throbber
SENJU EXHIBIT 2142
`LUPIN v SENJU
`IPR2015-01105
`
`PAGE 1 OF 21
`
`

`
`350
`
`ANEREA coscsLLr
`
`that tries to explain observed market segmentation using data on national
`market shares. Empirical observations of market shares for trade—name
`and generic drugs in post—patent therapeutic categories in the US market
`usually indicate a degree of segmentation between branded drugs and their
`generic equivalents, arising from a finite cross-price elasticity between the
`two types of drugs (the cross~pricc elasticity between two homogeneous
`goods
`should be infinite). However,
`these studies
`ignore individual
`heterogeneity. The micro dataset at hand allows me both (i) to control for
`individual heterogeneity and (ii) to explore the degree of time—dependence
`in drug choices, both of which can be important
`in explaining the
`substantial and persistent differences in market shares among therapeuti-
`cally equivalent drugs.
`Second, in recent years, we have witnessed a surge in direct advertising
`to consumers by pharmaceutical companies for prescription drugs sold in
`the US market. The amount spent on direct-to-consumer prescription drug
`advertising rose from US$35rn in £987 to US$357rn in 1995, US$6l0m in
`1996, and over USS} billion in 1997 (NERA {i999}). This spending choice
`reflects a widespread belief within the pharmaceutical
`industry that
`patients should have a role in the choice of prescrr'ptz'on drugs. This paper
`directly studies the patient’s role in pharmaceutical choice.
`Finally, the most important institutional features of the Italian market
`during the sample period such as the important role of licensed products,
`limited patient co—payrnents, and lack of direct financial
`incentives to
`doctors to prescribe cheaper drugs characterize almost every EU country
`(NERA {l999}).
`I use a new panel dataset provided by the Etalian National Health
`Institute, which includes all the prescriptions in the anti-ulcer market from
`l990—i992 for a 10% random sample of the population of Rome aged
`lS»85. This dataset allows researchers a glimpse into the dynamics of
`prescription behavior at the micro level which is not possible with the
`predominantly aggregate and! or cross~sectional datasets which have been
`used in most studies of pharmaceutical markets to date.
`My main conclusions are as follows. I begin by testing the null hypo-
`thesis of whether doctors and.’ or patients are indifferent between drfilerent
`brands of the same molecule, as we would expect given their therapeutic
`equivalence. After rejecting the hypothesis, I attempt to isolate both the
`patient-level and the doct0r—level factors which are responsible for product
`differentiation.
`I focus specifically on the degree of time—dependence in
`doctors’ and patients’ drug choices by testing whether the patients show
`state dependence in their purchasing patterns, and whether the doctors
`exhibit habit persistence. I find significant evidence of doctor and patient
`‘habit’, which imply that in molecular sub markets in which brands are not
`allowed to compete on the basis of price, habit persistence at the micro
`
`£9 Blackwell Publishers Ltd. 2006.
`
`PAGE 2 OF 21
`
`PAGE 2 OF 21
`
`

`
`PREFERENCES IN ms PRESCRIPTION DECISION
`
`351
`
`level can translate into sticky and persistent market shares at the aggregate
`level.
`
`'¥."he paper is organized as follows. In the next section I survey the
`previous empirical literature. In Section ill, I describe the dataset used in
`the estimation. Section IV describes my empirical specification, while
`Section V reviews the results. A summary of the results make up the final
`section.
`
`:1. Docrons’ DEMAND
`
`While the present study focuses on doctors’ demand for pharmaceutical
`products, most of the recent literature on pharmaceuticals (for example,
`Caves at of. H991], Caves and I-Iurwitz [I988], Berndt et at’. {£997}, Scott
`Morton {l99’7, 2000], and Scherer [l993]) has focused on supply—side issues
`(e.g., entry, pricing, advertising, R&D races). In his comment on Caves
`at
`:11.
`{I991}, Fakes
`[i991] argues
`that a panel
`following doctors’
`prescriptions over time would be the only way to understand the major
`determinants of the demand For pharmaceuticals. The panel data E use
`aiiow me to separately identify doctor and patient effects.
`Much of the previous work on the demand for pharmaceuticals has used
`aggregate, market—share data, which are much better suited to measuring
`the degree of differentiation between various drugs rather than explain its
`causes. For example, Stern {l995]
`finds low substittitability between
`branded and generic drugs, while Eliison er a1. {I997} find a high elasticity
`of substitution between generic and branded drugs.
`One recent microdata-based analysis of the demand for pharmaceuticals
`is that by Hellerstein U998}. She focuses on doctors’ choices between
`branded and generic versions of drugs for which a patent has recently
`expired. Significantly, she finds some evidence of habit persistence in the
`prescription behavior of physicians, even after controlling for observable
`characteristics of physicians and patients. Unfortunately, her dataset does
`not allow her to test for patients’ effects owing to data limitations, while
`her dataset allows for an analysis of financial incentives due to third—party
`payer variation. My dataset, on the other hand, has multiple observations
`for doctor-patient interactions, prescription of the same moiecule by a
`single doctor to many patients, and prescriptions of the same drug by
`many doctors.
`£987} analyzes competition between patent holders
`Gorecki E1986,
`and licensees in Canada: an institutional setting very similar to the
`Italian market. He only observes aggregate data, but he is able to take
`advantage of the regulatory variation among Canadian provinces to
`identify
`competitive
`effects
`in
`his
`empirical
`anaiyses. Gorecki’s
`conclusions in [E9863 are consistent with my results: ‘. .. Since physicians
`still write, by and large, brand name prescriptions for the pioneering
`£133 Blackwell Publishers Ltd. 2000.
`
`PAGE 3 OF 21
`
`PAGE 3 OF 21
`
`

`
`352
`
`ANDREA COSCELLE
`
`brand, unless an element of price competition is introduced at the level of
`the pharmacist the pioneering brand will continue to dominate the market
`[. . .]. Hence it
`is
`the combination of attempting to nullify quality
`differences between the pioneering and late
`entrant brands
`and
`introduction of price competition that results in the late entrants capturing
`market share’.
`
`Pharmaceutical markets are subdivided into therapeutic classes. Follow-
`ing most of the recent economic literature on pharmaceuticals {e.g., Stern
`[l995]), I regard a therapeutic class as having several sub-markets. I define
`a therapeutic market as a 4-digit ATC code (for example, A028 contains
`all the anti-ulcer drugs), and a sub—market as a specified molecule (for
`example,
`ranttidine). The ATC code is an international classification
`scheme which classifies drugs by target part of the anatomy, mechanism of
`action, and chemical and therapeutic characteristics. This is a natural
`definition of demand because a 4~digit ATC code includes all the molecules
`which can theoretically be prescribed for a certain diagnosis. The
`molecules themselves difi"er according to side effects,
`interactions with
`other drugs, specific indications and prices. In the markets I study, a
`physician typically decides the appropriate molecule for the diagnosis and
`then she decides which trademamel version of the molecule to prescribe to
`the patient.
`My work focuses on a particular therapeutic market: anti—uicer drugs
`(A023).
`I analyze this market because it accounts for a considerabie
`proportion of world-wide expenditure on pharmaceuticals (around 5%,
`IMS International [l996}). Ulcers also required repeated treatment in the
`early 1990s,” a key feature of my analysis.
`I analyze six molecule
`submarkets (famotidine, ranitidtrze, nizatidine, roxatidine, omeprazole and
`misoprostole), which represent more than 90% of the prescriptions during
`the sample period (l990—}992). I restrict my sample to these six molecules
`because the other molecules represent more ‘mature’ and smaller sub-
`marlcets, where some of the prices for identical brands dii‘l‘er.3 In each sub-
`market
`there is a patenbholder and licensees marketing the molecule.
`Much of the literature on trade-name drugs versus generics is concerned
`with the dimensions
`(among others,
`‘perceived quality’ or name
`recognition) according to which these products ‘differ’. In my analysis I
`focus on competing drugs based on the same active ingredient and
`
`‘All the drugs sold under a iicense or a patent in the ltalian market have a trade name.
`alt has recently been found that approximately 80% of peptic ulcers can be cured by
`eradicating He.!'1'c0bap£el‘ Pylori, a bacterium responsible for the recurrence of ulcers, by using
`a combination of antibiotics and antimulcer drugs (Graham [§993l).
`3 Producers of older molecules had their prices equalized only upon applying for a price
`revision, which happened much later. Moreover, some of the producers in these excluded sub-
`maricets are very small firms for whom the assumption ofidentical quality might not hold.
`© Blackwell Publishers Ltd. 2000.
`
`PAGE 4 OF 21
`
`PAGE 4 OF 21
`
`

`
`PREFERENCES IN THE PRESCRIPTION EDIZCHSION
`
`353
`
`marketed by important producers entering the market at
`time.‘‘
`
`the same
`
`III.
`
`THE DATA
`
`The main dataset (provided by the Istitato Superiore della Samlta ’) records,
`for a 10% sample of the population of the Metropolitan Area of Rome
`aged 15-85, all the prescriptions in the anti-ulcer (A0213) drug market
`during the period E990»~l992. The sample is stratified according to age and
`gender; so that the results are representative of the Rome population.
`This patient-level dataset contains over 3I0,000 observations. An obser~
`vation records the identity of the prescribing doctor, the identity of the
`patient, the year and month, and the particuiar presentation form of the
`drug prescribed (for exarnpie,
`1 package of ZANTAC 20 tablets,
`i50 mg
`each). An observation indicates exactly the drug bought by the patient,
`because the records are collected from pharmacies. In the patient-ievel
`dataset there are more than 3,400 doctors prescribing at least once to one
`of the in-sample patients. A supplementary dataset from the same source
`records ail the prescriptions that 350 of these doctors wrote for any of
`their patients during the same period. The supplementary cioctor—based
`dataset contains over 710,000 prescriptions and each observation records
`exactly the same information as the patient—ievel ctataset. The final dataset
`used in my estimations has more than 75,000 observations; it retains all
`the observations in the patientdevei dataset for the patients who received
`at
`ieast one prescription from one of the 350 doctors whose entire
`prescription history is known.
`
`Italian Marker Three important characteristics of the Italian pharmau
`ceutical industry are: (i) there is no price and third-party payer variation,
`(ii) the over—the—connter (OTC) market was tiny in the period of interest,
`and direct advertising to patients for prescription drugs had not yet
`started,5 and (iii) during the sample period, the pharmacist had no power
`to sabgtitute generics for trade-name drugs, as he does in many American
`states.
`
`Doctors’ Prescribing Behavior Doctors heavily prescribe across brands:
`
`“By doing this I believe I have effectively controlled for all ‘objective’ dimensions of
`difierentlation between drugs; therefore I can proceed with my tests of doctor or patient
`indifference fairly confident
`that
`I have controlled for a large share of drug-specific
`heterogeneity.
`5 It is currently illegal throughout the EU and will remain so for several years even though
`the subject is now occasionally raised.
`5Hellersteir2‘s dataset, therefore, potentially contains a iarge amount of measurement error
`in the prescription variable for states where substitution with generics is mandatory.
`© Blackwell Publishers Ltd. 2000.
`
`PAGE 5 OF 21
`
`PAGE 5 OF 21
`
`

`
`354
`
`ANDREA COSCELLI
`
`for example, 98.6% of the in—sarnple doctors prescribed each of the three
`avaiiable brands of omeprazole at ieast once during the sample period.
`Moreover, doctors usually prescribe multipie brands of each molecule in a
`given month. Thus doctors do not specialize in particular drugs over time
`or at a particuiar point in time.
`Patients are not Eimited to a single brand either. At a given point, 40%
`of them wiil have had experienced a shift to a new brand of the same
`moiecule. Diiferent doctors treat the same patient dilierently. Although
`the proportion of switches in the overall
`sample is 4.5%, among
`observations where patients change doctors, the proportion rises to 9%.
`This fatter incidence, however, is much Eower than the 48% switch rate that
`we would expect were the new doctor not to take into account the patient’s
`history of prescriptions, and to prescribe to the patient according to the
`same proportion used for her other patients.
`Most strikingly, of those patients who were switched by the new doctor
`and then returned to their original doctor, 50% (44! 88) are switched again
`when they go back to their usual doctor, and almost all of those (93.2%
`or 41 out of 44) go back to the treatment they received in the previous
`period. These patterns demonstrate cieariy that the probability of receiving
`a new treatment is significantiy influenced by the doctor’s identity, and
`that doctors differ in their choice among therapeutically equivaient drugs
`for the same patient. Next, I present a formal econometric rnodei which
`accommodates all these aspects of behaviour.
`
`IV .
`
`EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS
`
`iV(i). Theory
`
`I analyze the problem facing a doctor trying to choose among brands of
`a certain moiecule. The entire analysis is conditional on the choice of the
`molecule, which is driven by a more complicated set of factors (indications,
`patients general health, side efiects, price, etc.); most of these factors are
`unobservable to the econometrician. By restricting myseif to the analysis
`of ‘homogeneous’ goods, I can hoid price and quality constant and focus
`on other factors driving the choice of competing brands.7
`The central focus of the study is the question of what brand of a given
`molecule doctor i prescribes to a patient j given this patient’s past
`prescription experience with this moiecuie. In particular, doctor i must
`decide whether to prescribe the brand the patient received in the previous
`period (hereafter o for ‘old’ brand) or a new brand, which might generate
`
`71 do not anaiyze whether the doctor prescribed a different presentation form, because all
`the producers sell the same presentation forms, and there was therefore no need to change
`vendor if the doctor or the patient wanted a different presentation form.
`it? Btackwcli Prihlislici-s Ltd‘ 2600.
`
`PAGE 6 OF 21
`
`PAGE 6 OF 21
`
`

`
`PREFERENCES IN THE PRBSCRIPTEON DECISION
`
`355
`
`r: for ‘new’ brand). More
`(hereafter
`a higher utility to the doctor
`specificaiiy, a choice problem where the decision maker decides either to
`stay on the diagonal of a transition probabilities model, or to move off-
`diagonai to any other brand, is collapsed into a simpler problem where the
`decision-maker is confronted with the binary choice of either to stay on
`the diagonal or to move ofiidiagonal. Since the analysis is conditional on
`the choice of the molecule, ‘new brand’ does not include other molecules.
`
`IV(ii). Estimation Strategy
`
`The empirical model pararneterizes the probability of switching brands as
`a function of patient and doctor attributes. I define as an ‘old’ brand, 0, at
`time t, the brand consumed by the patient at time t— 1. This means that
`I define as a ‘new’ brand, any brand that differs from the ‘old’ one without
`taking into account whether the ‘new’ brand was previously prescribed.
`This means that my analysis focuses on ‘firsborder’ state dependence, so
`that only one-period lags have an effect. Moreover, since only the year and
`month of the prescription are observed, there are ‘ties’ in the dataset. That
`is, there are patients who receive more than one prescription in a month.
`When the prescriptions are ranked in a chronological order,
`the pre-
`scriptions where the patient, molecule and month are the same are
`randomly ordered. Finally, the prescriptions in the sample are written
`either for one package or for two packages of the same brand. The sample
`is evenly split between these two occurrences. Since I model a prescription
`episode, and not quantity, as my dependent variabie, I do not distinguish
`between a prescription of two packages and a prescription of one
`package.3
`i use probit specifications to test the null hypothesis of no doctor and! or
`patient preferences. These models include doctors’
`fixed effects and
`patients’ random effects to capture the unobserved (to the econometrician)
`component of doctors’ and patients’ preferences.
`The dataset sulfers from the probiem of initial conditions common to
`rnost dynamic panel data models.
`I observe a sample of doctors and
`patients for three years, but
`I do not have any information on their
`behavior before the sample period begins. Ideally, I would observe the
`doctors’ behavior
`since
`they started practicing and the patients’
`prescriptions since they were first treated for ulcer problems. This is
`impossible;
`therefore following one of the suggestions put forth in the
`literature (Heckrnan {i98l}), I assume that the prescription process starts
`anew if patients have not had a prescription for six months. Thus, I only
`
`“This implies a two—paclcage prescription ieads to the same degree of state-dependence as
`a one—package prescription.
`© Blackwell Publishers Ltd. 2000.
`
`PAGE 7 OF 21
`
`PAGE 7 OF 21
`
`

`
`356
`
`ANDREA COSCELLI
`
`use data on patients where I am able to observe whether for six months
`prior they did or did not receive ulcer medications. This basically means
`that when the process restarts,
`the decision makers do not retain the
`information on anything which happened before.9
`
`El/(iii). Definition of the Variables
`
`Tables I and II list all the variabies used in the estimations. SWITCH is
`
`the dependent variable and it takes value 1 if patient j receives a brand at
`time t different from what he received at time t —— 1 (for the some moiecule),
`it is 0 otherwise. We review those variables that are not seifiexpianatory.
`
`Patients’ Variables
`
`Timewinvarianz #PRESCRIPTiONS distinguishes among patients ac»
`cording to the seriousness of their uicer probiem (e.g., chronic versus
`
`TABLE I
`P.-U‘!ENT—LEV£L VARIABLES USED IN ‘rm: ESTIMATION
`
`Dependent variable
`SWITCH
`
`Patient is variables
`GENDER
`AGE
`
`.#PRESCRlPTIONS
`
`#DOCTORS
`
`#MOLECULES
`
`#SPF:LL—MOLECULE
`#“PAS'F SWITCHES
`.#MONTHS
`
`Takes value 1 if the brand prescribed is different from the
`brand previously prescribed, 0 otherwise
`
`Takes value 1 if female and 2 if‘ male
`
`Patient’s age
`Total number of prescriptions that the patient receives in
`the sample
`Tolai number of different physicians who prescribed at
`least one drug to the patient
`Total number of different molecules that the patient
`consumes in the sample
`Number of prescriptions oi" the molecule up to time t
`Number of (witiiimmolecule) switches zip to time t
`Actual number of months elapsed between the prescription
`at time t and the one at t —— i
`
`NEWDOCTOPJFEMP
`
`NEWDOCTOR-PERM
`
`Dummy equal to 1 if the physician is a temporary one for
`the patient, 0 otherwise
`Dummy equal to i if the physician is a new permanent one
`for the patient, 0 otherwise
`NEWDOCTOR—RET
`Dummy equai to 1 if the patient returns to a previous
`physician, 0 otherwise
`
`9Most of‘ the models were rerun with a 3«month window instead. The results are not
`quaiitatively different.
`© Blackwcil Publishers Ltd. 2000.
`
`PAGE 8 OF 21
`
`PAGE 8 OF 21
`
`

`
`PREFEIUENCES IN ms PRESCRIPTION DECISION
`TABLE Ii
`DOCTOR-LEVEL VAREABLES useo IN THE ESTIMATION
`
`357
`
`Doctors’ Chfirtlct‘tZt'iSt'iiC.S‘—-{mill-uticet‘ market
`QUANTYTY
`Average monthly quantity prescribed by the doctor in the entire
`market in the previous six months
`Average monthly herfindahl index across brands in the entire
`market in the previous six months
`Average monthly herfindah] index at the molecule level in the
`entire market in the previous six months
`
`E-IERFBRAND
`
`HERFMOLE
`
`Doctors ’ chamctertstics»~m0lecu1e~.!'pec{fic
`MOLESHARE
`Share of prescriptions of the molecule by the doctor in the
`previous month
`Weighted proportion of the prescriptions of the moiecule written
`for the oid brand in the 2 previous months {last month's share
`plus 09 oz" the previous rnonth’s share)
`
`% OLD BRAND
`
`occasional), while #MOLECULES differentiates patients according to
`their willingness to change treatment. #IDOCTORS controis for patienb
`specific preferences for changing doctor. ?atients who change doctors
`more often probably gather more information on possibie treatments;
`therefore it ought to he more difficult for a doctor to switch them; on the
`other hand, these patients might be more experimental.
`
`Tz'me-varying There are three time-varying covariates for the patient,
`which are crucial to measure patient ‘habit’.
`#SPELL~MOLECULE increases over time with any prescription of
`the molecule. #1-"AST SWITCHES increases only upon a withirwnoicculc
`switch. These two ad~hoc variables proxy for the switching tendency of
`a patient. For example, a patient who receives the tenth prescription of
`the motecute ranitidine, has 4.‘¢SPELL—MOLECULE== 10,
`if #PAST
`SWITCHES m0, this indicates that the patient has aiways been with the
`same brand. Finaiiy, .#i\/IONTHS counts the actual number of months
`elapsed between prescription episodes. it cannot exceed six, given the
`definition of a treatment episode. Finally, there is a series of prescription-
`spectfic dummies defining whether the patient is receiving the prescription
`from a substituting physician (NEWDOCTOR—TEMP),’° has permanently
`moved to a new physician (NEWDOCTOR-PERM), or is returning to
`the usual physician (NEWDOCTOR—RBT) after receiving a prescription
`from a substitute. These variabies explore whether doctors have different
`preferences for vendors of a particuiar molecule. If prescriptions decisions
`
`“Most of the temporary substitutions occur when the physician is on vacation, or the
`patient is out of town when he needs a prescription.
`© Blackwell ?ublishcrs Ltd. 2009.
`
`PAGE 9 OF 21
`
`PAGE 9 OF 21
`
`

`
`358
`
`ANDREA ooscsrm
`
`are determined soieiy by the patient’s condition, a change in the pre-
`scribing doctor shouid not vary the patient’s likelihood of being switched.
`
`I use doctor covariates which are time-varying. Most
`Doctors‘ Variables
`of them summarize the prescribing behavior of the physicians in the six
`months imrnediateiy prior to the prescription episode.
`
`Constant across molecule markets Table II describes the variables in
`detail. QUANTITY distinguishes between heavy and tight prescribers of
`anti—ulcer drugs, and proxies for the size of the doctor’s patient base.
`HERFBRAND proxies for the doctors’ preference to prescribe multiple
`brands, while HERFMOLE controls for the dispersion in prescribing
`behavior of the doctor due to choice of difiereaz molecules, which is
`dictated by heterogeneity in the patients’ pool. Its coefficient does not have
`any specific economic meaning:
`it simply ailows me to interpret
`the
`coefficient on HERFBRAND as
`representing doctors’ preference for
`prescribing multipie brands, rather than their need to prescribe muitipie
`drugs (molecules) due to therapeutic considerations. This distinction is
`based on the assumption that the doctor first chooses the molecule that
`suits the patient and then decides which brand to prescribe.
`
`Moleculaspectfic % OLD BRAND captures habit persistence by the
`doctor. MOLESHARE proxies for the importance that the molecule has
`for the doctor.
`
`Molecule markers The number of competing products, the time since
`the molecule entered the market, the size of the vendors, and the amount
`of advertising all differ across molecule markets. I use moiecule dummies
`to proxy for the different competitive conditions in each molecule market.
`Finaily,
`I
`include monthly dummies to control for exogenous changes
`(such as regulatory changes) that occur during the sample period.
`
`Summary Statistics Table III provides sample summary statistics. There
`are siightly more than 75,000 observations in the original sarnpie, an
`observation being a prescription.
`I exclude the following observations:
`(i) patients who received prescriptions from doctors whose entire pre-
`scription history is not known, (ii) the first prescription of each molecule
`for each patient, so as to initialize the process, and (iii) ail prescriptions in
`the first 6 months and those more than 6 months apart for the same patient
`because of the initial conditions probiem discussed above. This leaves
`43,840 observations.
`There are more than 5,000 different patients and 350 doctors in the
`sample. I observe a change of brand (SWITCH) in 4% of the observations.
`There are siightly more prescriptions written to females in the sample,
`63 Blackwell Pubiishers Ltd. 2000.
`
`PAGE 10 OF 21
`
`PAGE 10 OF 21
`
`

`
`PREFERENCES IN THE PRESCRIPTION DECISION
`TABLE III
`SUMMARY S'§'A’I‘iS'I‘ICS FOR THE SAMPLE
`
`359
`
`Max
`Std. Dev. Min
`Mean
`
`
`Dependent variable
`Switch
`
`Patient is variables
`Gender: 1 if fcmaie, 2 if maic
`Age
`.#In-sampie prescriptions
`#Molecu1es prescribed in—sampie
`#Different doctors prescribing
`#Prescriptions of the molecule
`#Past switches up to time I
`#Months between prescriptions
`New doctor—temp
`New doctorwperrn
`New doctor-ret
`
`0.040
`
`0.197
`
`0
`
`1
`
`'
`
`1.484
`62.73
`29.478
`1.87
`1.629
`i4.9S5
`0.396
`1.232
`0.018
`0.02%
`0.024%
`
`0.499
`12.65
`19.75
`1.09
`1.1 i
`12.68
`1.205
`1.277
`0.134
`0. E43
`0.155
`
`1-F
`15
`2
`1
`1
`2
`0
`0
`0
`0
`0
`
`2-M
`85
`126
`8
`14
`106
`18
`6
`E
`1
`1
`
`Doctors‘ cltaractcrEstics~anl£«m'cer market
`Average monthly quantity prescribed in»samp]e
`E-ierfindahl brand level
`Herfindahl rnolecirie Eevel
`
`Doctors ’ characteristicswmoiecule specific
`% Oid brand prescribed
`Molecule share
`
`876.168
`0.243
`0.485
`
`297.568
`0.069
`0.123
`
`207.08
`0.09
`0.292
`
`25 1 2.717
`0.68
`0.93
`
`0.97
`0.528
`
`0.405
`0.256
`
`0.025
`0.025
`
`1.9
`1
`
`Moleculc sub-market
`1
`0
`0.438
`0.742
`mnidine
`1
`0
`0.199
`0.04
`nizatidine
`1
`0
`0.091
`0.008
`roxatidme
`
`omeprazale l 0.097 0.297 0
`
`
`
`
`While the average age is around 62. Turning to the time—varying covariates
`for the patients: the average prescription is written to a patient who is
`purchasing the particular molecule for the fourteenth time (#SPELL-
`MOLECULE) and who has already switched brands 0.4 times (# PAST
`SWITCHES). The average time between two prescriptions (#MONTHS)
`is less than two months. Finaiiy, in approximately 6% of the prescriptions,
`the prescribing doctor differs
`from the one who wrote the previous
`prescription. The number of prescriptions where the patient temporarily
`visits a doctor difierent
`from the one responsible for
`the previous
`prescription {NEWDOCTOR-TEMP) is about 1.8%; whereas 2% of the
`prescriptions are written by a new doctor, who then becomes the usual
`doctor for the patient (NEWDOCT‘OR—PERM). Finally, 2.4% of the
`prescriptions are written by the osuai physician after the patient has been
`prescribed something by 21 substitute in the previous period.
`The unit of measurement for the quantity variable (QUANTITY) is
`the defined daily dose, which is an international measurement unit. For
`© Blackweil Publishers Ltd. 2000.
`
`PAGE 11 OF 21
`
`PAGE 11 OF 21
`
`

`
`360
`
`ANDREA COSCELLI
`
`each molecule, the daily number 01" milligrams of the chemical compound
`that the average patient needs is defined. Therefore any package can be
`transformed into a number of days of therapy for the average patient.
`Finally, the dummy variables for the molecule markets indicate that 74%
`of the prescriptions in the sample were for
`rcmitidine,
`foliowed by
`omeprazole with 9%.
`Yable IV compares the market shares in the original sample to those in
`the estimation samples. First, column (1) shows that withimmolecule
`market shares differ. Second, the main estimation sample is remarkably
`similar to the original sample, white the switching sample in column (3)
`
`TABLE IV
`Manner SHARES IN THE SAMPLE
`
`Colnmn (1) shows market shares in the overall sample; in column (2) market shares in the
`sample used in the estimation are reported. Column (3) is a subset of the sample used in
`column (2), conditional on the patients’ being prescribed a new brand. Column {4} indicates
`the expected brand frequency in the switch sarnpie based on the total in~sample market shares
`Estimation
`Overall
`Estimation
`sampie and
`Conditional
`
`sample
`sample
`switch
`probabilities
`
`Famotidfne
`FAMODIL
`GASTREDIN
`MOTIAX
`
`Ranitidine
`RANIBEN
`RANSBLOC
`RANIDIL
`TRIGGER
`Uacex
`ULKOBREN
`ZANTAC
`
`Nizaridine
`Caomz.-xr
`NIZAX
`ZANIZAL
`
`Roxalidine
`GASTRALGIN
`N501-X2
`Roxrr
`
`0.467
`0.448
`0.083
`
`0.02
`0.02%
`0.419
`0.021
`0.029
`0.002
`0.483
`
`0.359
`0.581
`0.059
`
`0.332
`0. E99
`0.468
`
`0.458
`0.453
`0.088
`
`0.03
`0.025
`0.432
`0.024
`0.024
`0.003
`0.467‘
`
`0.37%
`0.566
`0.062
`
`0.292
`0.161
`0.546
`
`0.415
`0.415
`0.169
`
`0.07
`0.062
`0.387
`0.032
`0.033
`0.005
`0.405
`
`0.437
`0.437
`0.125
`
`0.285
`0.428
`0.286
`
`0.437
`0.454
`0.108
`
`0.03§
`0.026
`0.435
`0.017
`0.026
`0.007
`0.454
`
`0.453
`0.466
`0.08
`
`0.3
`0.272
`0.427
`
`Omeprazoie
`0.304
`0.303
`0.343
`0.304
`LOSEC
`0.326
`0.37
`0.329
`0.352
`MEPRAL
`0.33
`0.326
`0.328
`0.343
`OMEPRAZEN
`
`#0bservations 1,775 75,316 43,840 1,775
`
`
`
`
`Source: Author‘s computations based on the data set described in Section III.
`© Blackwell Publishers Ltd. 2000.
`
`PAGE 12 OF 21
`
`PAGE 12 OF 21
`
`

`
`PREFERENCES IN THE PRESCRIPTION DECISION
`‘ TABLE V
`CORRELATION TABLE
`
`301
`
`
`
`
`
`
`SWETCI-I #SPMC)LVariable #1\/ION #PASTSW °/o0Li)§3R HERFB
`SWITCH
`1.000
`1.00
`#SPELL-MOLECULE
`~0.05
`1.00
`#'MON'I‘HS
`0.0587 —0.02332
`1.00
`-0.071’?
`#PAST SWITCHES
`0.1897
`0.2442.
`L00
`—0.09S9
`——0.361
`ah’-‘OLD BRAND
`-43.0983
`-0. 185
`1.00
`0.1788
`—-0.0323
`0.0022
`HBRFBRAND
`-0.012‘)
`~0.025'7
`
`QUANTITY ——0.0533 —~0.l072 0.02 —~0.0525 0.027i 0.0066
`
`
`
`
`Source: Author’s computations based on the data set described in Section III.
`
`shows the small brands receiving a somewhat Earger share than in the other
`sample. Cohrmn (4) computes the conditional probabilities of a drug being
`prescribed upon switching,
`i.e.,
`I assume that the probability of being
`prescribed brand i, given that a patient is switched from j is simpiy brand
`i’s share among ail brands other than j in the sample, and assuming that
`the probability of being switched away from brand j is the same for ail j.
`The comparison of column (3) and column (4)
`indicates that srnalier
`brands (such as NEOH2, MOTIAX and ZANIZAL) gain market share from
`the larger brands by having patients who have already received the
`molecule switched to their drugs.“ Finaily, there is not any significant
`increase in market shares for the small producers during the sample
`period, even if the subsample of the ‘new patients’ is separately analysed.
`
`Correlations Table V provides the sample correlations for the duration
`covariates measuring doctor and patient habit persistence.
`to
`Table V indicates habit persistence by doctors (doctors tend not
`switch patients whose ‘old’ drug is what they usuaiiy prescribe) and brand-
`loyalty by patients (patients are not switched after they have received the
`brand for a certain number of consecutive periods).
`
`V.
`
`RESULTS
`
`V(i). Baseline Model
`
`The first column in Table VI presents the estimation results for the
`baseline rnodei, which uses all the information availabie.
`GENDER and AGE are both significant. Men are prescribed a new
`
`" The difference between the expected frequency computed in coiumn (4), and the actual
`frequency reported in column (3)
`is quite limited considering that the actuai number of
`observed switches to small drugs in the sample is very limited for the ieast
`important
`molecules:
`for example there are oniy three switches to N201-I2, and two switches to
`ZANIZAL.
`© Blackwell Publishers Ltd. 2000.
`
`PAGE 13 OF 21
`
`PAGE 13 OF 21
`
`

`
`362
`
`ANDREA COSCELLI
`T.uu.x-: VI
`BASELENE Moos1.mPaosrr Esrizvmriou
`
`Asymptotic t-statistic on the right-hand side
`
`Dependent variabie—SWITCH
`
` Baseline No patients No doctors
`
`
`
`
`Patients ‘ char-actermics
`-2.96
`~0.07l
`Gender: 1 if1'ema1e,2i1‘ma!e
`3.03
`0.003
`Age
`-1.66
`Totaé #in—samp1e prescriptions —-0.002
`3.27
`Total #moEccu1es prescribed
`0.040
`#S;)eil-molecule
`-0.026 W12. 19
`#Past switches
`0.244
`32.77
`#Months
`0.069
`8.3% 1
`.#Difi‘erent doctors
`0.011
`0.989
`New doctor-temp
`0.108
`L083
`New doctorqierm
`0.344
`5.328
`New doctor-ret
`0.081
`1. 224
`Newdoc x #spe1E-molecule
`0.03 3
`2.030
`
`~—0.07
`0.002
`-0.003
`0.066
`0.025
`0.23
`0.08
`0.012
`0.342
`0.312
`0.059
`0.0006
`
`-3.43
`3.02
`——3.068
`6.33
`—— 2 3.55
`36.568
`1i.34
`1.329
`5.934
`6.454
`1.046
`0.166
`
`Doctors ’ characterz'.ru'cs——arzti-ulcer marker
`Total quantity prescribedf 100
`0.002
`Herfindahi brand leveé
`~0.337
`Herfindabl molecule level
`0.079
`
`0.86
`-2.48
`0.79
`
`

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket