throbber
SENJU EXHIBIT 2200
`LUPIN v SENJU
`IPR2015-01105
`
`PAGE 1 OF 5
`
`

`
`130
`
`/ THE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
`
`from those for the full sample, indicating that measurement error in the mean-charac-
`teristics variables is not causing large biases in the results.
`There are two potential reasons to be concerned about the inclusion of state laws
`in the estimation in Tables 4-6. As explained in Section 5, the inclusion of only linear
`terms for state substitution laws may not adequately capture their effect on the pre-
`scription choice if they change the effective price differential of the drug. Moreover,
`estimating a coefficient on an interaction between mandatory substitution laws and the
`drug dummies might arguably allow for separate identification of baseline differences
`across drugs from the proportion of the drug’s cost to the patient that is internalized
`by physicians (the term 7, in the model). Rather than attempting to estimate and in-
`terpret regression coefficients from a model allowing for full interactions between drug
`dummies, insurance dummies, and the two types of state prescription laws, I indirectly
`account for this possibility by simply estimating the model with only the subsarnple of
`4,334 observations from states with permissive substitution laws and one-line prescrip-
`tion pads. The results, reported in Tables 7-9, are quite similar to those for the full
`sample reported in Tables 4-6. This means that there is little difference in the treatment
`of patients across different regimes of state substitution and prescription-pad laws (so
`that 7, is essentially zero). Given that much of the variance in the prescription decision
`is unexplained, it is not surprising that differences across states in laws that may be
`poorly understood by physicians and poorly adhered to by pharmacists have little or
`no direct effect on prescription behavior. This result is nonetheless consistent with the
`conclusion that physicians internalize little of any differential costs to different patients.
`
`7. Conclusion
`
`This article examines the importance of physicians in the process by which patients
`I
`get either trade-name or generic drugs. The central result is that the physician is an
`important agent in the prescription decision. This should be a key focus of future
`research, since the reasons for why some physicians are more likely than others to
`prescribe generic drugs is largely left unexplained by the empirical analysis presented
`here. Identifying the sources of heterogeneity in behavior across physicians is an im-
`portant part of understanding how the market for prescription drugs operates and, more
`generally, how physicians behave when faced with different information and incentives.
`One avenue for future research should focus on differences across drugs in generic
`prescription rates. A formal treatment of information diffusion would be a useful start-
`ing point for thinking about this issue. One possibility for examining diffusion empir-
`ically is to gather data on the length of time generics and trade-name drugs have been
`marketed and to incorporate such information into the model of prescription choice.
`Another element in the examination of the diffusion of generics would be to combine
`data from the NAMCS surveys in other years. At the time this article was written, the
`NCHS would not release to me physician—identifying data for years other than 1989.29
`It would also be useful to consider other dimensions of differences across drugs, such
`as their use in treating chronic versus acute conditions, or life-threatening versus mild
`conditions.
`
`On the policy side, it is clear that there are potentially large social costs due to
`the habitual prescription of trade-name drugs. VVhen physicians make prescription de-
`cisions based on incomplete information combined with agency problems, they do not
`make cost-effective decisions. Even state legislation that encourages generic substitu-
`tion does not seem to have had an impact on physician prescription decisions. Changes
`in the structure of the health care system, however, may dramatically alter the market
`
`7’ As of the 1991 NAMCS, the NCHS has included physician identifiers in the public-use data, but
`there is no information on the state in which the physician practices.
`
`PAGE 2 OF 5
`
`PAGE 2 OF 5
`
`

`
`HELLERSTEIN /
`
`131
`
`TABLE 7
`
`Estimated Coefficients on Demographic Variables, Geographic
`Variables, and Average Characteristics for Subsample from States
`with Permissive Substitution and One-Line Prescription Pads
`
`Probit
`Probit
`% Change in
`Variable
`Coefficient
`t-Statistic
`Generic
`
`
`Random-Effects Random-Effects
`
`Constant
`
`Age
`
`Female
`
`Nonwhite
`
`Hispanic
`
`Specialist
`
`Mean age
`
`Percent female
`
`Percent black
`
`Percent Hispanic
`
`Percent Medicaid
`
`Percent Medicare
`
`Percent private
`
`Percent HMO/prepaid
`
`Midwest
`
`South
`
`—.3l
`
`—.O1
`
`-.10
`
`.07
`
`- .02
`
`.00
`
`.00
`
`—.41
`
`-.13
`
`- .60
`
`.21
`
`-.10
`
`.08
`
`.20
`
`- .28
`
`—.3O
`
`-2.13
`
`-3.60
`
`-2.31
`
`.77
`
`- .17
`
`.02
`
`.87
`
`-2.00
`
`-.52
`
`- 1.85
`
`.77
`
`-.3!
`
`.50
`
`.92
`
`-2.08
`
`-.09
`
`-.l5%
`
`-3.08%
`
`2.29%
`
`- .67%
`
`.05%
`
`.O8%
`
`- 12.77%
`
`-4.02%
`
`- 19.77%
`
`6.59%
`
`-3.24%
`
`2.60%
`
`6.09%
`
`-9.00
`
`-9.56
`
`-1.66
`-.36
`- .05
`West
`
`
`.25p 8.98
`
`Note: The dependent variable is one if the generic is prescribed, zero otherwise. The
`sample size is 4,334. The mean and percent variables refer to the mean and percent char-
`acteristics of the physician whom the patient visits. The omitted region category is Northeast.
`The omitted insurance categories are self-pay and percent self-pay. The percent changes in
`generic prescription are calculated as the average over the sample of the percent change in
`the probability of receiving a generic. For example. the percent change in the probability
`of generic prescription for age is the average percentage change for a marginal increase in
`age. For the dummy variables, the percent change in generic prescription represents the
`average percentage change that occurs when a person moves into the category represented
`by the dummy variable. The parameter p is the estimated variance of the random physician
`effect.
`
`for prescription drugs. Information from IMS America Inc., a market research firm,
`shows that managed-care payments (both private managed care such as HMOs and
`Medicaid HMOS) accounted for 58.5% of dollar revenues for pharmaceutical retail
`sales in 1996, up from less than 30% in 1990 (IMS America, 1996). Given the emphasis
`on cost containment in HMOS, the continued growth of managed care may increase
`the market share of generic drugs, or may cause the price differential between trade-
`name and generic drugs to fall as HMOS negotiate with trade-name manufacturers for
`price discounts. Other information from IMS (IMS America, 1995) indicates that there
`is some evidence that changes are already occurring. As of 1995, pharmacists substi-
`tuted generics in approximately half of all cases where physicians wrote a new pre-
`scription for a trade—name drug for which a generic was available. This is up from less
`than 30% in 1989. Interestingly, however, while 44% of all new prescriptions (including
`
`PAGE 3 OF 5
`
`PAGE 3 OF 5
`
`

`
`132
`
`/ TI-IE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
`
`Estimated Coefficients for Drug-Class Dummy Variable for
`TABLE 8
`Subsample of States
`
`Probit
`Random-Effects
`% Change in
`Drug Class
`Coefficient
`t—Statistic
`Generic
`
`
`Random-Effects
`
`Antimicrobials
`
`Cardiovascular/renals
`
`Central nervous system
`Hormones/hormonal
`mechanisms
`
`Skin/mucous membrane
`
`.97
`
`.21
`
`.76
`
`1.05
`
`-.77
`
`5.53
`
`.88
`
`3.85
`
`5.78
`
`-2.59
`
`30.42%
`
`5.02%
`
`22.54%
`
`33.61%
`
`-10.72%
`
`Ophthalmics
`-.26
`—.74
`-4.89%
`-.66 -.88Respiratory tract -9.80%
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Note: The omitted drug category is pain relief.
`
`both single— and multisource drugs) were filled with generics in 1995, only 42.4% of
`prescriptions paid for by private managed care were filled generically. This may suggest
`that managed-care groups have successfully bargained for price discounts from trade-
`name drug manufacturers.
`There is one important caveat to the potential social benefits of increased generic
`prescription. Reducing the returns to t:rade—name drugs may have an adverse effect on
`
`Tests of Moral Hazard for the Subsample of States Equality of Individual Insurance
`TABLE 9
`Variables with Sell‘-Payment Random-Effects Probit Results
`
`Skin!
`
`Respir-
`Mucous
`atory
`Pain
`Mem- Opthal-
`Cardio—
`Anti-
`Insurance
`
`
`
`
`
`’ microbials vasculars Metabolics Hormones branes mics ReliefVariable Tract
`Medicaid
`
`Coefficient
`
`I-statistic
`
`% change
`Medicare
`
`— .06
`
`-.45
`
`.56
`
`2.18
`
`— .48
`
`-1.67
`
`.37
`
`1.37
`
`.61
`
`1.45
`
`- .04
`
`—.l3
`
`— . 17
`
`-.21
`
`-2.31%
`
`17.97% -15.37%
`
`14.30% 7.11%
`
`-.90% -1.24%
`
`- . 16
`
`.36
`
`.32
`
`.56
`
`.13
`
`Coefficient
`
`t-statistic
`
`% change
`Private
`
`Coefficient
`
`r-statistic
`
`% change
`HMO/prepaid
`Coefficient
`
`-.02
`
`— . 10
`
`.37
`
`1.97
`
`-.71
`
`2.01
`
`.71
`
`1.49
`
`.46
`
`-.6l%
`
`10.91%
`
`-5.60%
`
`14.13% 2.87% 12.07%
`
`2.89%
`
`-.01
`
`-.13
`
`-—.01
`
`—.07
`
`—.I4
`
`-.91
`
`-.20
`
`-1.28
`
`.13
`
`.40
`
`.20
`
`.45
`
`.12
`
`.55
`
`.10
`
`.13
`
`-51%
`
`-36% -5.06%
`
`-7.50% 1.03%
`
`3.42%
`
`2.62%
`
`.94%
`
`-.04
`
`.17
`
`-.17
`
`-.12
`
`.43
`
`.28
`
`—.06
`
`-.05
`
`I-statistic
`-.32
`.55
`-.65
`-.59
`1.26
`.53
`—.21
`-.03
`-1.38% 4.68% -5.83% -4.54% 4.31% 5.21% -1.13%% change —.41%
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Note: The percent change row represents the average percent change over the sample of patients in the
`probability of receiving a - generic prescription when the patient’s insurance status changes from self-pay to
`the appropriate insurance category. Sample sizes in empty cells are too small to estimate coefficients.
`
`PAGE 4 OF 5
`
`PAGE 4 OF 5
`
`

`
`HELLERSTEIN /
`
`133
`
`pharmaceutical R&D investment and new drug development. There is little evidence
`on the magnitude of this effect, which suggests another important avenue for future
`research. Nonetheless, if the private returns to pharmaceutical R&D need to be sup-
`plemented to promote more efficient levels of drug discovery, the best mechanism to
`subsidize private drug development is probably not the indirect subsidies provided by
`market imperfections in the demand for prescription drugs.
`
`Appendix A
`
`The data for this article are taken from three versions of the 1989 NAMCS: the publicly available
`I
`NAMCS for patient visits; a version of the NAMCS for patient visits with additional confidential identifying
`information; and the publicly available NAMCS for drug mentions. The NAMCS is a survey of approximately
`1,200 office-based physicians and a subsample of their patients, conducted not-quite annually by the National
`Center for Health Statistics (NCHS). It is a three-stage sample of primary sampling units (PSUs), physician
`practices within a PSU, and patient visits within practices. A PSU is a county, group of counties, or standard
`metropolitan statistical area. After the first and second stages of the sample, selected physicians were ran-
`domly assigned to two consecutive weeks of the year beginning in February 1989, and they filled out detailed
`questionaires on a random subsample of patient visits during those two weeks. The average physician re-
`corded data for approximately 30 patients, although there is a lot of variability in the number of patients per
`physician. The sampling scheme was designed so that physicians with larger practices recorded data for more
`patients, although not in fixed proportions to the overall sizes of the practices. (Physicians who saw fewer
`than ten patients filled out questionaires for all patients they saw.)
`These questionaires contain data on demographic characteristics of the patient (age, sex, race, ethnicity)
`as well as data pertaining to his or her medical condition and details about what occurred during the visit
`such as duration of the visit, procedures performed, and diagnosis. In addition, the physician recorded for
`each patient the expected source(s) of payment for the visit: self-pay. Medicare, Medicaid, Blue Cross/Blue
`Shield, other commercial insurance. HMO/prepaid plans, no charge, or other. If the patient paid for the visit
`but was to be reimbursed by a third-party payer, the physician was told to only consider the third-party payer
`as the source of payment. Most importantly, the physician was instructed to list up to five medications
`ordered for the patient and to record “the same specific drug name (brand or generic) .
`.
`. used on any
`prescription." The definition of medications was interpreted broadly and included both prescription and
`nonprescription pharmaceuticals.
`All three versions of the data contain the results of the questionaires as well as information identifying
`the specialty of the physician and the region of the country in which the physician practices (North, South,
`East, Midwest). In the publicly available 1989 NAMCS for patient visits and its confidential counterpart, the
`unit of observation is a patient visit, and patient-specific sampling weights are included in the data. The
`confidential NAMCS also links the patients of each physician together via a physician identification number
`and contains information on the U.S. state in which the physician practiced. The state identifiers allow
`prescriptions to be classified according to state laws about generic substitution. and the physician identifiers
`allow for the inclusion of physician-specific effects into the model. Although the public version of the
`NAMCS is available for other years as well, the confidential version of the data has only been prepared for
`1989.
`
`In the NAMCS for drug mentions, the unit of observation is an ordered medicine. Therefore, infor-
`mation is included only for those patients for whom a drug was ordered; for patients for whom multiple
`medicines were ordered, multiple observations appear (and these observations cannot be linked in these data).
`Because the drug-mentions data focus on medicines, drug-specific sampling weights are attached to each
`observation. In addition, these data contain information matching each ordered medicine to a unique trade-
`name drug code as well as a corresponding generic drug code. The data also include other information about
`the drug ordered such as the generic name, manufacturer (either generic or trade-name), prescription status
`(over—the-counter or prescription), and drug class code (one of 20 major classes such as opthalmics or
`neurologics).’° In conversations with representatives at the NC}-IS. it became clear that the manufacturer
`codes for each drug are not entirely reliable. I therefore verified each manufacturer codr sing the 1991 Drug
`Facts _and Comparisons, a comprehensive pharmaceutical industry source for drug information.
`The two sources of sampling weights in the data are the patient weights from the NAMCS for patient
`visits and the drug weights from the drug-mentions data. Experimentation with these two sets of sampling
`weights yielded very little difference between unweighted and weighted estimates of any of the results in
`this article. All results reported here are derived without sampling weights.
`
`3° See Table 3 for a list of the drug codes used in the empirical analysis.
`
`PAGE 5 OF 5
`
`PAGE 5 OF 5

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket