throbber
HEALTH ECONOMICS
`Health Econ. (2009)
`Published online in Wiley InterScience (www.interscience.wiley.com). DOI: 10.1002/hec.1454
`
`SPENDING ON NEW DRUG DEVELOPMENT1
`
`CHRISTOPHER PAUL ADAMSa, and VAN VU BRANTNERb
`aBureau of Economics, Federal Trade Commission, Washington, DC, USA
`bGlobal Consumer & Small Business Banking, Bank of America, Charlotte, NC, USA
`
`SUMMARY
`This paper replicates DiMasi et al. (J. Health Econ. 2003; 22: 151–185; Drug Inf. J. 2004; 38: 211–223) estimates of
`expenditure on new drug development using publicly available data. The paper estimates that average expenditure
`on drugs in human clinical trials is around $27m per year, with $17m per year on drugs in Phase I, $34m on drugs in
`Phase II and $27m per year on drugs in Phase III of the human clinical trials. The paper’s estimated expenditure on
`new drug development is somewhat greater than suggested by the survey results presented in DiMasi et al.
`(J. Health Econ. 2003; 22: 151–185; Drug Inf. J. 2004; 38: 211–223). The paper combines a 12-year panel of research
`and development expenditure for 183 publicly traded firms in the pharmaceutical industry with panel of drugs in
`human clinical trials for each firm over the same period. The paper estimates drug expenditure by estimating the
`relationship between research and development expenditure and the number of drugs in development for 1682
`company/years (183 firms multiplied by the number of years for which we have financial and drug development
`information). The paper also estimates expenditure on drugs in various therapeutic categories. Copyright r 2009
`John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
`
`Received 14 May 2007; Revised 24 November 2008; Accepted 5 January 2009
`
`KEY WORDS: pharmaceuticals; drug development
`
`1. INTRODUCTION
`
`DiMasi et al. (2003, 2004) estimate the cost of new drug development for all drugs and for drugs in
`certain therapeutic categories, respectively. The authors estimate the average cost of new drug
`development to be $802m per new drug. This number has become a central part of the policy debates on
`numerous issues regarding the pharmaceutical industry including the Medicare Prescription Drug Act,
`drug importation, generic entry and vaccine development. Drug companies argue the high cost of drug
`development justifies the high prices paid by governments,
`insurers and customers. Given the
`importance of the $802m number to the debate it is important to know whether it is correct and what it
`means.
`DiMasi et al. (2003) calculate the cost of new drug development with data from two sources. The
`authors survey 10 large pharmaceutical firms and ask those firms to report the expenditure in human
`clinical trials for 68 drugs chosen at random from the Tuft’s drug development database called the
`CSDD. The authors then use information on average success rates and successful durations from the
`CSDD data to calculate the cost of bringing a new drug to market. Recently, Light and Warburton
`(2005) point out numerous problems with DiMasi et al. (2003). In particular, because ‘cost data used
`
`*Correspondence to: Bureau of Economics, Federal Trade Commission, 601 New Jersey Avenue NW, Washington, DC 20580,
`USA. E-mail: cadams@ftc.gov
`1The authors are not aware of any potential conflicts that may bias their work. As far as the authors are aware, the study raises no
`ethical issues.
`
`Copyright r 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
`
`Petitioner Mylan Pharmaceuticals Inc. - Exhibit 1068 - Page 1
`
`

`
`C. P. ADAMS AND V. V. BRANTNER
`
`was proprietary and confidential, readers cannot know how each company collected its data, or what
`was counted as research costs, and no independent verification of the accuracy of the information is
`possible’ (p. 1031). This paper provides an independent verification of the survey cost data by using an
`alternative publicly available data source on research and development expenditure. Adams and
`Brantner (2006) verify the second part of DiMasi et al. (2003) paper by using publicly available data to
`estimate success rates and average successful durations.
`By comparing aggregate annual expenditure on research and development across firms and over time
`to the number of drugs in human clinical trials for each firm and each year, we can determine the
`‘marginal expenditure’ on an additional drug in development. If Drug Firm A spends an additional
`$50m in 1992 relative to 1991 but in 1992 Drug Firm A has two additional drugs in development we
`argue this provides an estimate of average annual expenditure by Drug Firm A, i.e. $25m per drug per
`year. Similarly, if Drug Firm B spends $100m more than Drug Firm A in 1992 but Drug Firm B has an
`additional four drugs in development in 1992, then we estimate drug expenditure to be $25m per drug
`per year. Note that this is an estimate of the correlation between expenditure and the number of drugs in
`development. We are not attempting to estimate the impact of an additional dollar of expenditure on
`the number of drugs in development or the impact of additional drug on the amount of expenditure.
`There are a number of advantages to this approach. First, we are using publicly available data so
`our results can be verified by other researchers. Second, we are using data from 183 publicly traded
`firms rather than 10 firms selected by the study’s authors. Our selection criteria is that the firms
`have research and development expenditure information in the CompuStat data base, be in the
`pharmaceutical industry (see Danzon et al., 2004) and have drugs in the Pharmaprojects data set
`(see Adams and Brantner, 2006). These firms range in size from 100 employees to almost 180 000
`employees with sales ranging from $2m annually to almost $45b annually. Third, we are using
`contemporaneous reports of research and development expenditure where the reports are scrutinized by
`both the market and the SEC. In their comment on DiMasi et al. (2003), Light and Warburton (2005)
`argue that
`
`considering the clear interest of pharmaceutical companies in higher (rather than lower) estimates of
`drug development costs, and sampled firms’ likely awareness of the intended use of the survey data, it
`is not unlikely that companies would deliberately and systematically overstate costs in their survey
`responses (p. 1031).
`
`We argue that such biases are less likely here given the large number of firms and the checks on the
`reports including audits.
`Of course there are also serious concerns about the approach we use here. First, the data are
`aggregate research and development expenditure. Those not only include expenditure on drugs in
`human clinical trials but also include development expenditure on drugs yet to reach trials. To identify
`the amount spent in human clinical trials we must infer the information from cross sectional and time-
`series variation in expenditure that is associated with variation in the number of drugs in development.
`Such variation may lead to spurious estimates. For example, if one firm specializes in anti-infective
`drugs and we compare the specialty firm’s expenditure on anti-infective drugs to that of a firm that has
`just one or two anti-infective drugs, we may estimate that expenditure on the extra drug as being small.
`This low estimate may be due savings from specialization rather than an accurate measure of the cost of
`adding another anti-infective drug.
`Second, we are estimating changes for the ‘marginal drug’, which may be more expensive than the
`average drug.2 The relationship between expenditure on the marginal drug and expenditure on the
`average drug depends on what assumption the reader is willing to make regarding how expenditure per
`
`2Thanks to Eric Durbin for pointing this out.
`
`Copyright r 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
`
`Health Econ. (2009)
`DOI: 10.1002/hec
`
`Petitioner Mylan Pharmaceuticals Inc. - Exhibit 1068 - Page 2
`
`

`
`SPENDING ON NEW DRUG DEVELOPMENT
`
`drug changes with the number of drugs. If expenditure per drug is constant then the marginal and the
`average are the same. On the other hand, if expenditure per drug is increasing with the number of drugs
`in development then marginal expenditure will be higher than average expenditure. A number of papers
`suggest that there may be economies of scale or scope in drug development (Cockburn and Henderson,
`1996, 2001; Danzon et al., 2004). If there are economies of scale then we would expect marginal
`expenditure to be less than average expenditure.3 Note that marginal expenditure may be a more useful
`measure for determining the incentive effects of policy changes.
`Third, we use Pharmaprojects’ definition of a ‘drug development project’ and assign the drug to the
`‘originator’. In general, this definition corresponds to a new patented molecular entity. In the main
`part of the analysis we drop drugs that are new formulations of existing drugs (i.e. an extended
`release version of an existing drug). The analysis does not account for the fact that the drug
`development project is part of a joint venture (and thus expenditure is spread across multiple firms) or is
`being developed by an altogether different firm (and our method is assigning the drug project to the
`wrong firm).4 Such mis-measurement may bias our estimates downward. It should be noted that our
`counts of drugs in the different phases are measuring the development associated with the originating
`firm.
`In order to have a number that is comparable to DiMasi et al.’s (2003) average expenditure over the
`sample period, we control for differences between firms and differences over time. We attempt to
`control for some cross-sectional variation by conditioning on net sales. If for example, larger firms
`spend more on drug development projects than smaller firms then net sales should control for this
`variation. Similarly, if firms are spending more on drug development projects at the end of the period
`than at the beginning then our controls for time will provide a better sense of the average expenditure
`per project during the period. Note that identification of spending per drugs is coming to some extent
`from the fact that larger firms have more drugs and that there are more drugs over time in the database.
`The controls attempt to separately identify the effect of having another drug in human clinical trials
`from the effect of being large or later in time.
`DiMasi et al. (2003) uses a similar approach to verify their own estimates. The authors use firm level
`R&D expenditure reported by PhRMA and estimate lagged expenditure on firm level counts of
`approved drugs. The authors estimate average expenditure per approved drug to be between $354m and
`$558m. These numbers are similar to their estimate of $403m using the survey data. Other researchers
`have simply divided aggregate R&D expenditure by the total number of approvals per year. The
`concern with these approaches is that less than one in four drugs in human clinical trials actually make it
`to the market and the process can take between 6 and 12 years with substantial variation across drugs
`(Adams and Brantner, 2003).
`The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 discusses the data used in this study and provides
`some background information on new drug development. Section 3 presents the results. Section 4
`concludes.
`
`2. DATA AND BACKGROUND
`
`This paper combines data from two data sources. Information on each firm’s research and development
`expenditure comes from the Standard Poor’s CompuStat Industrial file and Global Vantage Industrial
`Commercial file used by Danzon et al. (2004).5 This data set provides financial information on publicly
`traded drug companies including net sales, employment and expenditure on research and development.
`
`3To the extent one is concerned that large firms may have lower (or higher) expenditure per drug than smaller firms, some of this
`variation is accounted for in the analysis through conditioning on sales revenue.
`4Danzon et al. (2005) analyze joint ventures.
`5All monetary values are in 1999 dollars using the domestic manufacturing Producer Price Index.
`
`Copyright r 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
`
`Health Econ. (2009)
`DOI: 10.1002/hec
`
`Petitioner Mylan Pharmaceuticals Inc. - Exhibit 1068 - Page 3
`
`

`
`C. P. ADAMS AND V. V. BRANTNER
`
`Table I. Firm/year summary statistics
`
`Variable
`
`Number of drugs
`R&D expenditure ($m)
`Net sales ($m)
`Employees (’000)
`
`Obs
`
`2245
`1682
`1701
`1537
`
`Mean
`
`4
`264
`2355
`11
`
`Median
`
`Std. Dev.
`
`2
`37
`110
`1
`
`6
`551
`5438
`25
`
`Max
`
`45
`4678
`44 611
`179
`
`Information on drugs in development comes from a Pharmaprojects data set used by Adams and
`Brantner (2006) and Abrantes-Metz et al. (2005). This data set uses public information to track drugs
`through the development process, providing information on the length of time in different phase as well
`as when and if drugs completed a development phase. The two data sets overlap for the years
`1989–2001. The data sets are matched using the name of the pharmaceutical firm.6 Pharmaprojects
`updates its information on the firms developing each drug after a merger, so we used text searches of the
`database and searches of a related data set called the Manufacturing Index to determine the ownership
`of drugs over time.7
`According to Danzon et al. (2004) there are 383 firms in their original data. Once we match these
`firms to firms in the Pharmaprojects data we are left with 183 firms. It is not clear exactly why there are
`firms that do not match. The two data sets do not exactly overlap in time and that may explain some of
`it. Another explanation is that the Pharmaprojects does not capture name changes or mergers among
`smaller firms (see footnote 7). Table I presents some basic summary statistics for this sample of firm/
`year combinations. Table I shows there are an average of four drugs in development for each firm for
`each year 1989–2001. Note this measure is not a very good measure of the stock of drugs in development
`because we only observe drugs entering one of the stages of human clinical trials after 1989. In the
`average firm/year $264m is spent on research and development, $2355m is made in sales and there are
`11 000 employees. Note that medians are substantially lower than the means suggesting that the
`distributions are all skewed toward zero.
`Figures 1–3 present the distribution of the number of drugs in human clinical trials per firm/year, the
`amount of R&D expenditure per firm/year, and a scatter plot of the two, respectively. The first two
`figures show that the distributions of drugs and expenditures are heavily skewed to zero. The third
`figure seems to show a positive correlation between the amount of R&D expenditure per firm per year
`and the number of drugs in development per firm per year.
`Figure 4 presents a summary of the research and development process for new drugs. The first
`stage of drug discovery is commonly called ‘preclinical development’. In this stage pharmaceutical
`firms analyze thousands of drugs to determine whether one may have an affect on a disease or
`condition. As candidates are discovered these drugs are tested on animals to determine whether the
`drug may be safe and effective in human beings. It is estimated that drugs spend over 4 years in
`preclinical testing. DiMasi et al. (2003) do not have direct survey information on preclinical expenditure
`because pharmaceutical firms do not track preclinical expenditure by particular drug candidates.
`Given this and given that the Pharmaprojects data are based on public information and are not very
`reliable regarding drugs in preclinical development, we do not estimate expenditure on preclinical
`development.
`After preclinical development the sponsoring firm applies for an investigation new drug application
`(IND) with the FDA in order to test the candidate in humans.8 There are three steps to human clinical
`
`6This matching was done by hand in order for it to be as accurate as possible.
`7This was done for all mergers involving firms in the Forbes’ top 20 of pharmaceutical industry over the period as well as any other
`major mergers in the pharmaceutical industry.
`8If the firm wants to eventually market the drug in the US the firm must apply for an IND prior to undertaking human trials. That
`said, there are exceptions.
`
`Copyright r 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
`
`Health Econ. (2009)
`DOI: 10.1002/hec
`
`Petitioner Mylan Pharmaceuticals Inc. - Exhibit 1068 - Page 4
`
`

`
`SPENDING ON NEW DRUG DEVELOPMENT
`
`Figure 1. Drugs in development
`
`Figure 2. Annual R&D expenditure
`
`trials. In Phase I, the drug is tested for safety on a small group (e.g. 20) of healthy volunteers. Phase II
`tests concentrate on safety but the test is on a larger group of patients with the condition (e.g. 200).
`Phase III are the large efficacy trials with upwards of 3,000 patients participating. Once the trials are
`completed the results of all three stages are presented to the FDA in the form of a new drug application
`(NDA).
`Table II presents some basic summary statistics on the drugs owned by the firms in the sample. The
`first set of three rows show the mean length in months of successful durations. The second set of three
`
`Copyright r 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
`
`Health Econ. (2009)
`DOI: 10.1002/hec
`
`Petitioner Mylan Pharmaceuticals Inc. - Exhibit 1068 - Page 5
`
`

`
`C. P. ADAMS AND V. V. BRANTNER
`
`Figure 3. R&D expenditure by drugs in development
`
`Figure 4. CDER chart of the development process
`
`Table II. Summary statistics for drugs
`
`Duration (months)
`Phase I
`Phase II
`Phase III
`Success (frequency)
`Phase I
`Phase II
`Phase III
`
`Obs
`
`235
`144
`130
`
`314
`302
`184
`
`Mean
`
`16.58
`30.65
`27.15
`
`0.75
`0.48
`0.71
`
`Copyright r 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
`
`Health Econ. (2009)
`DOI: 10.1002/hec
`
`Petitioner Mylan Pharmaceuticals Inc. - Exhibit 1068 - Page 6
`
`

`
`SPENDING ON NEW DRUG DEVELOPMENT
`
`rows shows the frequency with which drugs successfully complete the phase. The table shows that these
`drugs seem to be fairly representative (see Adams and Brantner, 2006; DiMasi et al., 2003). Successful
`durations vary by a month or two and success rates vary by a few percentage points of those reported in
`Adams and Brantner (2006).
`
`3.1. Mean expenditure estimates
`
`3. RESULTS
`
`Table III presents regression results for the amount of research and development expenditure on the
`number of drugs in human clinical trials. There are six regressions reported in the table. First are the
`basic regressions on the number of drugs in human clinical trials then on the number of drugs in each of
`the three phases of development. These regressions are then repeated adding measures of time and firm
`characteristics. All results report robust standard errors clustering on firm name. The number of drugs
`is the number of drugs in development for each firm/year combination. Note that ‘new formulations’ of
`existing drugs are not included in the count variable.9 This is done in order to make the estimates closer
`to DiMasi et al. (2003) estimate for new molecular entities.10 The variable time is simply the number of
`years from 1988. The variable ‘sales’ is the amount of net sales for each firm/year. The time and sales
`variables allow the analysis to capture changes in expenditure over the time period and across firms,
`where ‘sales’ is probably best thought of a measure of firm size.
`Table III shows that average expenditure per drug in human clinical trials is between $74m and $27m
`per year.11 Once we include controls for time and firm characteristics, the results suggest that the
`average expenditure on drugs across all three phases of development is approximately $27m per year.
`This estimate is quite precise and is statistically different from zero at traditional levels. If sales are not
`accounted for then Phase I expenditure is estimated to be $81m per year, $68m for drugs in Phase II and
`$77m for drugs in Phase III. Once time and sales are accounted for, these estimates fall to $16m, $34m
`and $27m respectively.12 The Phase II and III expenditures are estimated precisely and are statistically
`different from zero. The Phase I estimate is less precisely estimated and 0 lies within the traditional
`confidence interval.
`How do these results compare to the estimates of expenditure in DiMasi et al. (2003)? We estimate
`the average annual expenditure on drugs in all three phases of human clinical trials is $27m. If we take
`DiMasi et al. (2003) estimates of expenditure for each phase of $15m, $24m and $86m for Phases I, II
`and III, respectively, and weight them proportionally to the time spent in development and the
`probability of being in each of the phases then we have the appropriate comparison.13 This
`transformation gives an estimate of annual expenditure of $21m.14 Our estimate is higher than this
`transformed estimate from DiMasi et al. (2003) although $21m lies within the 95% confidence
`interval.15 To compare the expenditure by phase it is necessary to do another transformation. The
`numbers presented in DiMasi et al. (2003) are for the average drug over the length of the phase, while
`
`9A new formulation may, for example, be an extended release version of an existing approved drug.
`10Thanks to an anonymous referee for this suggestion. The estimates of expenditure per drug including formulations are lower
`than the estimates presented here. The last section suggests that this occurs because expenditure on new formulations is
`substantially lower than for other drugs.
`11Most of the decrease seems to come from including the sales variable.
`12Note that these results are most properly thought of as correlations between the number of drugs and the amount of expenditure.
`There has been no effort made to account for endogeniety in the joint decisions to increase expenditure and take more drugs into
`clinical trials.
`13From DiMasi et al. (2003) the average durations are 12, 26 and 34 months, respectively.
`14The average expenditure is (12*1510.71*26*2410.31*34*86)/(12126134) 5 (18014431906)/72 5 21.
`15$21m does not lie within the 90% confidence interval. Although, this does not account for sampling error with the original
`DiMasi et al. (2003) estimate.
`
`Copyright r 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
`
`Health Econ. (2009)
`DOI: 10.1002/hec
`
`Petitioner Mylan Pharmaceuticals Inc. - Exhibit 1068 - Page 7
`
`

`
`C. P. ADAMS AND V. V. BRANTNER
`
`Table III. R&D expenses OLS (robust standard errors)
`
`1
`74.31
`(5.87)
`
`All phases
`
`Phase I
`
`Phase II
`
`Phase III
`
`2
`
`80.72
`(18.61)
`68.01
`(12.72)
`76.94
`(23.90)
`
`Time
`
`Time2
`
`Sales
`
`Constant
`
`23.75
`(5.91)
`2.09
`(0.46)
`0.07
`(0.01)
`147.19
`147.97
`22.64
`21.49
`19.87
`(20.88)
`(21.00)
`(31.04)
`(36.18)
`(17.20)
`Observations
`1682
`1682
`1682
`1682
`1682
`R2
`0.59
`0.59
`0.60
`0.60
`0.89
`Standard errors are clustered on firm names. Is statisically different from 0 at 1% level and is at 5% level.
`
`5
`26.85
`(3.44)
`
`3
`74.86
`(5.91)
`
`62.34
`(10.88)
`4.32
`(0.83)
`
`4
`
`78.05
`(18.61)
`69.07
`(12.67)
`80.08
`(24.07)
`62.27
`(13.08)
`4.31
`(0.97)
`
`6
`
`16.78
`(10.35)
`33.59
`(6.80)
`26.78
`(11.08)
`25.31
`(6.76)
`2.19
`(0.53)
`0.07
`(0.01)
`23.16
`(17.69)
`1682
`0.89
`
`we have estimated expenditure for 1 year. If we use the phase durations presented in Table II we can
`estimate expenditure for the whole phase. This procedure gives 1.38 17m 5 $24m for Phase I, which is
`more than DiMasi et al. (2003) estimate of $15m for Phase I. For Phase II the same method produces an
`estimate of $86m, which is much higher than the DiMasi et al. (2003) estimate of $24m. Finally, for
`Phase III this method gives an estimate of $61m, which is less than the DiMasi et al. (2003) estimate of
`$86m. For Phases I and III, the DiMasi et al. (2003) estimates lie within the 95% confidence interval
`around our estimates. However, there is no overlap between the confidence interval around the DiMasi
`et al. (2003) estimate of Phase II expenditure and the confidence interval around our estimate.
`It is not clear what explains such a large discrepancy between our estimate of Phase II expenditure
`and DiMasi et al. (2003) estimate. One possibility and a more general concern is that our method may
`be misallocating expenditure to drugs in different stages of development. This may occur for two
`reasons. First, we assume that if a drug moves into a new phase in a particular year then the drug has
`been in that phase for the whole year. Still, given the expected difference in Phases II and III expenditure
`this assumption is more likely to lead to an underestimate of Phase III expenditure than an overestimate
`of Phase II expenditure. Second, the relationship between financial years and the years assigned in the
`data. Again, this may reduce the accuracy of the estimates but it is unlikely to bias the estimates.
`Another possibility is that there is under reporting of drugs in human clinical trials particularly in the
`earlier phases.16
`As other work has shown, expenditure on research and development is increasing at a substantial
`rate. In fact, here we have it increasing at a parabolic rate although this is due to the particular
`functional form that is used in the estimation. The results also show that there is a strong relationship
`between sales and research and development expenditure with every $1 in sales associated with an extra
`$0.07 in R&D expenditure. Note also, adding sales to the regression substantially improves the model’s
`ability to explain the data. The constant in this estimation cannot really be interpreted as we do not have
`a measure of the stock of drugs in development as of 1989. We are only able to observe new
`development starts in 1989 and later.
`The baseline regression measures the average expenditure on new drugs by firm and year. It does not
`account for whether that average may be driven up by the large increase in R&D expenditure observed
`
`16It is not clear exactly how such under reporting would bias the results and in what direction.
`
`Copyright r 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
`
`Health Econ. (2009)
`DOI: 10.1002/hec
`
`Petitioner Mylan Pharmaceuticals Inc. - Exhibit 1068 - Page 8
`
`

`
`SPENDING ON NEW DRUG DEVELOPMENT
`
`during the period or by large expenditures by the larger pharmaceutical firms. Latter regressions add a
`parabolic time trend and a parameter (‘sales’) to capture variation across firms. The time trend estimates
`capture the large increase in expenditure that occurred during the period. The sales coefficient suggests
`that large firms, at least large firm/years, are associated with large expenditures per drug.17 This
`variation across firms is also captured to some extent via the quantile regression analysis presented in
`the next section.18 This analysis suggests larger firms spend more on clinical trials.
`Note that the measured positive relationship between sales and expenditure may not be causal.
`Larger pharmaceutical firms may have different R&D strategies than smaller firms. For example, Big
`Pharma may run substantially more trials over different
`treatments, comparison groups, and
`populations compared with smaller firms. Such trials may put the firm in a better position to sell the
`drug internationally and in multiple domestic markets for different indications. Note also that these
`numbers do not measure expenditure by smaller non-publicly traded firms such as those funded by
`venture capital firms.
`
`3.2. Quartile expenditure estimates
`
`Table IV presents results from the 25, 50 and 75% quartile regressions. Comparing these results to the
`results from columns 5 and 6 in Table III we see that expenditure per drug per year is substantially less
`at the lower quartiles. At the bottom quartile, expenditure per new drug in development is around $9m
`per year, with $15m at the median and $18m at the top quartile. All these numbers are estimated fairly
`precisely. These numbers compare to $27m per year for the mean. Similarly, estimated expenditures per
`phase of development are substantially lower at the 25, 50 and 75% quartiles relative to the mean. The
`results suggest that the distribution of expenditure on drug development is quite skewed. These results
`suggest that a number of firms spend very large sums on drug development.
`As before, we can transform our median estimates to compare with the median estimates presented in
`DiMasi et al. (2003). This procedure gives 1.38 14.60 5 $20m for Phase I, which is more than DiMasi
`et al. (2003) estimate of $14m for Phase I. For Phase II the same method produces an estimate of $36m,
`which is much higher than the DiMasi et al. (2003) estimate of $17m. Finally, for Phase III this method
`gives an estimate of $30m, which is much less than the DiMasi et al. (2003) estimate of $62m.
`
`3.3. Implications for cost estimates
`
`If we use the mean estimates for expenditure on drugs in development in place of the survey estimates
`used by DiMasi et al. (2003) we can recalculate the over all ‘cost of drug development’ or more
`accurately the net revenue needed to make investment in drug development profitable. Doing this
`calculation using the same durations and success rates as reported in Adams and Brantner (2006) we
`estimate new drug development cost to be $1214m, which is much higher than the original estimate of
`$802m or even the Adams and Brantner (2006) estimate of $867m. These high estimates may be due to
`measurement of expenditure on the marginal drug rather than the average drug.19 However, such an
`estimate may be more useful to policy makers as it is more likely to measure the impact of changes in
`
`17The baseline analysis is measured at the firm/year level. This means that we are measuring the expenditure of the average firm/
`year on a drug rather than the expenditure on the average drug. If the average firm/year is large then our measure may be high
`because large firms happen to spend more on drugs. By adding a coefficient for firm size the measure can be adjusted to account
`for the variation in expenditure across firms. Note however, that if the average drug is developed in a large firm then these results
`may need to be adjusted either by adding back in the sales coefficient multiplied by the sales of the firm, which produces the
`average drug or by looking at the quartile estimates in the next section.
`18Note that the coefficient estimate on sales is larger for the 75% quartile compared with the 50% quartile and the 25% quartile.
`That is, for drugs with larger expenditures there is a stronger relationship between the size of the firm and the size of the
`expenditures.
`19Note also that these estimates are based on the very high Phase II expenditure estimates.
`
`Copyright r 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
`
`Health Econ. (2009)
`DOI: 10.1002/hec
`
`Petitioner Mylan Pharmaceuticals Inc. - Exhibit 1068 - Page 9
`
`

`
`C. P. ADAMS AND V. V. BRANTNER
`
`Table IV. R&D expenses quantiles (standard errors)
`
`25%
`
`50%
`
`50%
`14.60
`(0.19)
`
`75%
`18.68
`(0.15)
`
`75%
`
`18.31
`(0.44)
`22.59
`(0.39)
`15.45
`(0.50)
`4.09
`(0.85)
`0.36
`(0.06)
`0.10
`(0.00)
`13.81
`(2.69)
`1682
`0.80
`
`25%
`8.88
`(0.12)
`
`All phases
`
`Phase I
`
`Phase II
`
`Phase III
`
`Time
`
`Time2
`
`Sales
`
`Constant
`
`7.65
`18.35
`(0.42)
`(0.55)
`10.73
`13.98
`(0.36)
`(0.46)
`7.84
`13.05
`(0.44)
`(0.58)
`2.48
`2.56
`3.58
`3.52
`4.46
`(0.69)
`(0.80)
`(1.01)
`(1.00)
`(0.80)
`0.19
`0.19
`0.29
`0.29
`0.39
`(0.05)
`(0.05)
`(0.07)
`(0.07)
`(0.05)
`0.07
`0.07
`0.08
`0.08
`0.10
`(0.00)
`(0.00)
`(0.00)
`(0.00)
`(0.00)
`6.82
`6.54
`14.85
`2.15
`2.16
`(2.27)
`(2.61)
`(3.31)
`(3.26)
`(2.52)
`1682
`1682
`1682
`1682
`1682
`Observations
`Pseudo R2
`0.60
`0.60
`0.70
`0.70
`0.80
`Standard errors are in parenthesis. Refers to statistical significance from 0 at the 1% level, at the 5% level.
`
`policy on the development of new drugs. We could interpret these estimates as stating a firm would need
`expected net revenue of over $1 billion to develop one more drug for the market.20
`
`3.4. Expenditure by therapy
`
`DiMasi et al. (2004) presents estimates of drug development costs for a small number of major
`therapies. In attempt to replicate this work, Table V presents results similar to those presented in
`Table III but where the drug counts are by major therapeutic category. Table V presents the marginal
`cost of a drug by major therapy grouping. This number is estimated by counting the number of drugs in
`human clinical trials for each of the major categories presented.21 Note, that we would not expect these
`numbers to be negative.22 The table shows cardiovascular, dermatological, genitourinary, anticancer
`and neurological drugs all have more expenditure per drug in human clinical trials than the average
`drug. Note, however, only genitourinary drugs are estimated to be statistically different from the
`average at traditional levels. New formulations of existing drugs have substantially smaller expenditure
`in human clinical trials than the average drug. In fact, expenditure on new formulation is not estimated
`to be statistically different from zero, but is statistically different from the average. The reader may be
`surprised that biotech drugs are estimated to have less than average expenditure (although the estimate
`i

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket