throbber
Studies in Income and Wealth
`
`Volume 58
`
`
`
`-— -‘--w-smu-n--—-—v--—-+-‘—--—r----w—a'--————~......._,4;—
`
`
`
`
`
`Iofiafimumazmmmmmzn. _
`mm mauumon, w/a rznmssnem, IS FR0H%E1;TE::
`
`
`
`The Economics of
`New Goods
`
`Edited by
`
`Timothy E Bresnahan and
`Robert J. Gordon
`
`Page 1 of 5
`
`SENJU EXHIBIT 2151
`LUPIN v. SENJU
`IPR2015-01100
`
`

`
`
`
`7
`
`7.1
`
`Introduction
`
`The introduction of Tagamet into the U.S. market in 1977 marked the begin
`ning of a revolutionary treatment for ulcers and the emergence of a new ind 1
`try. What distinguished the products of this new industry was their ability
`heal ulcers and treat preulcer conditions pharmacologically on an outpati
`basis, thereby substituting for traditional, and costly, hospital admissions
`surgeries. Tagamet, known medically as an I-I,-receptor antagonist, promo
`the healing of ulcers by reducing the secretion of acid by the stomach.
`__
`A striking feature of the antiulcer market is that it has sustained growth M
`sales (quantity, not just revenue) for over fifteen years and still shows no
`of slowing. New prescribing habits have clearly diffused to an ever increasm
`number of physicians. Today there are a total of four H2-receptor antago__
`Tagamet, Zantac, Pepcid, and Axid. Zantac is now the United States’ (and..th‘
`worlds) largest-selling prescription drug, having estimated worldwid6,..s_,
`in 1992. of about $3.5 billion. Moreover, Tagarnet is also among the ten t"
`selling prescription drugs in the United States.‘
`-
`
`Ernst R. Bemdt is professor of applied economics at the Sloan School of Management?’
`Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Linda T. But is assistant professor of economics at Bo
`University. David H. Lucking-Reiley is assistant professor of economics at Vanderbilt U,I1i_\il'-1:5"
`Glen L. Urban is professor of marketing and dean of the Sloan School of Management
`Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
`Financial support from the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation is gratefully'.aCkn0Wiedged."asf—
`data support of Stephen C. Chappell, Nancy Duckwitz. and Richard Fehring at IMS Intern_at:i_,
`and Joan Curran, Marjorie Donnelly. Phyllis Rausch, Ditas Riad, Paul Snydcrrnan, and _le
`lowe at Merck & Co. The authors have also benefited from the research assistance of Adi
`Ami: Alon, Ittai I-larel. Michele Lombardi, and Bonnie Scouler, and from discussions wi
`
`
`
`The Roles of Marketing, Product.-.
`Quality, and Price Competitio_n_
`in the Growth and Composition
`of the U.S. Antiulcer
`
`Drug Industry
`
`Emst R. Berndt, Linda '1". Bui, David H. Lucking—Reiley,
`and Glen L. Urban
`
`Robert C. Feenstra and Clinton R. Shiells
`
`
`(2) if price is mismeasured, so is the dependent variable, but then their formula
`for the coefficient becomes (13 + 1 )(U ‘ 1 )a 3115111153 i1'flP1i9d U 2 1-215 CV5“
`less credible.
`
`“Aging of lines”: Once popular restaurants lose customers over time. We
`could bring in new ones and make an adjustment for their superiority. But then.
`some time later, the chefs are hired away and the old restaurants regain their
`share. Will we come back to the same level? How?
`A major finding is that if one allows for the changing mix of import goods
`this leads to lower estimates of their income elasticity. That makes sense, but
`how low “should” the import income elasticity be? Can one really explain
`rising world trade just by the reduction in transport costs and the rising quality
`of traded goods? I find the notion that traded goods have higher income elastic-
`ities quite plausible. The explicit “bias" adjustment to the price index that fol-
`lows is, however, more problematic. But the advice to collect more data is
`surely right!
`
`References
`
`Berry, S. T. 1994. Estimating discrete-choice models of product differentiation. Rana‘
`Journal afEconomi'cs 25, no. 2 (summer): 242-62.
`‘
`_
`Griliches, Zvi, and Iain Cockburn. 1994. Generics and new goods in pharmaceutical
`price indexes. American Economic Review 84 (5): 1213-32.
`Hanoch, Giora. 1971. CRESI-I production functions. Ecanometrica 39 (5): 695-712.
`Trajtenberg, Manuel. 1990. Product
`innovation, price indices and the (mis-)
`measurement of economic performance. NBER Working Paper no. 3261. Cam-
`bridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
`
`Page 2 of 5
`
`

`
`E. R. Berndt, L. T. Bui, D. H. Lucking-Reiley, and G. L. Urban
`__.___________________i
`
`297
`
`The U.S. Antiulcer Drug Industry
`
`by total industry patient-days, one would implicitly be assuming that the vari-
`ous drugs are perfectly substitutable. To circumvent this problem, we employ
`the economic theory of price indexes and calculate the industry price using the
`Fisher-Ideal price index."
`in tenns of quality, to the extent that product-quality characteristics affect
`the size of the potential market, they should be included in an overall industry
`demand equation. We would expect that the size ofthe potential patient market
`would depend on the specific indications for which the FDA has granted
`approval. We shall concentrate on one particular indication. GERD, which
`represented an especially large potential new market, and for which the H2-
`antagonists first received FDA approval relatively late in the sample. Specifi-
`cally. when the FDA granted approval to Glaxo’s Zantac for GERD. Zantac
`detailcrs were permitted to provide specific infomiation to physicians concom-
`ing the treatment of GERD. This was significant, for instead of being confined
`to detailing to gastroenterologists who saw ulcer patients, now Zantac detailers
`also made calls on general practitioners who commonly saw patients having
`GERD symptoms. This undoubtedly expanded the potential market.
`Such reasoning suggests that a dummy variable, say, GERD (taking the
`value of I following FDA approval), be employed in the overall industry de-
`mand equation. However, it is worth noting that information concerning the
`efficacy of drugs for different indications typically diffuses prior to formal
`FDA approval. The medical community is often aware of results of clinical
`trials prior to the FDA’s reviewing the clinical-trial data and coming to a final
`decision concerning approval for a new indication. As a result, a great deal of
`prescribing is done off-label prior to the FDA‘s granting approval. Thus, it is
`not clear how reliable the GERD dummy variable will be in capturing major
`changes in the size of the potential patient base.
`The third set of factors affecting industry demand involves marketing ef-
`forts. Earlier we noted that, in this industry, the two principal forms of market-
`ing efforts are minutes of detailing and either pages or deflated dollars of medi-
`cal joumal advertising. There are several
`important
`issues concerning the
`measurement of marketing efforts. First. since drug marketing is largely a mat-
`ter of providing information about the existence and usefulness of the product,
`we expect its impact to be long-lived; once a physician has been informed, it
`is hard to see how such information might be destroyed. Indeed. precisely be-
`cause of this durability, firms typically expend a particularly large amount of
`marketing effort in the early stages of a new products life. Hence the impact
`of marketing on sales is likely better measured by the cumulative stock of
`marketing efforts since product launch, rather than simply by the flow of cur-
`
`l4. Specifically, the Fisher-Ideal price index is the geometric mean of the Laspcyres and
`
`rent monthly expenditures. We will also want to allow for the possibility that
`this stock of information depreciates or deteriorates over time. although we
`might expect the depreciation rate to be quite low.‘
`We therefore employ the well—known perpetual—mventory method. Let M, be
`the stock of marketing effort atthe end of month 2 (as measureguby the stpcgl:
`of journal advertising and detailing minutes), let 8 be th_6 H1011 Y |‘3_° ° _
`preciation of this stock. and let m, be the flow of marketing effort during time
`eriod t. Define M, as the depreciation-adjusted stock of marketmg effort car-
`Eied over from the last month (1 - 3 )M,_, . P1U5 new marketing °ff°“5 during
`months 2 (m,), that is
`
`(1)
`
`M=(l —s>M.-.+m.= 2 <1-5>"‘"*v
`'
`v I I
`
`We construct separate stock measures for detailing and for journal advertising.
`Unlike the typical case for capital-stock accounting, we have no problem W111
`establishing benchmark or “starting values" since we know that prior to August
`1977, the Tagamet journal (and detailing) stocks were aero. To implement
`equation (1), one must however assume rates of depreciation for each of these
`stocks. As discussed below, we will use the historical data on marltetl|_1g and
`sales to estimate 8 econometrically.rather than assume its value afipnon. an
`The other major issue in measuring the effects of marketing e orts en 1 8
`an innovation of this paper. Other authors have suggested that advertisrrigbe
`modeled as having two simultaneous effects in the market: overall advertising
`by all firms affecting overall market demand. and relative levels of advertising
`among firms affecting the individual lions’ market shares." Wehtalte
`cling one step further here by hypothesizing that firms may c glosethté other
`their marketing efforts to emphasize one of the.two effects more
`an
`.
`Although the degree to which firms’ marketing efforts are directed, say._at
`overall market expansion cannot be difficllll °b5°“’ed f'°"‘ dafa ‘Ti qugiguceff
`of marketing done by firms, we now propose a method for estima ng
`fect cconometrically.
`_
`To clarify this concept, we discuss it in the context of the antiulcer drug
`market When SmithKline marketed Tagamet from its introduction in 1977
`until the entry ofZantac in 1983. they did not wony about c:fmP:11“S f‘t’1'1;‘na:
`ket share in the H3-antagonist markel._for Patel“ Sm“5_ F°
`‘:1’
`‘Ed map
`temporary monopoly position. From tins monopoly posit1on,_ e go
`T
`keting for SmithKline was to convince more and more physicians ofthe untitty
`of H,—antagonists in treating ulcer patients. They, and no other filrpr, reapflisg
`rewards ofhaving expended efforts on diffusing lIlfO1'l'l‘IaI1(l>-;'l on 2 8:“: Zan-
`to physicians, since they held 100 percent market share.
`owever,
`
`

`
`E- R- Berfldt. L. T. Bui, D. H. Luckiiig-Reiley, and G. L. Urban
`
`
`
`311 The US. Antiulcer Drug Industry
`
`table 7.2 focus only on relative quantifies (market shares), but leave fixed the
`We of total ‘“d“S“'Y demand 351 Say. Q; denote these price elasticities by ei‘.
`A total—price elasticity also captures the impact of a product’s price change (in
`total industry demand; denote such a price elasticity by 2” (no asterisk). As
`has been 5h°Wn _bY- inter alia, Berndt and Wood (1979), the relationship be»
`tween eff and e”. is as follows:
`
`cumulative detailing or cumulative medical journal advertising is a more ap-
`propriate measure of marketing impacts than are current monthly expendi-
`tures. In the context of industry demand, we distinguish investments of firms
`in these marketing activities by the industry structure prevailing when the ex-
`penditures originally occurred. In a monopoly market structure, all marketing
`expenditures are market—expanding, for the monopolist has I00 percent market
`share. In a market structure with k products, however, marketing activities be-
`come more rivalrous, and as k becomes large, we expect relatively little “spill—
`over” of a firm’s marketing efforts in affecting industry demand. We have hy-
`pothesized, therefore, that in terms of affecting industry demand, the relative
`effects of marketing expenditures originally made when k products were in the
`market will tend to decline as It increases. In other words, we hypothesize that
`the effectiveness of marketing in generating industry sales depends on market
`structure in a systematic manner.
`.
`In our empirical analysis of the antiulcer drug market, we obtained consider-
`able but not quite unanimous support for this hypothesis. In particular, nor-
`malizing the impact of a monopolist‘s marketing investments on current sales
`to unity, we estimated the impact in a duopoly to be 0.6, in a three-product
`industry to be 0.8, and in a four-product market to be 0.5; these last three
`numbers are all statistically significantly different from unity (implying that
`we reject the hypothesis that the effectiveness of marketing efforts is indepen-
`dent of market structure), and from zero (indicating that we reject the hypothe-
`sis that once there is competition, the only impact of marketing is on market
`share, and there is none on overall market size). Thus our results suggest that
`in the antiulcer drug market there is clear evidence of spillovers, and that these
`spillovers are considerably less than 100 percent effective. Moreover, for the
`most part, these spillovers decline as the number of products in the industry in-
`creases.
`
`Second, we find that at the industry level, both cumulative minutes of detail-
`ing and cumulative pages of medical journal advertising affect sales; typical
`estimates of these elasticities are 0.5 and 0.2, respectively. At the market—share
`level, relative sales of products are also positively related to relative cumulative
`minutes of detailing; this elasticity is typically in the range of 0.7 to 0.9. To-
`gether these results imply that the marketing efforts of firms in the antiulcer
`drug market had substantial effects, in terms of affecting both market shares
`and the size of the overall industry.
`Third, a somewhat unexpected result we obtained is that at the industry
`level, the rate of depreciation of stocks of both minutes of detailing and ,m’edi.-.=
`cal journal advertising was estimated to be zero. We believe that this: result.
`rcflects the fact that market-expanding marketing primati1y.involvesinformi=rig:
`physicians about the usefulness of this class of drugs, and that once a.physic.ian
`begins prescribing these drugs, he or she is not likely to-forget aboutstheir
`
`61 Q.
`
`a1
`
`a1 P
`
`_
`
`((3121?) (8li:PJ.)’
`E” _ €’fl‘2:5 +
`lisdthe ‘?l“3“lit.‘l demanded of productj,.Q is total industry demand,
`S m ustry price. The first partial derivative in equation (10) can be
`to equal unity (other things being equal, demand for product j grows
`equiproportionally with market demand, i.e., according to its market share)
`while the second partial. derivative is the industry— or market—price elasticity
`(estimated values of which are given in table 7.1). The last partial derivative
`in equation (10) indicates the impact of a change in product j's price on the
`overall industry price index; it can be approximated by the revenue share of
`product _] in total industry revenues.
`Alternative OLS and 2SLS estimates of er are given in table 7 2 While NLS
`,
`‘
`'1}
`.
`_

`3
`and NL-2SLS estimates of the industry-price elasticity are presented in table
`7.1. For the two—product market, 1993 drugstore revenue shares for Tagaincr
`and Zaritac are approximately 0.25 and 0.75. For the f0ur—product marker
`m':i5‘:)5:9a‘e:
`approximately 0-19 ('I_'agam'et).'0.60 (Zantac). 0.12 (Pepcid),
`)- T0g8LT1er. these relationships imply that in the two—product
`LS estimates of the total own-price demand elasticities for Taga-
`met and Zantac are approximately -l.l54 and — 1.690 respectively while in
`the four-product market. the 2SLS estimated total own~price demand elasticity
`IS *0-909 for Tagamet. -1.153 for Zantac, —0.s2o for Pepcid and -0 799
`for Axid. Note that while these point estimates imply that some (if the deniand
`elasticities are less than one in absolute magnitude the associated standard
`errors may well. imply that reasonable confidence intervals include values of
`one and above (in absolute value).
`
`7.6 Concluding Remarks
`
`In this paper we have attempted to explain the phenomenal growth of the
`‘I-Ifantagonist antiulcer drug industry in the United States, as well as changes
`11111 the market shares garnered by the various products over time. Although we
`fave eiéamined the roles of product quality, order of entry, and price, we have
`091133 Particular attention on the role of various marketing efforts. Our
`framework and results can be summarized as follows.
`h Firlst, miarketing efforts suchas detailing and medical journal advertising
`
`Page 4 of 5
`
`

`
`E. R. Berndt, L. T. Bui, D. H. Luclting-Reiley, and G. L. Urban
`
`
`
`313 The U8. Antiulcer Drug Industry
`
`(Tagamet, Zantac, Pepcid, and Axid), we find that the market—share impact of
`the stock of detailing minutes deteriorated at an annual rate of around 40 per-
`cent, reflecting perhaps a more rivalrous content of marketing efforts.
`The remarkable growth in the market share of Zantac over time can be par-
`tially expliined, then, by the very substantial marketing efforts undertaken by
`Glaxo. However, pricing policies also had an impact. Zantac gained share over
`Tagainet in part because the price premium commanded by Zantac declined
`from about 56 percent in 1983 to only 25 percent in 1993. Our estimates of
`indiistry—piice elasticities range from about -0.7 to -0.9, while estimates of
`cross—price elasticities between any pair of the four products are about 0.7.
`Another set of important factors affecting sales of antiulcer drugs concerns
`product—quality attributes. At the industry level, the evidence suggests that the
`size of the market was enlarged considerably when the FDA granted approval
`for the GERD indication-—a condition that occurs in a relatively large popula-
`tion. At the marl-cet—share level, we find that when a product had a GERD-
`approval advantage relative to other products, its market share increased. Thus
`another reason why Zantac fared so well in the marketplace is that for quite
`some time it was the only product that had received FDA approval for the
`treatment of GERD. Another variable affecting market share significantly is
`the number of adverse interactions with other drugs reported to the FDA. On
`this accountT'agamet fared relatively badly (by 1993, Tagamet had twelve drug
`interactions, Zantac and Axid had only one, and Pepcid had none). Thus Zan-
`tac also enjoyed advantages from this product-quality characteristic. Ari unex-
`pected result we obtained, however, was that dosing frequency did not appear
`to affect market shares in a statistically significant manner.
`Finally, we found that, as in many other markets, order-of-entry effects are
`very substantial. In particular, holding constant price, marketing efforts, and
`product quality relative to the nth product, the (rt + l)th entrant can expect
`about forty percent lower sales.
`The results of this paper are of considerable interest in the current health-
`care reform debate. Critics of the pharmaceutical industry have argued that
`much detailing is merely aimed at market share and is socially wasteful. Some
`have suggested placing ceilings on the marketing activities of pharmaceutical
`firms, but our findings demonstrate that this could have negative social welfare
`impacts. The findings in this paper suggest that marketing efforts also play a
`very important role in the diffusion of information to physicians, although the
`degree to which this is true probably declines somewhat as the number ofprod-
`ucts in a market increases. Moreover, our results suggest that in order to over-
`come pioneer-product advantages, later entrants have found it necessary to
`advertise more intensively. An implication of these results is that if all pharma-
`ceutical firms were constrained in their marketing activities, it is possible that
`the benefits would accrue primarily to the pioneer firms, at the expense of later
`
`vantages. Thus, such a policy could have anticompetitive impacts, although it
`would be consistent with a patent system that rewards innovation.
`_
`The research reported in this paper should be extended in a number of ways.
`First although the industry and market- share equations are plausible and pro-
`vide important initial evidence on the roles of marketing, price, and product-
`quality competition in the antiulcer market, the underlying models could be
`modified in a number of useful ways. The most obvious exltension
`Itgurfl;
`formulate the models withrn an explicitly dynamic diffusion rami=i\i:ioffi,JSi0n
`as those involving the Gompertz, logistic. OT 011'l€T 11101? $e11e13_ _‘
`_
`curve formulations. In such a framework, marketing and P1'1C111g P01113135 1111811‘
`not only affect the long-run or equilibrium level of demand, but they might
`also affect the speed at which a long-run equilibrium level is approached.
`As second useful extension would involve incorporating data on direct—to—
`consumer marketing. In I988 SmithKline experimented with a “Tommy
`Tummy” television advertising campaign that was aimed directly at consumers
`but did not mention Tagamet by name. More recently, Glaxo has advertised in
`magazines and on television, suggesting that patients with hearfiblzlsrlihiiilfilflafiigo
`discomfort should see their physicians. Thfisfi ads 313 5P°11591°
`3’
`Research Institute and, consistent with FDA regulations on direct-to—consumer
`.
`.
`.
`.
`.t
`advertising, do not mention the Zantadproduct by namle unjlegs thet1::]Sl;1:dE_=
`warning and other product information 1S also fully disc osel .
`_ incet ‘S more
`vertisements typically do not mention products names. E11611’ "T1930 _1
`likely to be on industry demand than on market share. Moreover, direct-to-
`consumer advertising may change the physician-patient inforination-sharing
`relationship and therefore could modify the diffusion process. It would be
`useful to exiimine whether such effects have actually occurred, and by exten-
`sion, how effective is direct-to-consumer marketing in the aritiulcer market-
`place.
`.
`_
`.
`Third, and perhaps most importantly. 1113 fi11d1I1_8S Of 11115 231$’ 5“g[_geS;1‘::::'
`e-sting topics in the theory of 11'1Cil1SII‘1ai organization. What is
`e op tin
`keting strategy for firms when there are spillovers and marketing activities haV€
`.
`.
`.
`-
`-
`-
`'
`h .
`‘
`long-lived impacts’? What is the correspondingly optimal Pl'1C1118_ 133 “V101
`How does this optimal behavior vary with market structure? How is the opti-
`.
`-
`-
`'
`th
`mal behavior affected by federal tax provisions that alloqwutlfiie :3XPe1:;:1§1(11":ic:
`than amortizing) of long—lived marketing investments.
`3 316
`P
`tions for social welfare?
`.
`Obviously much remains to be done. We believe we have demonstrated
`quite clearly that marketing efforts are very important in understanding the
`diffusion and economic success of new products. Product quality and pricing
`behavior have also been shown to play i1T1P01'15a111 W135
`tit‘: dlffifstiggI1:::e'::_::
`We hope the results of this paper contribute to this an of or re aoducts
`I
`projects that enrich our understanding of the economics 0 new pr
`.-
`M
`
`:2
`
`Page 5 of 5

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket