throbber
Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 260–278
`
`Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect
`
`Journal of Financial Economics
`
`journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jfec
`
`How are shorts informed?
`Short sellers, news, and information processing$
`
`Joseph E. Engelberg a, Adam V. Reed b,n, Matthew C. Ringgenberg c
`a Rady School of Management, University of California, San Diego, San Diego, CA 92093, USA
`b Kenan-Flagler Business School, University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill, NC 27599, USA
`c Olin Business School, Washington University in Saint Louis, St. Louis, MO 63130, USA
`
`a r t i c l e i n f o
`
`a b s t r a c t
`
`We find that a substantial portion of short sellers’ trading advantage comes from their
`ability to analyze publicly available information. Using a database of short sales combined
`with a database of news releases, we show that the well-documented negative relation
`between short sales and future returns is twice as large on news days and four times as
`large on days with negative news. Further, we find that the most informed short sales are
`not from market makers but rather from clients, and we find only weak evidence that short
`sellers anticipate news events. Overall, the evidence suggests that public news provides
`valuable trading opportunities for short sellers who are skilled information processors.
`& 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
`
`Article history:
`Received 15 July 2010
`Received in revised form
`8 August 2011
`Accepted 29 August 2011
`Available online 9 March 2012
`
`JEL classification:
`G12
`G14
`
`Keywords:
`Asymmetric information
`Manipulation
`News media
`Short sales
`
`1.
`
`Introduction
`
`There is now overwhelming evidence that short sellers
`are informed traders. When short interest or short volume
`are high, future returns are predictably low (see, e.g.,
`Senchack and Starks, 1993; Asquith, Pathak, and Ritter,
`2005; Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang, 2008). Return predict-
`ability, however, suggests only that short sellers have an
`information advantage over other traders. In this paper,
`we ask how short sellers obtain that advantage.
`
`$ The authors thank Dow Jones for providing access to their news
`archive and Paul Tetlock for assistance with the Dow Jones archive. We
`have benefited from comments from Greg Brown, Jennifer Conrad, Wayne
`Ferson, Charles Jones, G ¨unter Strobl, Robert Whitelaw, and an anonymous
`referee. We also thank seminar participants at the University of North
`Carolina, the 2010 Utah Winter Finance Conference, the University of
`Southern California, and the IESE Business School—IX Madrid Finance
`Workshop. This paper was previously titled, ‘‘Buy on the Rumor, [Short]
`Sell on the News: Short Sellers, News and Information Processing.’’
`n Corresponding author.
`E-mail address: adam_reed@unc.edu (A.V. Reed).
`
`0304-405X/$ - see front matter & 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
`doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2012.03.001
`
`To address this question, we combine a large archive of
`all corporate news events with a large panel of daily short
`selling. This unique combination allows us to comprehen-
`sively examine the relation between short selling and
`news events. We find that a substantial portion of short
`sellers’ trading advantage comes from their ability to
`analyze publicly available information. In fact, while news
`events occur on only 22% of the days in our sample, these
`trading days account for over 45% of the total profitability
`from short selling.
`Although our evidence suggests that short sellers obtain
`an information advantage via superior information proces-
`sing, some commentators have suggested other ways that
`short sellers achieve an advantage. The Securities and
`Exchange Commission (SEC) suggested that short sellers
`spread ‘‘false rumors’’ in an effort to manipulate firms
`‘‘uniquely vulnerable to panic.’’1 If this type of manipulation
`
`1 Cox, C., 2008. What the SEC really did on short selling. The Wall
`Street Journal, 24 July.
`
`CFAD VI 1071 - 0001
`CFAD VI v. CELGENE
`IPR2015-01103
`
`

`
`J.E. Engelberg et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 260–278
`
`261
`
`were taking place, then it suggests that short sellers might
`initiate a trade and then spread rumors (see, e.g., van
`Bommel, 2003). In other words, we might expect to see
`short sellers trade before news events, even though the
`news events could turn out to contain false information.
`We find little evidence to support the claim that short
`sellers’ advantage comes from trading before information is
`released, even though short sellers have been shown to
`trade before the release of certain types of public informa-
`tion. For example, Karpoff and Lou (2010) show that short
`selling increases before the initial public revelation of firms’
`financial misrepresentation. Similarly, Christophe, Ferri, and
`Angel (2004) find evidence of informed short selling in the
`5 days before earnings announcements.
`In contrast, when we look at all corporate news events
`in the Dow Jones archive, we find that the trades of short
`sellers are similar to the trades of other market partici-
`pants in the days leading up to a news release. Uncondi-
`tionally, the ratio of short volume to total volume is 0.196
`and this ratio falls by 0.019 on negative news days and
`rises by 0.022 on positive news days. However, during the
`days leading up to the news event, the ratio is the same or
`slightly smaller than the unconditional mean, irrespective
`of the news type. Moreover, during the days after a news
`event, the ratio is the same or slightly larger than the
`unconditional mean. The result suggests that, on average,
`short sellers trade on or after news release dates and they
`do not anticipate public news announcements.
`Given that short sellers tend to trade on or after news
`events, we next ask whether these news events present
`profitable trading opportunities for short sellers. Interest-
`ingly, the extant theoretical literature provides mixed
`predictions on the role of news releases. On the one hand,
`a number of papers argue that news reduces information
`asymmetry (see, e.g., Korajczyk, Lucas, and McDonald,
`1991; Diamond and Verrecchia, 1987). For example, if a
`firm announces a merger, investors who knew that the
`merger was likely no longer have an information advan-
`tage over those who did not. The news announcement
`therefore reduces the information asymmetry between
`informed and uninformed investors. Under this view, the
`trades of informed traders (short sellers) should be less
`profitable when they are initiated immediately following
`a news announcement.
`On the other hand, several papers suggest that public
`news events can lead to differential interpretations by
`traders based on variation in the traders’ skill (see, e.g.,
`Kandel and Pearson, 1995). Rubinstein (1993) puts it
`succinctly: ‘‘In real life, differences in consumer behavior
`are often attributed to varying intelligence and ability to
`process information. Agents reading the same morning
`newspapers with the same stock price lists will interpret
`the information differently.’’ Under this view, public news
`events present profitable trading opportunities for skilled
`information processors, which can explain not only high
`volume around news events (Kandel and Pearson, 1995)
`but also evidence of return predictability from ‘‘soft’’ infor-
`mation in news announcements (see, e.g., Engelberg, 2008;
`Demers and Vega, 2008). This suggests that news announce-
`ments should make the trades of informed traders (short
`sellers) more profitable on news days.
`
`When we take both of these theories to the data, we find
`evidence in support of the second view. Several papers find
`that abnormal short selling unconditionally predicts lower
`future returns (see, e.g., Senchack and Starks, 1993; Asquith,
`Pathak, and Ritter, 2005; Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang, 2008).
`We also find that abnormal short selling leads to lower
`future returns, but we find that this effect is concentrated
`around news events. In particular, the predictability for
`future returns more than doubles on news days and quad-
`ruples on days with negative news. While a long-short
`trading strategy based on the level of short selling would
`have earned a return of 40% over our 2.5-year sample
`period, a long-short strategy that conditioned on short
`selling and news events would have earned 60%. Moreover,
`a strategy based on short selling and negative news would
`have earned an astonishing 180% during our 2.5-year
`sample period.
`An alternative explanation for this result could be that
`some buyers make systematic mistakes around news
`events (Antweiler and Frank, 2006), and that these buyers’
`mistakes are reflected in market makers’ offsetting short
`sales. To determine whether short sellers’ trades are due
`to superior information processing or to offsetting posi-
`tions, we exploit a unique feature of the short selling data,
`namely, exempt versus non-exempt trade marking, which
`allows us to distinguish market makers from non-market
`makers (clients). We find that clients’ trades are particu-
`larly well informed, and that these trades are much more
`profitable in the presence of news events. In contrast,
`market makers’ trades are not particularly well informed,
`and there is no differential impact in the presence of
`news. Thus, there appears to be little support for the claim
`that return predictability from shorts is greater on news
`days because of market makers offsetting short sales.
`Another alternative explanation for our main result is
`that short sales are profitable on news days because news
`days provide short sellers with increased liquidity. This
`explanation, however, requires that the costs of short
`selling are lower around news announcements. However,
`we find little evidence that market liquidity improves on
`news days. For example, we find that bid-ask spreads
`actually increase by nearly 5% around news announce-
`ments, which is consistent with existing models of market
`maker behavior in the presence of informed traders (see,
`e.g., Glosten and Milgrom, 1985; Kyle, 1985). When coupled
`with our finding that the trades of short sellers are more
`than twice as profitable in the presence of news, the
`evidence is consistent with the idea that public news events
`present profitable trading opportunities for skilled informa-
`tion processors and short sellers are, on average, skilled at
`processing public news.
`The remainder of this paper proceeds as follows.
`Section 2 discusses related literature. Section 3 describes
`the databases used in this study and presents our main
`hypotheses. Section 4 presents our analyses and findings.
`Finally, Section 5 concludes.
`
`2. Related literature
`
`The ideas in this paper relate to three distinct branches
`of the existing literature. First, this paper relates to an
`
`CFAD VI 1071 - 0002
`
`

`
`262
`
`J.E. Engelberg et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 260–278
`
`extensive literature on the behavior of short sellers
`relative to other traders. Second, our paper contributes
`to a growing literature on how market participants
`respond to public news. Finally, this paper sheds light
`on an emerging debate on whether news increases or
`decreases information asymmetry. In this section, we first
`discuss prior papers that connect news to short selling.
`We then provide an overview of the relevant literature in
`each of these three branches.
`Fox, Glosten, and Tetlock (2009) use news and short
`selling data to examine the role of short sellers from a
`regulator’s perspective. Motivated by the intense scrutiny
`that short sellers receive from the press and lawmakers,
`they investigate whether short selling appears to be
`socially beneficial or harmful (and worthy of regulation).
`In addition, several extant papers look at short selling
`behavior in the context of a specific type of corporate
`news event. As such, these studies shed light on a subset
`of this paper’s sample of news events. Karpoff and Lou
`(2010), for example, examine short sellers’ positions in
`firms that are investigated for financial misconduct and find
`that short sellers generally anticipate public announcements
`of investigations. Christophe, Ferri, and Angel (2004) and
`Christophe, Ferri, and Hsieh (2010) focus on short sellers’
`trades around earnings announcements and analyst down-
`grades, respectively, and find evidence that short sellers are
`informed traders who can profit from these events. Similarly,
`Daske, Richardson, and Tuna (2005) and Boehmer, Jones, and
`Zhang (2010) look at short selling around management
`forecast announcements and earnings announcements.
`While Daske, Richardson, and Tuna (2005) find no evi-
`dence that short sale transactions concentrate prior to bad
`news events, Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang (2010) find some
`evidence of anticipation, and they show that a significant
`fraction of short sellers’ information advantage comes
`from trading around these events. Finally, Nagel (2005)
`looks at the cash flow news implied by a vector auto
`regression and finds an asymmetric effect on returns,
`indicating that short sellers help incorporate news into
`prices when short selling is not constrained.
`While the above papers identify patterns in short
`selling around a handful of specific corporate news events,
`the current paper aims to uncover patterns in short sellers’
`trades around all types of corporate news events. Doing so
`allows us to speak more generally about short sellers’
`behavior around new releases of public information. In
`particular, using a list of all corporate news events, we can
`sort the universe of trading days into those with and
`without news and examine the differential performance of
`short sellers surrounding news events.
`
`2.1. Short sellers’ trading patterns
`
`Several papers compare the trades of short sellers to
`the trades of other market participants. There are multiple
`dimensions over which trades can be compared. Much of
`the recent literature focuses on the profitability of trades,
`which, roughly speaking, can be measured using the
`performance of a stock’s price after the initiation of a
`short sale. In one of the earliest articles to empirically
`examine short sales, Seneca (1967) finds a negative relation
`
`between short interest and returns and concludes that
`short positions are indicative of bearish opinions. Similarly,
`Boehme, Danielsen, and Sorescu (2006) show that when
`short selling is constrained and there are relatively diverse
`opinions, abnormally high short interest can precede
`negative future returns. Using transaction data at a higher
`frequency, Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang (2008) find that
`heavily shorted stocks significantly underperform lightly
`shorted stocks, especially stocks heavily shorted by
`non-program institutional traders; and Diether, Lee, and
`Werner (2008) show that not only do prices follow short
`selling, but short selling also follows prices, that is, short
`sellers tend to short after price run-ups. These results
`further indicate that short sellers could have an informa-
`tion advantage.2 In sum, the above work establishes that
`the performance of short sellers’ trades indicates that
`short sellers are informed traders. Our paper contributes
`to this literature by asking how short sellers come to enjoy
`an information advantage in the first place.
`
`2.2. Public news
`
`While a large literature examines volume and return
`phenomena around specific news events (e.g., earnings
`announcements, mergers, and dividend initiations and
`omissions), a more recent literature considers such phe-
`nomena around any corporate news event. Categorizing
`all Wall Street Journal stories between 1973 and 2001,
`Antweiler and Frank (2006) find that return responses
`vary widely across news categories, although they find
`evidence of overreaction (return reversal), on average.
`Also using a database of all news events, Tetlock (2011)
`finds evidence of even stronger return reversal following
`repeated news events, consistent with the idea that
`investors overreact to ‘‘stale’’ news stories. Several studies
`using comprehensive news databases examine whether
`well-known asset pricing anomalies are related to news.
`Chan (2003) considers the momentum anomaly among
`stocks with and without recent news and finds evidence
`of price momentum only among news stocks. Similarly,
`Vega (2006) finds more earnings momentum among
`stocks with high differences of opinion on news days.
`More recently, researchers have asked whether the
`content of news stories contains value-relevant informa-
`tion. Tetlock, Saar-Tsechansky, and Macskassy (2008) and
`Engelberg (2008) show that, indeed, the qualitative con-
`tent of the information contained in news stories can
`predict both earnings surprises and short-term returns.
`These findings support the idea that there is value-
`relevant or ‘‘soft’’ information in news stories that is not
`immediately impounded into prices.
`To summarize, this literature highlights the impor-
`tance of looking at more than one news category when
`
`2 A closely related dimension of research is whether short sellers’
`trades reveal information to other market participants. In other words,
`are short sellers’ trades newsworthy in and of themselves? Senchack and
`Starks (1993) show that abnormally large short interest announcements
`have small but significant negative returns. Similarly, Aitken, Frino,
`McCorry, and Swan (1998) show that short sales are followed by price
`declines within 15 minutes on the Australian Stock Exchange.
`
`CFAD VI 1071 - 0003
`
`

`
`J.E. Engelberg et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 260–278
`
`263
`
`assessing the behavior of short sellers. Moreover, it shows
`that the information content of news leaves room for
`traders with different information processing abilities to
`arrive at different conclusions about the value relevance
`of the news event. Our work builds on these findings by
`analyzing the universe of corporate news events in the
`U.S. over our sample period, and by asking whether, in our
`sample, information processing ability plays a role in the
`performance of short sellers’ trades.
`
`2.3. Public news and informed trading
`
`There are two views regarding the relation between
`the trading patterns of skilled investors and the release of
`public news items such as the articles contained in the
`Dow Jones archive. Under the first view, public informa-
`tion does not provide traders with an information advan-
`tage; that is, managers who rely on public information
`(rather than generate private information) are low-
`skilled. Consistent with this view, Kacperczyk and Seru
`(2007) estimate managers’ reliance on public information
`(RPI) as the R-squared of a regression of percentage
`changes in fund managers’ portfolio holdings on changes
`in analysts’ past recommendations and find that fund
`managers with low RPIs (low reliance on public informa-
`tion) perform better than fund managers with high RPIs
`(high reliance on public information).
`Under the alternative view, the public release of
`information presents trading opportunities for skilled
`processors of information; that is, when news is released,
`traders with superior information processing skills can
`convert this news into valuable information for trading
`(Kandel and Pearson, 1995). Earnings announcements, for
`example, are often accompanied by lengthy documents
`and conference calls that are scrutinized by information
`processors. Those traders who show exceptional skill in
`converting such data into value-relevant information are
`rewarded with superior returns on event-driven trades.
`Evidence consistent with this view comes from studies
`that attempt to look at the textual content of news and firm
`announcements. Specifically, Tetlock, Saar-Tsechansky, and
`Macskassy (2008), Engelberg (2008), Demers and Vega
`(2008), and Feldman, Govindaraj, Livnat, and Segal (2009)
`all show that the content of corporate news predicts returns,
`which is consistent with the view that information proces-
`sing skills can generate superior returns.
`Our paper sheds light on the above debate by finding
`additional evidence in support of the second view by
`showing that trades occurring after the release of news
`stories can be more profitable than trades in non-news
`periods.
`
`3. Hypotheses and methodology
`
`3.1. Hypothesis development
`
`hypotheses that aim to explore the source of short sellers’
`profitability.
`The timing of trades is one of the areas in which short
`sellers can differ from other traders. Prior research finds
`some evidence that short sellers trade before public
`information is released (see, e.g., Karpoff and Lou, 2010;
`Christophe, Ferri, and Angel, 2004). Similarly, the Secu-
`rities and Exchange Commission has suggested that short
`sellers spread ‘‘false rumors’’ in an effort to manipulate
`firms. Furthermore, in the popular press, there have been
`allegations of insider trading by well-known hedge funds
`such as SAC Capital Advisors and Galleon.3,4 Although
`there are many possible channels through which short
`sellers’ trades could be profitable, our first set of hypoth-
`eses seeks to empirically test whether the timing of short
`sales is different than that of other trades. We refer to this
`as the Anticipation hypothesis. Formally:
`
`H1. In the presence of news events, short sellers trade
`before other traders.
`
`This hypothesis is an alternative to the null hypothesis
`that there is no difference in timing.
`We next turn to the profitability of short sellers’ trades
`around news events. The literature is split as to whether
`news events increase or decrease asymmetric informa-
`tion, thereby increasing or decreasing the profitability of
`informed trades. On the one hand, many papers model
`news events as points in time associated with reduced
`information asymmetry (see, e.g., Korajczyk, Lucas, and
`McDonald, 1991; Diamond and Verrecchia, 1987). If news
`events do indeed reduce asymmetric information, the trades
`of informed traders (e.g., short sales) should be less profit-
`able on news days. On the other hand, other papers suggest
`that public news events are subject to differential inter-
`pretations by traders (see, e.g., Rubinstein, 1993; Kandel and
`Pearson, 1995). Under this view, public information events
`present profitable trading opportunities for skilled informa-
`tion processors, and thus, the trades of informed traders
`(e.g., short sellers) should be more profitable after news
`days. This discussion leads to the following set of hypoth-
`eses, which we call the Profitability hypotheses:
`
`H2a. Short sales are less profitable after news announ-
`cements.
`
`H2b. Short sales are more profitable after news announ-
`cements.
`
`These hypotheses rest against the backdrop of the null
`hypothesis, which states that short sales are as profitable
`after news events as they are at other times.
`Since our empirical work finds that short sales are
`more profitable after news events, we also explore why
`profitability increases. While the literature finds that
`news events create trading opportunities for informed
`
`In this section, we formalize many of the ideas introduced
`in the beginning of the paper. Our first set of hypotheses
`concerns the timing of trades, while the second set concerns
`the profitability of trades. Finally, we have two sets of
`
`3 E.g., Rothfeld, M., Pulliam, S., Bray, C., 2011. Fund titan found
`guilty—Rajaratnam convicted of insider trading; Jurors cite tapes: ‘Just a
`lot of evidence.’ The Wall Street Journal, 12 May.
`4 Our approach is not designed to detect specific instances of insider
`trading, but rather,
`it is designed to examine the average trading
`patterns of short sellers.
`
`CFAD VI 1071 - 0004
`
`

`
`264
`
`J.E. Engelberg et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 260–278
`
`traders (see, e.g., Engelberg, 2008; Demers and Vega,
`2008), other potential explanations exist. The first alter-
`native explanation posits that some buyers make sys-
`tematic mistakes around news events (see, e.g., Antweiler
`and Frank, 2006), and that these mistakes are reflected in
`market makers’ offsetting short sales. We formalize this
`idea in our third set of hypotheses, which we call the
`Uninformed counterparty hypotheses:
`
`H3. The profitability of short sales comes from market
`makers’ offsetting trades.
`
`This hypothesis rests against the null hypothesis that
`the profitability of short sales comes equally from market
`maker and non-market maker trades.
`Another alternative explanation relates to liquidity.
`Given the increase in volume around news events, news
`events could provide a trading opportunity for those
`traders for whom liquidity is an important factor in a
`trade’s profitability. As a result, the perceived profitability
`of short sales around news events could have nothing to
`do with information; rather, short sellers could simply be
`trading around news events because news events create
`liquidity, which allows them to execute profitable trades.
`This relation between news events and liquidity is the
`basis for our fourth and final set of hypotheses, which we
`call the Liquidity hypotheses:
`
`H4. The profitability of short sales around news events is
`due to the increased liquidity that news events provide.
`
`The null hypothesis is that the profitability of short
`sales around news events is not a result of the liquidity
`that news events provide.
`
`3.2. Data
`
`To test the hypotheses developed above, we employ
`two main databases. The first database contains informa-
`tion on short sales, while the second contains news
`articles from the Dow Jones archive.
`
`3.2.1. Short sales
`Information on short sales comes from the NYSE Trade
`and Quote (TAQ) Regulation SHO database. Regulation
`SHO was adopted by the SEC in June of 2004 to establish
`new rules governing short sales in equity transactions and
`to evaluate the effectiveness of price test restrictions on
`short sales. As one consequence of Regulation SHO, transac-
`tion-level short sales data were publicly disclosed. The
`Regulation SHO database covers the period January 3, 2005
`through July 6, 2007 and contains data for all short sales that
`were reported to the NYSE for NYSE-listed and traded
`securities during this period.5 The database contains the
`stock ticker, the date and time of the transaction, the number
`of shares traded, and the execution price. While the data
`allow us to observe the opening of short positions, they do
`
`5 The vast majority of trades in the database are for NYSE-listed
`securities. Occasionally, securities that are not listed on the NYSE do
`trade on the NYSE, and these trades also appear in the Regulation SHO
`database.
`
`not contain information on the covering of these short
`positions. Thus, like other papers, we are constrained by
`the lack of information on short-covering transactions. In
`addition, the data also include an indicator that denotes
`whether a transaction was exempt from price test rules. One
`of the reasons a short sale transaction could be classified as
`exempt is that it was made by market makers engaged in
`bona fide market making activity. The exempt indicator has
`thus been used to separate trading by market makers from
`trading by non-market makers (see, e.g., Evans, Geczy, Musto,
`and Reed, 2009; Christophe, Ferri, and Angel, 2004; Boehmer,
`Jones, and Zhang, 2008; Chakrabarty and Shkilko, 2011).6
`However, when Regulation SHO was implemented, a group
`of randomly selected stocks was chosen to be part of a pilot
`study for which the exempt/non-exempt classification was
`no longer required. We exclude these pilot firms when using
`the exempt indicator variable in our analyses (i.e., Tables 6
`and 7).7
`For the purposes of our analysis, we aggregate the
`transaction data to the daily level, and we use the TAQ
`master files to add CUSIPs to the database. We then use
`the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) Daily
`Stock Event file to add PERMNOs to the database. Finally,
`we add returns, closing bid price, closing ask price, total
`volume, and shares outstanding from CRSP. Using these
`data, we calculate the Amihud (2002) illiquidity measure
`defined as 107  9retit9/volumeit, where volumeit
`is the
`dollar volume, and we calculate the daily bid-ask spread
`as a percentage of the closing mid-price.
`In addition, we add information on the daily volume-
`weighted rebate rate for equity loans in each stock over
`the sample period. The rebate rate for an equity loan is
`the rate at which interest on collateral is rebated back to
`the borrower. Thus, the rate is inversely related to the cost
`of shorting a stock. Our data on rebate rates come from a
`proprietary database on equity loan transactions as
`described in Kolasinski, Reed, and Ringgenberg (2011).
`The data are compiled by a third-party provider that is
`both a market maker in the equity loan market and a data
`aggregator for major equity lenders.
`
`3.2.2. Dow Jones archive
`To compile our sample of news events, we use the Dow
`Jones archive as in Tetlock (2010). This archive contains
`all Dow Jones News Service stories and Wall Street Journal
`stories over our 2005–2007 sample period. Each observa-
`tion in the news database is a news item; each news
`item includes at least one subject code and Dow Jones’s
`designation of the corporations that are mentioned in an
`article and are the subject of the story. Table 1 displays an
`example article and the associated entry in the Dow Jones
`archive. The database contains subject codes that identify
`
`6 For example, National Association Of Securities Dealers (NASD)
`Notice to Members 06-53 notes that ‘‘Rule 5100(c)(1) provides an
`exception to the bid test for short sales by a market maker registered
`in the security in connection with bona fide market making activity.’’
`7 Details regarding the Regulation SHO pilot study, including a list of
`firms involved, are available on the SEC Web site: http://www.sec.gov/
`rules/other/34-50104.htm. Our results are robust to the inclusion of the
`Regulation SHO pilot firms.
`
`CFAD VI 1071 - 0005
`
`

`
`J.E. Engelberg et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 260–278
`
`265
`
`Table 1
`Dow Jones archive.
`The table provides an example of the information contained in the Dow Jones archive. Panel A displays the text of an example article, while Panel B contains
`the associated entry in the Dow Jones archive. The archive entry contains the date and time the article was released as well as the stock symbols of firms
`mentioned in the article and a series of subject codes that identify the content areas of the article. For example, the code RND indicates that the article
`pertained to research and development. Articles can have more than one time stamp, indicating that the article was updated following its initial release.
`
`Panel A: Example news article
`
`GlaxoSmithKline and EPIX Pharmaceuticals
`Enter Drug Discovery and Development Alliance
`
`DOW Jones Newswires
`Epix Pharmaceuticals Inc. (EPIX) said it entered into a drug discovery and development pact with GlaxoSmithKline (GSK). As part of deal, Epix will
`receive an upfront payment of $35 million, which includes $17.5 million from the sale of 3 million shares of its common stock.
`Epix will also be eligible for up to $1.2 billion for the achievement of certain milestones, and royalties on product sales. Epix shares closed Monday
`unchanged at $5.52 and Glaxo shares fell 9 cents to $52.43. Epix said it expects to end 2006 with more than $100 million in cash and marketable
`securities. The company expects that its existing cash and marketable securities together with the expected revenue from the GlaxoSmithKline
`collaboration and other partnerships will be sufficient to fund operations through 2008.
`
`Panel B: Dow Jones archive values for the example article
`
`Story code¼20061212003980
`Date¼12/12/2006
`Time¼06:12:00:29, 06:12:02:36, 06:12:16:34, 06:12:24:59
`Stock symbols¼EPIX, GSK
`Subject codes¼CNW, DJEN, DJGP, DJGS, DJGV, DJI, DJIN, DJIV, FCTV, SPOT, WEI, RND, HDL
`
`the information content of each news article; for example,
`in Table 1 the subject code RND indicates that the article
`contains information about research and development.
`We adopt Dow Jones’s subject categorizations, which
`give us 71 different news categories. However, many of
`these subject codes are general codes that do not provide
`valuable information about the content of a news article.
`For example, nearly every article in the database has the
`code CNW, indicating that the article contains company
`news,
`in addition to a more specific news code. We
`remove these general codes from our analysis to obtain
`a final list of subject codes that contains 39 different news
`categories.8 Finally, if news is released before the market
`closes at 4:00 PM, we assign the current trading day to the
`news story; if news occurs after 4:00 PM, we assign the
`next trading day.
`The resulting news database contains the date and
`time an article was released, a unique firm identifier,
`subject codes, and a dummy variable that takes the value
`of one if a story was released in multiple pieces over the
`news day. The data also contain two dictionary-based
`sentiment score variables that indicate whether a st

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket