throbber
Are Physicians "Easy Marks"? Quantifying the Effects of Detailing and Sampling on New
`Prescriptions
`Author(s): Natalie Mizik and Robert Jacobson
`Source: Management Science, Vol. 50, No. 12 (Dec., 2004), pp. 1704-1715
`Published by: INFORMS
`Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/30048061 .
`Accessed: 20/01/2015 13:37
`
`Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
`http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
`
` .
`JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
`content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
`of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
`
` .
`
`INFORMS is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Management Science.
`
`http://www.jstor.org
`
`This content downloaded from 208.85.77.1 on Tue, 20 Jan 2015 13:37:52 PM
`All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
`
`Page 1 of 13
`
`SENJU EXHIBIT 2207
`LUPIN v. SENJU
`IPR2015-01099
`
`

`
`MANAGEMENT
`SCIENCE
`Vol. 50, No. 12, December 2004, pp. 1704-1715
`ISSN 0025-1909 1 EISSN 1526-5501 104150121 1704
`
`infimeR
`DOI 10.1287/mnsc.1040.0281
`f 2004 INFORMS
`
`Are
`
`Marks"?
`Physicians
`Quantifying the
`"Easy
`and
`Effects
`of Detailing
`Sampling
`New
`Prescriptions
`Natalie Mizik
`Graduate School of Business, Columbia University, 3022 Broadway, New York, New York 10027-6902, nm2079@columbia.edu
`Robert Jacobson
`Department of Marketing, School of Business, University of Washington, Seattle, Washington 98195-3200,
`yusho@u.washington.edu
`
`on
`
`public attention and considerable controversy surround pharmaceutical marketing practices and their
`Much
`impact on physicians. However, views on the matter have largely been shaped by anecdotal evidence or
`results from analyses with insufficient controls. Making use of a dynamic fixed-effects distributed lag regres-
`sion model, we empirically assess the role that two central components of pharmaceutical marketing practices
`(namely, detailing and sampling) have on physician prescribing behavior. Key differentiating features of our
`model include its ability to (i) capture persistence in the prescribing process and decompose it into own-growth
`and competitive-stealing effects, (ii) estimate an unrestricted decay structure of the promotional effects over
`time, and (iii) control for physician-specific effects that, if not taken into account, induce biased coefficient esti-
`mates of detailing and sampling effects. Based on pooled time series cross-sectional data involving three drugs,
`24 monthly observations, and 74,075 individual physicians (more than 2 million observations in total), we find
`that detailing and free drug samples have positive and statistically significant effects on the number of new
`prescriptions issued by a physician. However, we find that the magnitudes of the effects are modest.
`Key words: pharmaceutical marketing; salesforce effectiveness
`History: Accepted by Linda Green, public sector applications; received March 8, 2004. This paper was with the
`authors 1 month for 1 revision.
`
`Introduction
`industry's promotional tactics lead to an increase in
`appropriate versus inappropriate use of drugs in a
`As the cost of prescription drugs continues to escalate,
`cost-effective manner.
`increased public attention is being focused on the
`Concern that pharmaceutical marketing practices
`marketing practices of the pharmaceutical firms as
`have exacerbated increases in public health costs has
`one source of the problem. Direct-to-physician activ-
`prompted government actions at the federal and state
`ities account for the bulk of U.S. pharmaceutical
`levels. For example, in 2002 the federal government
`firm promotional spending. IMS Health (2003) esti-
`issued a warning to the drug industry to curtail some
`mates that over $5.8 billion was spent in 2002 on
`of their marketing practices (Washington Post 2002).
`detailing, i.e., pharmaceutical sales representatives
`H.R. 2356, which calls for ongoing annual funding of
`(PSRs) visiting physicians to promote their firm's
`$75 million to conduct comparative cost-effectiveness
`drugs. In addition, the retail value of the free drug
`drug studies, was introduced in Congress in June
`samples distributed during these visits is estimated
`2003. A primary intent of this legislation is to pro-
`at $11.5 billion.
`vide objective scientific evidence to "reduce doctors'
`A detailing visit typically lasts two to five minutes
`reliance on marketing information from the pharma-
`during which time a PSR discusses one to three of
`ceutical industry" (Pear 2003). Given the fact that one
`the company's drugs. Information (and, at times, mis-
`of every five dollars spent on pharmaceutical drugs in
`information) about a drug's composition, therapeutic
`the United States is paid for by a state program, state
`value, proper dosage, and potential side effects is
`governments have also taken steps to counter PSR
`communicated (Zigler et al. 1995). Often, PSRs will
`influence. Most notably, several states have under-
`also dispense samples and possibly offer small gifts
`taken counterdetailing initiatives (Gold 2001). State
`to the physician. At issue is whether these interac-
`employees visit physicians in hopes of persuading
`tions with PSRs compromise physician integrity and
`them to switch from prescribing branded drugs to
`affect their prescribing behavior. More precisely, the
`key public policy issue is the extent to which the
`prescribing lower-cost generic drugs.
`1704
`
`This content downloaded from 208.85.77.1 on Tue, 20 Jan 2015 13:37:52 PM
`All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
`
`Page 2 of 13
`
`

`
`Mizik and Jacobson: Quantifying the Effects of Detailing and Sampling on New Prescriptions
`Management Science 50(12), pp. 1704-1715, v 2004 INFORMS
`
`1705
`
`Prescription drug expenditures are projected to
`remain the fastest-growing sector of health care
`expenditures. They are expected to account for 14.5%
`of $3.1 trillion health care expenditures by 2012
`(compared with approximately 10% in 2001). With
`recent legislation providing a Medicare drug benefit
`expected to cost the federal government $534 billion
`over the next decade, it is no wonder that the impact
`of pharmaceutical industry marketing practices is of
`keen interest to policymakers, the business commu-
`nity, and the general public.
`Two competing views have dominated discussion
`on the matter. The prevailing view contends that
`PSRs significantly influence physicians' prescribing
`behavior and that this influence has negative effect
`on patients' welfare, in that PSRs encourage physi-
`cians to prescribe more expensive branded drugs.
`Many public policy organizations and consumer
`advocacy groups adhere to this view (see, for exam-
`ple, www.nofreelunch.org). The prominent alternative
`view argues that PSRs do influence physicians' pre-
`scribing behavior, but that this influence is positive
`in that PSRs provide physicians with valuable infor-
`mation. As a result, physicians are better informed
`and make better choices for their patients. Pharma-
`ceutical companies and industry groups advocate this
`second view.
`Despite the substantial resources that pharmaceu-
`tical companies invest in promoting their products
`and the controversy associated with pharmaceutical
`marketing practices, surprisingly little is known about
`the magnitude of the impact that PSR visits and free
`drug samples have on physician prescribing behavior.
`Narayanan et al. (2003) report a pharmaceutical exec-
`utive as stating, "No one is really sure if sending the
`legions of reps to doctors' offices really works. Every-
`one is afraid to stop it, because they don't know what
`difference it's making" (p. 4).
`In point of fact, much of the evidence on PSR
`effectiveness is anecdotal. The empirical studies
`investigating the issue have been subject to data or
`methodological limitations that restricted their ability
`to control for potential biases and have come to
`contradictory conclusions regarding even the central
`issues: the effects of detailing on prescriptions (e.g.,
`Parsons and Abeele 1981 versus Gonul et al. 2001),
`of detailing on price elasticity (e.g., Rizzo 1999 versus
`Gonul et al. 2001), and even of price on sales (e.g.,
`Rizzo 1999 versus Gonul et al. 2001).
`We have obtained access to a unique database
`that allows us to undertake econometric analysis
`that overcomes a number of fundamental limitations
`existing in past research. In particular, making use
`of a dynamic fixed-effects distributed lag model that
`accounts for physician-specific effects likely to induce
`
`bias if left uncontrolled, we assess the effect of detail-
`ing and sampling on physician prescribing behavior.
`The large number of observations in the database (it
`involves a total of more than 2 million observations)
`allows us to accurately pinpoint the impact that inter-
`actions with PSRs have on the number of new pre-
`scriptions issued by physicians.
`We find that, although detailing and free drug sam-
`ples have a positive and statistically significant asso-
`ciation with the number of new prescriptions issued
`by a physician, the magnitudes of the effects are mod-
`est. As such, our results challenge the two domi-
`nant views and support the contention that, rather
`than being easy marks, physicians are tough sells.
`This realization is important because the public policy
`debate continues over how best to address the high
`cost of prescription drugs.
`
`PSR Influence on Physicians
`Most discussions of PSRs have focused on the factors
`facilitating their influence. Unquestionably, PSRs pro-
`vide physicians with information about new drugs,
`new indications, dosages, and interactions for existing
`medicines. Azoulay (2002) finds evidence that detail-
`ing diffuses product information. Avorn et al. (1982)
`report that 20% of surveyed physicians view informa-
`tion provided by PSRs as "very important" in influ-
`encing their prescribing behavior. Furthermore, PSRs
`are trained in persuading physicians. Detailing takes
`the form of presenting facts and, as has been doc-
`umented (Zigler et al. 1995), misrepresenting facts
`about the drug in an effective manner. Finally, mere
`exposure or salience effects might lead to a temporary
`increase in prescribing following a PSR visit. Numer-
`ous studies have reported high physician responsive-
`ness to PSR activity attributed it to PSR persuasive-
`ness (Avorn et al. 1982, Powers 1998).
`Less attention has been paid to the factors limiting
`PSR effectiveness. The key consideration here is that
`PSRs are not the only or even the primary source
`of information about drugs for physicians. Scientific
`papers, advice from colleagues, and a physician's own
`training and experience also influence prescribing
`practices. Indeed, most physicians view these other
`influences as far more important than that of PSRs
`(Peay and Peay 1990).
`PSR influence is limited by the fact that many
`physicians have skeptical or negative attitudes toward
`PSRs (Lichstein et al. 1992, McKinley et al. 1990).
`Attribution theory suggests
`that with
`low source
`credibility, which is determined by factors such as
`a source's trustworthiness and expertise (Dholakia
`and Sternthal 1977), arguments in a message will
`be discounted (Eagley and Chaiken 1975). Physicians
`recognize that PSRs are neither experts nor com-
`
`This content downloaded from 208.85.77.1 on Tue, 20 Jan 2015 13:37:52 PM
`All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
`
`Page 3 of 13
`
`

`
`1706
`
`Mizik and Jacobson: Quantifying the Effects of Detailing and Sampling on New Prescriptions
`Management Science 50(12), pp. 1704-1715, r2004 INFORMS
`
`pletely trustworthy. They realize that information pre-
`sented is biased toward the promoted drug and is
`unlikely to be objective or even accurate (Connelly
`et al. 1990). Thus, physicians will discount informa-
`tion received from a PSR.
`Some additional characteristics of physicians would
`seem to make them particularly tough sells. Friestad
`and Wright's (1994) persuasion knowledge model
`suggests that targets of persuasion use their knowl-
`edge about the persuasion agent and can effectively
`cope with and even achieve their own goals during a
`persuasion attempt, e.g., obtaining free drug samples
`that can be later distributed to patients. Campbell and
`Kirmani's (2000) tests of the persuasion knowledge
`model reveal that busy targets with accessible agent
`motivation (a profile that would fit most physicians)
`are particularly effective in resisting persuasion.
`When cast within the workings of other sources
`of influence, we would expect the ability of PSRs to
`influence physician behavior to be relatively small. As
`such, we hypothesize a relatively small effect of PSR
`activity on physician prescribing behavior.
`
`Previous Empirical Research
`The various studies assessing the effect of PSR activ-
`ity on physician prescribing behavior have generated
`conflicting results. Indeed, on some of the most cen-
`tral issues-ranging from the effects of detailing on
`prescriptions, of detailing on price elasticity, and even
`of price on sales-studies have come to diametrically
`opposite conclusions. Data and methodological limi-
`tations, however, raise concerns about the inferences
`drawn from these analyses.
`A few quasi-experimental studies of the issue orig-
`inate in the medical community. These studies com-
`pare physicians who did not see PSRs or were visited
`less frequently by PSRs to physicians who saw PSRs
`or were visited more frequently by PSRs (Chren and
`Landefeld 1994, Powers 1998). The limitation of these
`studies is that they are not randomized: PSRs do
`not determine which physicians to visit on a random
`basis. Rather, PSRs tend to see physicians who are
`more likely to utilize the drug or who prescribe in
`higher volume. This consideration invalidates these
`attempts to assess the effect of PSRs independent of
`controls accounting for motivation influencing PSR
`behavior.
`The ability to potentially control for other influ-
`ences is an advantage of regression-based analysis.
`Past research has made use of different regression
`techniques to assess PSR influence. Unfortunately,
`it has been inadequate in controlling for physician-
`specific effects. Parsons and Abeele (1981) use data
`for 24 months and 14 territories to model the number
`of prescriptions sold in a given territory for a given
`month as a function of sales calls. Interestingly, the
`
`estimated main effect of detailing was negative. The
`most dominant explanatory factor in the model is
`sales lagged one period, which would reflect per-
`sistence in behaviors and carryover effects magnify-
`ing the influence of detailing. Alternatively, lagged
`sales could be reflective of territory-specific effects
`that are not modeled and, as such, could lead to
`biased estimates. Wotruba (1982), for example, raises
`this possibility of territory-specific effects to question
`the reported effects of detailing.
`Rizzo (1999) uses annual data for the period 1988-
`1993 and for 46 drugs to estimate a brand-level model
`linking prescriptions for a drug for a given year
`to pharmaceutical company marketing activities. He
`finds that price is negatively related to sales and that
`detailing is anticompetitive in that it decreases price
`sensitivity. Detailing is also found to have a direct
`positive effect on sales. Surprisingly, no consideration
`is given to the dynamic properties of sales. The classic
`spurious regression characteristics, i.e., very high R2
`in the presence of substantial unmodeled autocorre-
`lation, appear to be present. As such, questions exist
`about the validity of both the point estimates and
`standard errors reported in the analysis.
`Gonul et al. (2001) use data involving 1,785 patient
`visits to estimate a multinomial logit model assess-
`ing factors influencing physician prescribing behav-
`ior. Exactly opposite to the findings of Rizzo (1999),
`they report that price has a positive effect on prescrip-
`tion probabilities and that detailing increases price
`sensitivity. They find positive effects of detailing and
`sampling, but do not discuss the implications of their
`magnitudes. These magnitudes, calculated based on
`descriptive statistics, imply elasticities that are sur-
`prisingly large.' The elasticity estimates for the seven
`drugs studied, evaluated at the mean level of detail-
`ing and sampling, average 41% for detailing and 48%
`for sampling. Particularly for samples, which have a
`negligible marginal cost, their estimated coefficients
`imply enormous returns to enhanced PSR activity. In
`point of fact, these substantial effects could arise, not
`from the influence of PSR activity, but rather as an
`outgrowth of a joint correlation with an omitted factor
`from the model, e.g., larger practices prescribe more
`and receive more free samples.
`A concern, which Gonul et al. (2001) explicitly
`is over the role of physician-specific
`acknowledge,
`effects that can induce a bias in the estimated coeffi-
`cients. They state (p. 84),
`prescription behavior patterns might be strongly influ-
`enced by factors other than the explanatory vari-
`ables we include in our model. Examples are physi-
`
`1 The elasticity of prescription probability Pj to covariate Xjk in a
`conditional logit model is calculated as (dPj/Pj)/(aXjk/Xjk) = f3k * Xjk *
`(1- P).
`
`This content downloaded from 208.85.77.1 on Tue, 20 Jan 2015 13:37:52 PM
`All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
`
`Page 4 of 13
`
`

`
`Mizik and Jacobson: Quantifying the Effects of Detailing and Sampling on New Prescriptions
`Management Science 50(12), pp. 1704-1715, l2004 INFORMS
`
`1707
`
`to 11 years; annual sales range from under $0.5 billion
`to more than $1 billion; they come from different ther-
`apeutic areas. Although the effect of detailing can
`vary across drugs, analysis of these three drugs offers
`some generalizable insights, not only because they
`provide a cross-section of drugs in the marketplace,
`but because they represent more than 4 million PSR
`interactions with physicians.
`Model
`We employ the following dynamic fixed-effects dis-
`tributed lag regression model to assess the effect of
`detailing and sampling on new prescriptions:
`
`cians' unobservable personal characteristics.... Ignor-
`ing these factors might bias the coefficients of the
`included explanatory variables.
`The extent to which their estimates are biased by
`the failure to control for unobservable factors remains
`unanswered, but this is one consideration that might
`account for the large estimated effects.
`
`Empirical Analysis
`A key benefit of utilizing pooled time series cross-
`sectional (panel) data is the ability to test for and
`control the effect of unobserved fixed factors. These
`unobserved factors, if left uncontrolled, can induce
`bias in the coefficient estimates of the explanatory fac-
`tors included in the model. Past research has either
`not used panel data or not made full use of the ben-
`efits of panel data analysis. We make use of pooled
`time series cross-section observations (24 months of
`observations across 74,075 physicians) and panel data
`statistical methods (i.e., a dynamic fixed-effects dis-
`tributed lag regression model) to assess the effect
`of detailing and sampling on physician prescribing
`behavior.
`
`Data
`Access to the data was gained from a U.S. pharmaceu-
`tical manufacturer with the only condition of ensur-
`ing the anonymity of the firm and the drugs in the
`study. Two different sets of data were merged to form
`the database. One data set pertains to the number
`of new prescriptions for the studied drugs and their
`competitors issued by physicians during a month.
`The new prescription measure reflects both new and
`repeat usage, but does not reflect refills accompany-
`ing the prescriptions. These data cover a 24-month
`period for three widely prescribed drugs. The second
`data set pertains to detailing and sampling activity
`by PSRs for the same three drugs. The two data sets
`were merged into one database containing prescrib-
`ing and promotional activity information by month
`and physician.
`To reduce the possible influence of extreme val-
`ues (outliers) that would arise from, for example,
`data entry errors and the common practice of one
`physician signing for all samples that later get dis-
`tributed to a group of physicians attending a confer-
`ence, we excluded the top 0.5% of observations for the
`number of details, samples, and new prescriptions.
`We later undertook sensitivity analysis on alternative
`definitions of outliers (e.g., 0%, 1%, 5%) and found
`results in close correspondence across these alterna-
`tive samples.
`Table 1 presents basic background information and
`descriptive statistics for the drugs included in our
`study. The drugs differ on a variety of dimensions:
`They have been on the market from less than 1 year
`
`Prescribeit
`6
`=- a + E
`j=0
`
`6
`
`6
`j * Detailsit-j + E yj * Samplesit-j
`j=0
`6
`+ E Aj * Competitort- + E
`i=1
`
`
`
`* Prescribeit-
`
`=O
`T
`
`+
`
`11
`
`, * Time(r) + i, Ks Specialty(s) * Trendt
`
`s=1
`
`+=1
`+ Eit'
`(1)
`where Prescribeit, Detailsit, Samplesit, and Competitorit
`are, respectively, the number of new prescriptions
`issued, the number of PSR visits, the number of free
`drug samples received, and the number of new pre-
`scriptions issued for competitive drugs by physician i
`at time period t. Time(7) is an indicator function that
`takes on the value 0 prior to the time period r and 1
`from the time period r on, Specialty(s) is an indi-
`cator function that takes on the value 1 when the
`specialty area of the physician is s, 0 otherwise (i.e.,
`separate dummy variables for each of the 11 spe-
`cialty areas), and Trend is the observation number
`for a given month and year. Because it includes both
`current-term and lagged variables in the model, Equa-
`tion (1) allows for a wide range of possible effects and
`influences, e.g., serial correlation (current-effects) and
`state-dependent (persisting) dynamic relationships.
`A key characteristic of Equation (1) is that it allows
`for a physician-specific effect, i.e., the intercept ai
`is allowed to vary by physician. This consideration
`acknowledges that physician behavior patterns are
`influenced by unobserved or unobservable factors,
`e.g., physician characteristics. To the extent that these
`unobserved factors are correlated with detailing and
`sampling, analysis not controlling for their effects will
`result in biased estimated effects for the marketing
`phenomena. Although a Hausman (1978) specification
`test can empirically assess the role played by fixed
`effects, we have a priori reason to believe that these
`unobserved factors will in fact be correlated with mar-
`keting activity. For instance, larger practices will gen-
`erate more prescriptions and will also attract more
`
`This content downloaded from 208.85.77.1 on Tue, 20 Jan 2015 13:37:52 PM
`All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
`
`Page 5 of 13
`
`

`
`1708
`
`Table 1 Drug Profiles
`
`Mizik and Jacobson: Quantifying the Effects of Detailing and Sampling on New Prescriptions
`Management Science 50(12), pp. 1704-1715, w2004 INFORMS
`
`Drug A
`0.5 to 1 billion
`3 years
`
`12
`
`1.73
`(1.75)
`4.34
`(9.76)
`13.18
`(14.81)
`2-3
`
`Drug B
`over 1 billion
`11 years
`
`Drug C
`under 0.5 billion
`6 months
`
`18
`
`1.98
`(1.70)
`7.79
`(13.71)
`8.82
`(10.43)
`2-3
`
`11
`
`1.73
`(1.44)
`4.02
`(7.73)
`2.27
`(3.58)
`2-3
`
`Sales range (US$)
`Time on the market at the
`beginning of the study period
`Estimated number of competitors
`in the respective therapeutic area
`Mean number of details per
`physician per month
`Mean number of free drug samples
`per physician per month
`Mean number of monthly new
`prescriptions per physician
`Average number of refills following
`one new prescription
`Recommended duration of therapy 3 months, and as maintenance with 3 months and up to 9 months Not yet established
`periodic patient reexamination
`Average
`
`Above average
`
`Average
`
`42.91
`(43.63)
`
`48.80
`(53.73)
`
`22.46
`(19.03)
`
`6
`
`6
`
`6
`
`Cost of therapy relative to other
`drugs in the therapeutic area
`Mean number of monthly new
`in
`prescriptions per physician
`the respective therapeutic area
`Therapeutic area is
`Relatively new
`Well established
`Well established
`Specialty area of top prescribers
`Primary carett
`Primary careft
`Psychiatry
`Number of physicians
`10,516
`30,005
`55,896
`Number of data points
`252,384
`720,120
`1,341,504
`Note. Standard errors are in parentheses. The sum of the number of physicians
`in each of the three data sets is greater than the total
`in the study (74,075) because some physicians are in the upper 60 prescribing percentile
`number of physicians
`for more than one of
`the drugs in our study.
`ttThe primary care specialty area includes family practice, general practice, internal medicine, and osteopathy.
`detailing. As such, a spurious positive correlation, i.e.,
`involve both a direct effect on prescriptions and an
`indirect effect that arises through persistence in physi-
`unrelated to any potential effects of detailing, will
`cian behavior. The total effect of detailing and sam-
`exist between detailing and prescriptions due to a
`pling can be calculated as
`joint correlation with practice size.
`Because the effects of PSR activity are unlikely to
`be limited to the month when the visit occurred, we
`allow for current and lagged effects for both detailing
`and sampling. The number of observations available
`in our data sample allows us to directly estimate sep-
`arate effects for lagged terms. As such, we do not
`need to impose a specific decay pattern as a neces-
`sity for preserving degrees of freedom. We do, how-
`ever, need to specify the length of time that a PSR
`visit might influence physician behavior. We select a
`six-months lag length under the view that the effect
`of a visit will dissipate substantially over this period,
`but we also test for longer-term lagged effects. Still,
`we expect the effects of detailing to be largest in the
`months directly following the visit. The cumulative
`direct effect of detailing and sampling can be obtained
`and
`simply by summing the coefficients, i.e., E61=0j
`Lagged values for new prescriptions (Prescribeit_)
`capture autocorrelation in the series that arises
`through inertia and persistence in physician behavior.
`These autoregressive effects play a key role in that
`they magnify the effects of detailing and sampling.
`That is, the total effects of detailing and sampling
`
`6
`
`1-yyj
`j=1
`
`,
`
`/Pj/ 1-Bb-[ j and y/
`
`j=l
`
`j=0
`
`j=O
`respectively.
`We include both lagged own prescriptions and
`lagged competitors' prescriptions, thus the model
`separates lagged total demand dynamics into two
`key components: competitive substitution and own
`demand growth. Lagged own prescriptions will have
`a positive effect on prescriptions. Lagged competitors'
`prescriptions will have a negative impact on prescrip-
`tions because they capture the substitution effects
`that physicians make between competing drugs. The
`current competitive prescriptions, however, will cap-
`ture two different phenomena. They will reflect not
`only substitution effects, but also changes in total
`demand due to market expansion or contraction. In
`this regard, current-term competitive effects will act
`as a proxy for two different phenomena with oppo-
`site effects, i.e., negative substitution effects and posi-
`tive market demand effects. As such, the current-term
`coefficient (AO) will depend on the relative magnitude
`of the two conflicting effects and, therefore, the sign
`of the effect cannot be postulated a priori.
`
`This content downloaded from 208.85.77.1 on Tue, 20 Jan 2015 13:37:52 PM
`All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
`
`Page 6 of 13
`
`

`
`Mizik and Jacobson: Quantifying the Effects of Detailing and Sampling on New Prescriptions
`Management Science 50(12), pp. 1704-1715, @2004 INFORMS
`
`1709
`
`The other variables in Equation (1) are time-period-
`specific indicators and specialty-specific trends. The
`time-period-specific indicators (the coefficients 8,)
`allow for the fact that the number of prescriptions
`can shift across time periods. These intercepts capture
`not only seasonal effects but all brandwide influences
`that shift prescribing behavior across all physicians
`(e.g., price changes, changes in the set of alternative
`medications available, changes in advertising cam-
`paigns, etc.). That is, the inclusion of the time-specific
`indicator variables will capture all effects common
`across physicians, which would include the diffu-
`sion pattern for the drug, research reports in scien-
`tific journals, any negative or positive publicity for
`the brand or its competitors, etc. The 11 specialty-
`specific trends K, capture influences that shift pre-
`scribing behavior across all physicians in a particular
`specialty. After we take first differences, the time-
`period-specific indicators and the specialty-specific
`trends are transformed into time-period-specific inter-
`cepts and specialty-specific intercepts.
`To remove the influence of physician specific effects
`(i.e., ai), we take first differences of Equation (1) to
`obtain
`
`6
`
`data for antiulcer drugs.2 We found that, after making
`use of competitive sales as a proxy variable, monthly
`changes in brand detailing exhibited little correlation
`(0.01) with monthly changes in competitor detailing.
`Given the absence of correlation at the brand level, the
`correlation at the physician level can also be expected
`to be similarly small and, indeed, even smaller. As
`such, the magnitude of this bias in the estimated effect
`of detailing caused by the exclusion of competitive
`detailing from the analysis can be expected to be min-
`imal, or even completely absent.
`We estimate Equation (2) using instrumental vari-
`able estimation as ordinary least squares will generate
`biased estimates of the coefficients for APrescribeit-1
`and ACompetitorit. By construction, APrescribeit_1 will
`be correlated with the differenced error term qit
`and, just as substitution effects cause competitor pre-
`scriptions to influence own prescriptions, own pre-
`scriptions will influence the amount of competitor
`prescriptions. Following Anderson and Hsiao (1982),
`we use lagged values of the levels of the series
`(values at time period t - 2 and earlier) to gener-
`ate instrumental variable estimates for APrescribeit-1
`and ACompetitorit. This procedure generates consis-
`tent (i.e., asymptotically unbiased) estimates of the
`parameters and their standard errors.3
`Results
`For each of the three drugs in our study, we estimated
`the Equation (2) regression model. Table 2 reports
`the estimated coefficients. Figures 1 and 2 graphically
`depict the estimated direct effects of detailing and
`sampling, respectively.
`Persistence in Prescribing Behavior. For each of
`the three drugs in the study we observe signifi-
`cant persistence in physicians' prescribing behavior.
`Although the first-order autocorrelation is the most
`substantial for all three drugs, significant higher-order
`effects are present as well. For Drug A the estimated
`coefficients for months 1 through 6 of 0.357, 0.205,
`
`2 We thank Ernst R. Berndt for granting us access to these data. See
`Berndt et al. (2003) for a complete description of the data. Consis-
`tent with lack of correlation between firm and competitor detailing,
`we also found little difference in the estimated effect of detailing
`on sales generated from a model that included competitive detail-
`ing versus a model that excluded competitive detailing (i.e., the
`difference was less than 3%).
`3The consistency of the lagged-variable-based instrument hinges
`on the assumption that the disturbances are serially uncorrelated;
`see, for example, Arellano and Bond (1991) for a discussion. We
`included higher-order lagged endogenous variables in the model
`to ensure this would be the case and we find no evidence to the
`contrary. For example, for Drug A the second-order autocorrela-
`tion of the residual is -0.0029, with a t-stat of -0.96; the 3rd order
`autocorrelation is 0.00035, with a t-statistic of 0.12. Indeed, our esti-
`mated residual correlation matrix is in near exact correspondence
`with that postulated by a fixed effects, autoregressive model for
`each of our three drugs (Arellano 2003).
`
`=
`
`+
`
`6
`
`j=1
`
`* APrescribeit-j
`
`it. (2)
`
`APrescribe

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket