time reduction
`
`-1- Clinical cost —I- Total cost
`
`Figure 2.7 Cost reductions from simultaneous percentage
`decreases in all phase lengths.
`Source: rom DiMasi 2002.
`
`noted earlier, lengthier average development times, other things being equal, result
`in higher full cost estimates, because R3rD cash flows are capitalized at a given dis-
`count rate over a longer period before first marketing approval. Kaitin and DiMasi
`(2011) examined US clinical development and regulatory approval phase trends
`since the early 19805 (Figure 2.8). Although these data do not account for clinical
`testing periods outside the United States prior to testing in the United States nor
`for preclinical development periods, the average total time from the start of clini—
`cal testing in the United States to US regulatory approval has varied little, ranging
`from approximately eight to nine years for each five-year period since the early
`1980s.
`
`Although development times have remained relatively stable over the last few
`decades, the data on technical risks in drug development indicate a worsening of
`conditions. The DiMasi et al. (2003) study found an estimated clinical approval
`success rate of a little more than one in five (21.5 percent) for investigational drugs
`that first entered clinical testing between 1983 and 1994. More recently, DiMasi
`et al. (2010) found an estimated clinical success rate of approximately one in six
`(16 percent) for investigational drugs that first entered clinical testing from 1994
`through 2oo4 (Figure 2.9). Others have suggested even lower success rates for drugs
`tested in humans more recently (Paul et al. 2010).
`We can also gain insight into changes in direct resource costs associated with
`individual investigational drugs from data on the complexity ofclinical trials at a
`fairly micro level. Getz et al. (2008) examined a very large number ofUS-based piv-
`otal clinical trial protocols to determine changes in protocol complexity over time.
`Unique procedures in these protocols were counted, as well as the frequency with
`which those procedures were to be employed in each protocol. In addition, eligibil-
`ity criteria were examined, and a measure of investigator work effort was applied
`to the individual procedures. Data for 1992-2002 and 2003-2006 were compared.
`
`Page00018
`
`Page 00018
`
`

`
`
`
`PHARMACEUTICAL INNOVATION
`
`Years
`
`
`1935-89
`
` 193934 1990-94
`
`I3 Approval Phase
`13 Clinical Phase
`Figure 2.8 Mean US clinical development and regulatory approval phase
`times by period of approval.
`Source: From Kaitin and DiMasi zou.
`
`Transition
`
`Probability
`
`Phase I-II
`
`Phase ll-lli
`
`Phase 111-
`NDNBLA Sub
`
`NDAJBLA Sub-
`NDAIBLA App
`
`Phase I —
`NDAFBLA App
`
`E] 19934998 I 1999-2004
`
`Figure 2.9 Phase transilion probabilities and clinical success rates
`_
`‘
`by period of first human testing.
`*‘“’l"’9"'“’I°flS= NBA. new drug application: BLA. biologic license application;
`Sill?» Submitted; App. application.
`Source: From DiMa.~;i el al. now.
`
`Page 00019
`
`Page 00019
`
`

`
`
`
`
`
`I‘-."".-‘.-'\r_-er-‘cl-r-.'"M...-h’1’n':u/lit.a..''"
`
`
`
`
`
`R3(D COSTS AND RETURNS TO NEW DRUG DEVELOPMENT
`
`33
`
`As shown in Figure 2.10, the number of unique procedures per protocol, the fre-
`quency with which the procedures were applied, the work effort per procedure,
`and an overall measure ofthe burden of executing the protocols all increased. Of
`the measures depicted in Figure 2.10, only investigator fees declined, and those
`only slightly. In addition, the authors found that eligibility criteria for enrollment
`increased, patient enrollment and retention rates declined, and the number ofcase
`report forms per protocol increased.
`
`Impiicationsfor Rd-D Cost Trends
`
`The recent trends in aspects of the drug development process described in the
`previous section have implications for R&D costs in recent years. As was the case
`for differences between the second and the third survey-based studies, the data
`on approved drugs examined to date make it seem unlikely that changes in devel-
`opment and regulatory approval phase times will have had much impact on R&D
`costs in recent years. However, many in the industry have suggested that develop-
`ment tirneshave begun to increase in the wake ofhigh-profile safety concerns for
`approved drugs such as Vioxx and Avandia. It may be too soon to observe much
`impact from increased regulatory stringency for drugs that have bee

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket