throbber
Drivers of peak sales for pharmaceutical brands - Springer
`
`http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s11129-010-9089-5/fulltext.html
`
`Quantitative Marketing and Economics
`QME
`© The Author(s) 2010
`10.1007/s11129-010-9089-5
`
`Marc Fischer 1 , Peter S. H. Leeflang 2, 3 and Peter C. Verhoef 2
`
`(1)
`(2)
`(3)
`
`Business and Economics, University of Passau, Innstr. 27, 94032 Passau, Germany
`Economics and Business, University of Groningen, P.O. BOX 800, 9700 AV Groningen, Netherlands
`LUISS Guido Carli, Rome, Italy
`
`Marc Fischer (Corresponding author)
`Email: marc.fischer@uni-passau.de
`
`Peter S. H. Leeflang
`Email: P.S.H.Leeflang@rug.nl
`
`Peter C. Verhoef
`Email: p.c.verhoef@rug.nl
`
`Received: 20 January 2009
`Accepted: 28 July 2010
`Published online: 13 August 2010
`
`Abstract
`
`Peak sales are an important metric in the pharmaceutical industry. Specifically, managers are focused on the height-of-peak-sales and the
`time required achieving peak sales. We analyze how order of entry and quality affect the level of peak sales and the time-to-peak-sales of
`pharmaceutical brands. We develop a growth model that includes these two variables as well as control variables for own and
`competitive marketing activities. We find that early entrants achieve peak sales later, and they have higher peak-sales levels.
`High-quality brands achieve peak sales earlier, and their peak-sales levels are higher. In addition, quality has a moderating effect on the
`order of entry effect on time-to-peak-sales. Our results indicate that late entrants have longer expected time-to-peak-sales when they
`introduce a brand with high quality.
`
`Keywords Peak-sales metrics – Brand growth – Econometric models – Market entry – Pharmaceutical marketing
`
`JEL Classification C23 – C51 – L65 – M31
`
`1 Introduction
`
`New products play a very important role in the pharmaceutical industry (Leenders and Wierenga 2008; Stremersch and van Dyck 2009).
`Pharmaceutical firms constantly introduce new drugs, and for these new drugs, peak sales represent an important metric, frequently used
`by investors to assess pharmaceutical firms’ value (Obeid and Vine 2005; Suresh et al. 2006).
`
`Peak sales can be characterized along two dimensions: the height-of-peak-sales and the time-to-peak-sales. Both metrics are closely
`related to new product performance such as cumulative sales. Intuitively, a brand with a higher level of peak sales is likely to have higher
`average sales over its life cycle. As a result, cumulative sales are also higher. Similarly, a brand with longer time-to-peak-sales enjoys a
`longer period of growth that contributes to accumulate sales and achieve a higher level of peak sales. Consequently, cumulative sales are
`again higher.
`
`There are, however, exceptions to these rules. For example, a high level of peak sales may be achieved very fast. Although, we cannot
`rule out such a case theoretically, we do not believe it occurs often in reality because of restrictions to growth. Note that the growth rate
`
`1 of 30
`
`5/21/2015 6:16 PM
`
`ARGENTUM Exhibit 1189
`Argentum Pharmaceuticals LLC v. Research Corporation Technologies, Inc.
`IPR2016-00204
`
`00001
`
`

`
`Drivers of peak sales for pharmaceutical brands - Springer
`
`http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s11129-010-9089-5/fulltext.html
`
`needs to double if the same level of peak sales is to be achieved in half of the time. Firms can handle faster growth only up to a certain
`level due to supply and resource restrictions. In Appendix A, we also demonstrate that faster growth implies a higher variance of sales
`and therefore higher cash-flow volatility which is not desirable (Srivastava et al. 1998). Hence, even if demand might allow for a shorter
`time-to-peak sales, there are limits to growth from the supply side. The broad sample of new drugs that forms the basis of our empirical
`study supports our view. Time-to-peak-sales enhances height-of-peak sales and both peak-sales metrics increase cumulative brand sales.
`Together the two metrics explain more than 96% of observed variance in cumulative brand sales.
`
`Time-to-peak-sales and height-of-peak-sales provide two important yardsticks that are easy to evaluate and predict even before launch.
`Assume management wants to assess the sales potential of a new product two years prior to launch. Cumulative sales may be obtained
`from the life cycle curve. Predicting the lifetime and sales for all periods, however, requires much more information than predicting only
`two peak-sales metrics. It is much easier to reach a consensus estimate for time-to-peak-sales and height-of-peak-sales. For
`pharmaceuticals, as an example, management can triangle information on the population size, the incidence of a disease and the
`reachable market share for the new drug to obtain an estimate for the height-of-peak-sales. Management would certainly use information
`on competitive entries, order of entry, marketing investment, etc. to predict the peak-sales metrics. Our empirical analysis provides
`important insights into the relevance of these variables for peak sales. Importantly, the analysis also suggests that those variables do not
`provide explanatory power for cumulative sales beyond the two peak-sales metrics. Hence, peak-sales metrics cannot simply be
`substituted by other predictors.
`
`It is therefore not surprising that peak-sales metrics are widely adopted in practice, especially within the pharmaceutical industry. For
`example, Salix Pharmaceuticals reportedly has tumbled because its IBD franchise will “only achieve peak sales of $ 99 million, lower
`than its previous estimate of $ 135 million because of the Dec. 28 approval of three generic balsalazide (Colazal) formulations by the
`Food and Drug Administration” (Trading Markets.Com 2007). The importance of peak-sales metrics prompts business intelligence
`agencies such as IMS or Datamonitor to predict the peak sales of newly introduced drugs (e.g., Datamonitor 2007). Not only are the
`metrics important in practice (Obeid and Vine 2005), but scholars also acknowledge their relevance. For example, Bauer and Fischer
`(2000) and Schmid and Smith (2002) demonstrate that time-to- and height-of-peak-sales differ across brands introduced into different
`drug categories and countries due to factors such as order of entry.
`
`In the marketing literature, there has been extensive attention to the role of order of entry and quality with regard to (new product)
`performance (Gielens and Dekimpe 2001; Kalyanaram and Urban 1992; Kalyanaraman and Wittink 1994; Robinson and Fornell 1985;
`Shankar et al. 1998). An important debate addresses the question whether first movers really have a competitive advantage as is often
`attributed to them (Golder and Tellis 1993; Kornelis et al. 2008; Zhang and Narasimhan 2000). Quite in contrast, recently Tellis and
`Johnson (2007) argue that delivering superior quality is considered as the most important driver of new product success. Hence, we
`assess the role of order of entry and quality for the market performance of a new drug in terms of peak sales.
`
`The main objective of this study is to determine the drivers of height-of peak-sales and time-to-peak-sales in the pharmaceutical industry.
`Through this study we contribute to the literature on new products and brand life cycles (Hauser et al. 2006), as this is the first study to
`investigate drivers of time-to- and height-of-peak-sales. We show that some drivers differentially impact height-of-peak-sales and
`time-to-peak-sales. For example, marketing expenditures increase the level of peak sales, while they decrease the time-to-peak-sales. We
`aim to contribute to the literature on drivers of new product performance with a further investigation on the relative roles of order of
`entry, quality, and marketing efforts (see Tellis and Johnson 2007). Importantly, our results suggest that quality has by far the strongest
`positive effect on height-of-peak-sales, while it reduces the time-to-peak-sales. Finally, by executing this study in the pharmaceutical
`industry we also contribute to existing knowledge on pharmaceutical marketing (e.g. Kremer et al. 2008; Stremersch and van Dyck
`2009).
`
`The article is organized as follows: In the next section, we review the literature on drug life cycles and provide explanations why peak
`sales is a quite common phenomenon in the evolution of drug sales. Subsequently, we discuss potential drivers of time-to- and height-
`of-peak-sales and how they might affect the two metrics. We develop a model to measure the effects, then describe data from the
`pharmaceutical industry and discuss estimation issues. We follow up with a discussion of the empirical results. We continue with a cross-
`sectional analysis of new product performance to substantiate the relevance of the suggested metrics. In the final section, we conclude
`with research implications, limitations, and suggestions for further research.
`
`2 Drug life cycles and peak sales
`
`2 of 30
`
`5/21/2015 6:16 PM
`
`00002
`
`

`
`Drivers of peak sales for pharmaceutical brands - Springer
`
`http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s11129-010-9089-5/fulltext.html
`
`2.1 Life cycle research
`
`Studying the length and the shape of brand life cycles has a long history, including studies by Bauer and Fischer (2000), Brockhoff
`(1967), and Polli and Cook (1969). Research on specific metrics at the brand level in the development of the brand life cycle is scarce.
`Height-of-peak-sales and time-to-peak-sales have not been studied so far. Remarkably, studying the diffusion of article citations in
`Econometrica and the Journal of Econometrics, Fok and Franses (2007) model the time-to-peak citations and peak-citations of an article.
`Hence, though studied in a different context, there is academic attention for peak metrics in the econometric diffusion literature. We
`believe it is important to study such metrics in a new product context as well, as we will show that both these metrics are highly relevant
`for practice and they both are the most important determinants of cumulative brand sales.
`
`Research at the product level has, however, investigated other specific metrics, as overviewed in Table 1. Several studies consider
`time-to-takeoff and subsequent growth of consumer durables (i.e., VCRs, televisions), as well as their drivers (Agarwal and Bayus 2002;
`Neelameghan and Chintagunta 2004; Golder and Tellis 1997; Stremersch and Tellis 2004; Tellis et al. 2003). Bayus (1998) specifically
`analyzes product lifetime as an important metric. Although these studies provide insights into which factors (i.e., economic, cultural)
`influence time-to-takeoff at the product level by country, they do not clarify the drivers at the brand level.
`
`3 of 30
`
`5/21/2015 6:16 PM
`
`00003
`
`

`
`Drivers of peak sales for pharmaceutical brands - Springer
`
`http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s11129-010-9089-5/fulltext.html
`
`Table 1
`Overview of prior studies investigating specific metrics over a brand’s/product’s life cycle
`
`Study
`
`Metrics
`
`Data
`
`Antecedents
`
`Major findings
`
`Golder and
`Tellis (1997)
`
`Time-to-takeoff
`
`Aggregated sales by category
`in the U.S.
`
`Price, year of introduction, market
`penetration
`
`Bayus (1998)
`
`Product lifetime
`
`Aggregated sales at various
`product market levels in the
`U.S. PC industry
`
`Product introduction year, firm entry
`year, technology substitution
`
`- Average time-to-takeoff is six years.
`
`- At takeoff, price is 63% of
`introductory price, and penetration is
`1.7%.
`
`- Time-to-takeoff decreases after
`World War II.
`
`- Product life cycles are not shrinking
`over time.
`
`- Observed acceleration in life cycles
`is a result of technology substitution.
`
`- Time-to-takeoff varies substantially
`across European countries.
`
`Tellis et al.
`(2003)
`
`Time-to-takeoff
`
`Aggregated sales by category
`for different European
`countries
`
`Economic and cultural variables
`
`- Culture partially explains country
`differences.
`
`Agarwal and
`Bayus (2002)
`
`Time-to-takeoff
`
`Aggregated sales by category
`in the U.S.
`
`Price, new firm entry, commercialization
`year
`
`Stremersch
`and Tellis
`(2004)
`
`Rate of growth,
`duration of growth
`
`Aggregated sales by category
`for different European
`countries
`
`Economic and cultural variables
`
`Golder and
`Tellis (2004)
`
`Time-to-takeoff,
`slowdown, duration
`of growth
`
`Aggregated sales by category
`in the U.S.
`
`Price, economic growth, type of product,
`market penetration
`
`This Study
`
`Time-to-peak-sales,
`height-of-peak-sales
`
`Brand sales of 45
`pharmaceutical brands in
`France, Germany, Italy, and
`UK
`
`Own marketing expenditures,
`competitive marketing expenditures,
`order-of-entry, quality, number of
`competitors
`
`2.2 Brand life cycles in drugs
`
`- Advantages for waterfall strategy for
`international product introduction.
`
`- Takeoff in new firm entry leads to
`sales takeoff.
`
`- Firm entry dominates other drivers of
`time-to-takeoff.
`
`- Growth metrics vary substantially
`across European countries.
`
`- Economic factors primarily explain
`country differences.
`
`- Slowdown occurs when sales
`declines by about 15%.
`
`- Probability of slowdown is higher
`when economic growth is slower, price
`reductions are smaller, and penetration
`is higher.
`
`- Leisure-enhancing products tend to
`have higher growth rates and shorter
`growth stages.
`
`- Order of entry reduces time-to-
`peak-sales and height-of-peak-sales.
`
`- Quality reduces time-to-peak-sales
`and increases height-of peak sales.
`
`- A higher quality reduces the negative
`effect of order of entry on time-to-
`peak-sales.
`
`4 of 30
`
`5/21/2015 6:16 PM
`
`00004
`
`

`
`Drivers of peak sales for pharmaceutical brands - Springer
`
`http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s11129-010-9089-5/fulltext.html
`
`The development of demand for a new drug derives from both adoptions and repeats. For many drugs, the evolution of sales shows a
`peak. In Fig. 1, we depict the sales development of different brands in the French calcium channel blockers market. On the X-axis, we
`display the launch years of new drugs, and on the Y-axis, we provide annual sales for three entrants in this market. The figure clearly
`shows the occurrence of sales peaks. For example, the second entrant reaches its peak in 1988 with a sales level of approximately 200
`million daily dosages.
`
`Fig. 1
`Illustration of peak sales in the French market for calcium channel blockers
`
`The theories of adoption and imitation (Bass 1969) and informational cascades (Golder and Tellis 2004) explain why brand sales follows
`a life cycle. However, they are usually associated with the product level and first-time adoptions. Brand sales are, in addition, composed
`of repeat purchases, and they are subject to competition (Hahn et al. 1994).
`
`Although some authors have questioned the transfer of the product life cycle concept to brands (Dhalla and Yuspeh 1976), brand life
`cycles have been reported quite frequently. The broadest evidence for brand life cycles is available for pharmaceuticals. Bauer and
`Fischer (2000), Corstjens et al. (2005), Cox (1967), Grabowski and Vernon (1990), Hahn et al. (1994), Lilien et al. (1981), Rao and
`Masataka (1988), and Simon (1979) all find strong evidence for the existence of a drug life cycle. In total, these researchers document
`the life cycles for more than 500 newly introduced drugs.
`
`There are potentially several reasons why especially pharmaceuticals exhibit a peak in their sales trajectory. First, diffusion dynamics
`seem to be dominant for the evolution of (prescription) drug sales. Although refills have a large share in total drug sales, sales dynamics
`are predominantly driven by first-time prescriptions. This is simply due to the fact that physicians are reluctant to change a drug (i.e. the
`first-time prescription) once it has been found to work for a patient, even in response to heavy marketing initiatives by competitor
`brands. As a result, researchers have adopted diffusion approaches to model drug sales with repeats where repeat rates are assumed
`constant (e.g., Hahn et al. 1994; Shankar et al. 1998). Second, pharmaceutical companies concentrate the bulk of their marketing efforts
`(i.e., detailing) on the first two years after launch, which causes an immediate strong increase in prescriptions but results in slower sales
`growth or even decline in later years when marketing support is only limited (Osinga et al. 2010). Third, by definition there is a limit in
`users of a drug as it is only relevant for patients with a specific treatment for a disease. Fourth, the entry of new competitors may inhibit
`sales growth to continue. These competitors may be other innovative drugs within the same or new categories, or generics after the
`patent has expired.
`
`One might argue that instead of studying time-to- and height-of-peak-sales, one should study the time-to-takeoff metric (e.g. Tellis et al.
`2003). As noted, this metric has been studied at the category level but not at the brand level. So far, there is no empirical evidence in the
`literature that this phenomenon occurs at the brand level, as well. We explored the available brand time-series but did not find evidence
`for a sales-takeoff phenomenon. Hence, beyond our substantive arguments there are also empirical arguments to study peak-sales
`metrics.
`
`5 of 30
`
`5/21/2015 6:16 PM
`
`00005
`
`

`
`Drivers of peak sales for pharmaceutical brands - Springer
`
`http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s11129-010-9089-5/fulltext.html
`
`3 Variables affecting peak sales of pharmaceutical brands
`
`3.1 Potential peak-sales drivers
`
`In this study, we focus on the impact of order of entry and quality on (1) the time-to-peak-sales and (2) the height-of-peak-sales. We
`control for the effect of other, potentially relevant variables. Specifically, we consider own and competitive marketing support, the
`number of competitive entries into the market, the price of the drug, and marketing expenditures by co-marketing partners as control
`variables in the proposed brand sales model.
`
`We define a pharmaceutical brand as a new chemical entity (NCE) marketed by a company in a specific country. Typically, innovative
`drugs enjoy patent protection for several years after launch. The competitive situation changes dramatically for an innovative drug when
`its patent expires and cheaper generic competitors rush into the market. In addition, innovative brands may be attacked by brands from
`other categories that offer alternative forms of drug treatment (technological substitution). Given that our data come from two categories
`that belong to the most innovative categories without generic price competition in our observation period, we focus on effects from
`competition among innovative prescription drugs within a category.
`
`The sales evolution, and thus our focal metrics time-to-peak-sales and height-of-peak-sales, is determined by four key metrics: the speed
`of adoption, the size of the adopter (patient) potential, the repurchase (refill) rate and the interpurchase time. For the majority of
`categories, repeat sales dynamics (interpurchase time and repurchase/refill rate) are determined by exogenous factors such as therapy
`guidelines, patient characteristics, and physician skills. Physicians rarely risk switching the patient to another drug in response to
`marketing activities, because effectiveness and compatibility of the new drug are uncertain to a patient. Additionally, the time between
`refills follows medical needs for optimal treatment. As a consequence, we focus on the diffusion metrics speed of adoption and size of
`adopter potential in our discussion of order-of-entry and quality effects on peak sales as these decision variables do not change the repeat
`sales dynamics. Aggregate repeat sales metrics are constant over the life cycle of a drug unless therapy guidelines are replaced or the
`distributions of patient and physician characteristics change systematically (Hahn et al. 1994).
`
`3.2 Effects of order of entry and quality
`
`3.2.1 Order of entry
`
`Multiple studies investigate the impact of order of entry on a brand’s market share and sales (e.g., Kalyanaram et al. 1995; Robinson and
`Fornell 1985; Urban et al. 1986). Late entrants grow faster but achieve lower market share levels (Kalyanaram and Urban 1992). The
`effect has also been demonstrated for pharmaceuticals (Berndt et al. 1995; Shankar et al. 1998). These results are due to the fact that
`late-mover drugs face a lower adopter potential that is faster penetrated. In addition, late entrants are less effective than early entrants in
`competing for the remaining potential adopters (Kalyanaram and Urban 1992; Lieberman and Montgomery 1988). As a result, late
`entrants expect a lower level of peak sales and a shorter time-to-peak-sales. We note, however, that this effect may be moderated by other
`variables such as quality.
`
`If late entrants penetrate the expected lower adopter potential at the same speed with similar support and quality as earlier entrants,
`time-to-peak-sales will be shorter. There are, however, good reasons to believe that their adoption speed is even faster than for early
`entrants. This is because buying resistance at the category level is much lower than it had been in earlier periods of the market life cycle.
`With more brands, consumers have had multiple opportunities to collect consumption experiences. Furthermore, social pressures on later
`adopters may favor trial probabilities for late mover brands (Bass 1969; Rogers 1995). The entry of another brand should not only
`increase brand variety but also enhance marketing activity in terms of pricing, advertising and promotion, which may lead to faster
`adoptions (Horsky and Simon 1983; Krishnan et al. 2000; Prins and Verhoef 2007). To summarize, we expect order of entry to reduce
`both the time-to-peak-sales and the height-of-peak-sales.
`
`3.2.2 Quality
`
`Quality is considered of essential importance for new product success (Tellis and Johnson 2007). There is no doubt that a better quality
`increases the attractiveness of the brand, which in turn should enlarge its adopter potential. Indeed, many studies demonstrate the
`positive sales effect of quality for drugs (Berndt et al. 1995). Hence, we expect a positive relation between the level of quality and the
`level of peak sales.
`
`Adoption theory predicts that adoption will be faster for products with a relative quality advantage (Rogers 1995). Consequently,
`
`6 of 30
`
`5/21/2015 6:16 PM
`
`00006
`
`

`
`Drivers of peak sales for pharmaceutical brands - Springer
`
`http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s11129-010-9089-5/fulltext.html
`
`high-quality brands should face lower adoption barriers leading to a shorter time-to-peak-sales. The expected time-to-peak-sales should
`therefore decrease with quality. However, we have also argued that a better quality enlarges the adopter potential leading to a potentially
`longer time-to-peak-sales. If this effect is stronger than the accelerated adoption (trial) effect, we would expect a longer time-to-
`peak-sales for high-quality brands. As a consequence, we cannot provide a clear prediction about the direction of the (direct) quality
`effect and consider it as an empirical issue.
`
`3.2.3 Interaction between order of entry and quality
`
`Prior research has shown that the innovativeness of a new drug can reduce the disadvantage from being a late entrant (Shankar et al.
`1998). The study of Shankar et al., however, focused on market share or brand sales, but not on peak-sales metrics. Hence, we cannot
`make any inference about the interaction effect between quality and order-of-entry with respect to the time-to-peak-sales. For time-to-
`peak-sales, we expect that a higher quality reduces the negative effect of a late entry on the time-to-peak-sales. A product with better
`quality may provide the late entrant with more opportunities to gain prescriptions from competing incumbent brands. Low-quality late
`entrants won’t be able to attract these prescriptions. As a consequence, the adopter potential for low-quality entrants will be lower and
`they achieve their peak-sales earlier than high-quality late entrants. Quality thus reduces the negative impact of order of entry on time-to-
`peak-sales, i.e. we expect a positive interaction effect between quality and order of entry.
`
`3.3 Control variables
`
`3.3.1 Own marketing support
`
`The amount of marketing support will affect the time-to- and height-of-peak-sales. Prior research shows that higher marketing
`expenditures speed up adoption (Gielens and Steenkamp 2007; Prins and Verhoef 2007; Steenkamp and Gielens 2003). Diffusion
`research demonstrates that higher marketing expenditures increase the diffusion rate and extend the market potential of adopters (Horsky
`and Simon 1983; Mahajan et al. 1990). Depending on which of these two effects is larger, the time-to-peak-sales will be shortened or
`extended. A recent meta-analysis (Kremer et al. 2008) shows that own marketing expenditures improve the sales base of a drug. Hence,
`we expect a positive effect of own marketing support on the height-of-peak-sales.
`
`3.3.2 Competitive marketing support
`
`Initially, we might predict that competitive marketing expenditures negatively affect the time-to-peak-sales. Prins and Verhoef (2007)
`show that competitive advertising reduces time to adoption. But competitive marketing efforts may also have a category-building effect
`that enhances both own and competitors’ brand sales (Dubé and Manchanda 2005; Fischer and Albers 2010) and may extend the time-to-
`peak-sales. As a consequence, it is difficult to provide a clear prediction about the effect of competitive marketing expenditures on
`time-to-peak-sales.
`
`3.3.3 Number of competitors
`
`The number of competitors in the market might also be relevant in explaining both time-to and height-of-peak-sales. The market share
`theorem (Cooper and Nakanishi 1988) postulates that a brand’s market share is inversely related to the number of competitors in a
`market. The brand looses in relative attractiveness. The loss in attractiveness may have different sources. The memory-sequence effect
`(Alpert and Kamins 1994) or the variety seeking phenomenon (McAlister and Pessemier 1982) may explain the loss in attractiveness
`when more competitors are present in a market. We expect that the number of competitors reduces both the time-to-peak-sales and the
`height-of-peak-sales.
`
`3.3.4 Price
`
`In the empirical application, we use a sample of firms and brands from four European countries (France, Germany, Italy, and the U.K.)
`during the period 1987–1996. The systems of health insurance and price regulation in these countries explain why pharmaceutical firms
`did not use price as a tactical marketing instrument in that period. In France and Italy, prices are determined exogenously by the
`respective authorities. In principle, launch prices can be set freely in the U.K. and Germany. Because drug expenses are typically
`reimbursed, demand is inelastic. As a result, firms have no incentive to reduce the price over time. Since a subsequent increase of the
`approved launch price would result in the loss of the reimbursement status, prices are also not raised in later periods and thus stay rather
`constant. Hence, price plays more or less the role of a cross-sectional control variable in this specific sample. Note also that we do not
`
`7 of 30
`
`5/21/2015 6:16 PM
`
`00007
`
`

`
`Drivers of peak sales for pharmaceutical brands - Springer
`
`http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s11129-010-9089-5/fulltext.html
`
`observe generic price competition in the sample.
`
`3.4 Summary
`
`We provide a summary of the expected effects of our included drivers of time-to- and height-of-peak-sales in Table 2. In this table, we
`also report the operationalization of these variables, which we discuss in the next section in more detail. Finally, we note that we do not
`include distribution as predictor in our model (Kremer et al. 2008; Manchanda et al. 2005), as drug distribution in Europe is highly
`regulated, such that pharmacies are required by law to supply all approved prescription drugs.
`
`Table 2
`Variable definition and expected direction of effects
`
`Variable
`
`Definition
`
`Order of entry
`
`Count variable that counts the entry of NCEs into a product market
`
`Objective quality index based on evaluations of drug quality in international meta-analytic
`review reports (see Appendix B for details)
`
`See above
`
`
`ME =
`
`St ∑tr=0 (1 − φ)r
`
`Ex
`
`pt−r
`
`,
`
`where
`
`Quality
`
`Order of entry ×
`quality
`
`Control variables
`
`Stock of own
`marketing
`expendituresa
`
`Expected Effect on …
`
`Time-to-
`peak-sales
`
`Height-
`of-peak-sales
`
`−
`
`+/−
`
`+
`
`−
`
`+
`
`N.A.
`
`MES t = Stock of own marketing expenditures at the end of quarter t
`
`+/−
`
`+
`
`φ = (Estimated) quarterly depreciation rate
`
`Exp t = Own marketing expenditures in quarter t
`
`See also Berndt et al. (1995, 102)
`
`Stock of competitive
`marketing
`expenditures
`
`Expenditures of all other brands (excluding co-marketing partners) in a product market are
`cumulated to produce competitive marketing expenditures. The calculation of the stock follows
`the approach as outlined under own marketing expenditures.
`
`Number of
`Competitors
`
`Count variable that counts the number of NCEs that have entered a product market in a specific
`quarter
`
`+/−
`
`−
`
`+/−
`
`N.A.
`
`N.A.—Not estimated due to collinearity issues or data limitations
`aTo estimate the depreciation rate φ, we replace the stock variables in the brand sales model (Eq. 3) by quarterly marketing expenditures and add
`lagged sales to the predictor variables. The coefficient associated with the lagged dependent variable measures the carryover-coefficient (1-φ). To
`control for brand heterogeneity in this model, we specify a random brand constant that follows a normal distribution and estimate its mean and
`variance.
`
`4 Data
`
`4.1 Data sources
`
`We test our propositions using data from two prescription drug categories, calcium channel blockers and ACE inhibitors. These
`
`8 of 30
`
`5/21/2015 6:16 PM
`
`00008
`
`

`
`Drivers of peak sales for pharmaceutical brands - Springer
`
`http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s11129-010-9089-5/fulltext.html
`
`categories differ in their therapeutic principles for treating diseases such as hypertension or coronary heart disease. Data collected by
`IMS Health are available on a quarterly basis for a time period of 10 years (1987–1996) in each country. During that period, calcium
`channel blockers and ACE inhibitors represented the two largest (in monetary value) categories of cardio-vascular therapy. They offered
`the most advanced therapy alternatives for the treatment of hypertension, as an example, and substituted sales from established older
`categories such as diuretics or beta blockers. Lipid modifying agents (e.g., Lipitor) and A-II-inhibitors (e.g., Cozaar), which lead today’s
`cardio-vascular drug prescriptions, were only available at the very end of the observation period.
`
`The data include normalized (across different application forms) unit sales (transformed into daily dosages by a brand-specific dosage
`factor), daily dosage price and marketing spending, including expenditures on detailing (>90% of total spending), professional journal
`advertising and direct mailings. Sampling expenditures and other below-the-line activities (e.g., dinner invitations for physicians) are not
`covered. The data come from four European countries—France, Germany, Italy, and the United Kingdom—and comprise 73 brands in
`eight product markets (2 categories × 4 countries). In addition, the data provide the month of product launch, a quality measure for each
`NCE and marketing expenditures by competitors and firms co-marketing the product, a frequently used method in this industry to
`enhance the diffusion of a new drug among physicians.
`
`Both categories experienced multiple brand entries during the study period. The first calcium channel blocker was introduced in
`Germany in 1963 by Knoll, a German company which has been acquired by Abbott. The first ACE inhibitor was introduced in the
`United States and other countries in 1981 by Bristol Myers-Squibb. Additional countries followed quickly in both categories. Between 9
`and 12 brands entered the country markets in each category, with most entries occurring during our observation period. Both categories
`experienced considerable growth in the 1980s, which slowed down or even turned into negative growth by 1996. The categories are
`comparable in their sales histories.
`
`Even though the patent expired for a few early entrants in the calcium channel blocker category in the 1980s, intense generic competition
`did not evolve during our observed period. This is mainly due to the fact that cost containment issues did not play an important role in
`prescription behavior at that time. The market share of the few generic competitors is on average below 1%. In addition, we observe that
`all innovative brands continued to grow after they lost patent protection, i.e. patent

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket