throbber
Journal of Financial Economics 61 (2001) 77–106
`
`Short-sellers, fundamental analysis,
`and stock returns$
`
`Patricia M. Dechowa,*, Amy P. Huttonb, Lisa Meulbroekb,
`Richard G. Sloana
`a University of Michigan Business School, Ann Arbor, MI 48109, USA
`b Harvard Business School, Harvard University, Boston, MA 02163, USA
`
`Received 19 August 1998; received in revised form 26 June 2000
`
`Abstract
`
`Firms with low ratios of fundamentals (such as earning and book values) to market
`values are known to have systematically lower future stock returns. We document that
`short-sellers position themselves in the stock of such firms, and then cover their
`positions as the ratios mean-revert. We also show that short-sellers refine their trading
`strategies to minimize transactions costs and maximize their investment returns. Our
`evidence is consistent with short-sellers using information in these ratios to take
`positions in stocks with lower expected future returns. # 2001 Elsevier Science S.A. All
`rights reserved.
`
`JEL classification : G12; G14; M41
`
`Keywords: Short-sellers; Fundamental analysis; Trading strategies
`
`$This paper has benefited from the comments of seminar participants at the Australian
`Graduate School of Management, the American Accounting Association 1999 Annual Meetings,
`Cornell University, Louisiana State University, Harvard Business School, University of North
`Carolina, University of Southern California, University of Texas at Austin, and Northwestern
`University. We are also grateful for the comments from the editor, Bill Schwert, and the referee
`(Ken French).
`
`*Corresponding author. Tel.: +1-734-764-3191; fax: +1-734-936-8716.
`
`E-mail address: dechow@umich.edu (P.M. Dechow).
`
`0304-405X/01/$ - see front matter # 2001 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved.
`PII: S 0 3 0 4 - 4 0 5 X ( 0 1 ) 0 0 0 5 6 - 3
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1042
`
`

`
`78
`
`P.M. Dechow et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 61 (2001) 77–106
`
`1. Introduction
`
`Conventional wisdom characterizes short-sellers as sophisticated investors
`who incur relatively large transactions costs attempting to short-sell and
`subsequently repurchase temporarily overpriced securities.1 Asquith and
`Meulbroek (1996) provide evidence that short-sellers, as a group, successfully
`identify securities that subsequently underperform the market. In this paper,
`we identify the characteristics of the securities targeted by short-sellers.
`Specifically, we examine whether short-sellers target stocks of firms that are
`priced high relative to fundamentals such as earnings and book values.
`A large body of evidence demonstrates that ratios of measures of
`fundamental value to market value systematically predict future stock returns.
`These ratios compare estimates of ‘‘intrinsic’’ values based on accounting data
`to observed market prices. They range from simple ratios such as earnings-to-
`price and book-to-market (e.g., Fama and French, 1995; Lakonishok et al.,
`1994) to ratios based on more sophisticated valuation models such as Ohlson
`(1995) (e.g., Frankel and Lee, 1998; Dechow et al., 1999). Given the well-
`documented predictive ability of these ratios with respect to future stock
`returns, they provide a natural starting point for investigating the trading
`strategies of short-sellers.
`We document a strong relation between the trading strategies of short-sellers
`and ratios of fundamentals to market prices. Our tests indicate that short-
`sellers target securities that have low fundamental-to-price ratios and then they
`unwind their positions as these ratios revert to normal levels. We also show
`that short-sellers refine their trading strategies in three ways in order to
`maximize their investment returns. First, short-sellers avoid securities for
`which the transactions costs of short-selling are high. Second, short-sellers
`supplement their trading strategies by using information beyond that in
`fundamental-to-price ratios that has predictive ability with respect to future
`returns. Third, we show that short-sellers avoid shorting securities with low
`fundamental-to-price ratios when the low ratios are attributable to temporarily
`low fundamentals. In other words, short-sellers act as if they are able to
`discriminate between low ratios that are due to temporarily low fundamentals
`and low ratios that are attributable to temporarily high prices.
`A straightforward interpretation of our results is that low fundamental-to-
`price ratios are associated with temporary overpricing that is actively exploited
`by short-sellers. This interpretation is consistent with the Lakonishok et al.
`(1994) hypothesis that ‘‘na.ıve’’ investors tend to be overoptimistic about the
`future prospects of stocks with low fundamental-to-price ratios. Under this
`interpretation, our evidence suggests that short-sellers are sophisticated
`
`1 See, for example, Business Week, August 5, 1996, pp. 63–68, Fortune, November 9, 1998 p. 272,
`and Forbes, December 28, 1998, pp. 101–103.
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1042
`
`

`
`P.M. Dechow et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 61 (2001) 77–106
`
`79
`
`investors who play an important role in keeping the price of stocks in line with
`fundamentals. An alternative interpretation of our results is that
`low
`fundamental-to-price ratios are associated with unique risk characteristics.
`This interpretation is consistent with the Fama and French (1992) hypothesis
`that stocks with low fundamental-to-price ratios have low sensitivity to the
`‘‘book-to-market’’ risk factor. Under this interpretation, short-sellers achieve
`superior returns by short-selling low-risk stocks. These superior returns are
`compensation for the increased exposure to the book-to-market risk factor. In
`an attempt to discriminate between these competing interpretations, we
`conducted a telephone survey of major global short-selling hedge funds. The
`fund managers all endorsed the first interpretation provided above, i.e., they
`short-sell stocks they perceive to be overpriced. However, it is also possible that
`short-sellers inadvertently load up on the risk factor conjectured by the second
`interpretation above.
`The paper proceeds in four sections. The next section develops our
`predictions. Section 3 describes our research design, Section 4 presents the
`results, and Section 5 concludes.
`
`2. Empirical predictions
`
`We begin in Section 2.1 by describing the institutional features of short-
`selling and identifying the objectives, risks, and costs of short-selling. Section
`2.2 then describes several established techniques for predicting future stock
`returns by comparing ratios of fundamental measures of value to market
`prices. These sections provide the underpinnings for our empirical predictions,
`which are presented in Section 2.3. In Section 2.4 we discuss the possible
`confounding effects of any unidentified risk factors on the interpretation of our
`results.
`
`2.1. Institutional details on short-selling
`
`A short sale is a sale of a stock that one does not already own, but has
`borrowed from a brokerage house, a large institutional investor, or another
`broker-dealer. The short-seller establishes the position by selling the borrowed
`stock, and closes the position by buying the stock back at a later time, using the
`purchased shares to extinguish the initial loan of the stock. By selling short, an
`investor can profit from a decrease in the stock price. The risk-return profile for
`a short position is very different from that of a long position. A short-seller’s
`maximum gain is the sale price of the stock (if the stock price falls to zero),
`while the loss is potentially unlimited (if the stock price rises). Because of the
`high risk associated with short-selling, and because of its putative potential for
`manipulating stock prices, short-selling is heavily regulated in U.S. stock
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1042
`
`

`
`80
`
`P.M. Dechow et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 61 (2001) 77–106
`
`markets and is not allowed in many foreign stock markets. Many institutional
`investors are prohibited from short-selling, or restricted in the size of their
`short positions relative to the overall size of their portfolios. Asquith and
`Meulbroek (1996) provide an extensive review of the institutional aspects of
`short-selling. Here we provide only a brief summary of the process in the
`United States.
`Regulation in the United States has developed from beliefs that short-sellers
`can cause stock prices to spiral downward. The ensuing regulations act to
`increase the cost of
`short-selling. The U.S. Securities and Exchange
`Commission requires short-sellers to sell only on a ‘‘plus tick’’ or a ‘‘zero
`plus tick,’’ that is, when the stock price has increased. The proceeds from a
`short sale are not available to the short-seller. Instead, the proceeds are
`escrowed as collateral for the owner of the borrowed shares. Typically, the
`short-seller receives interest on the proceeds, but the rate received (the
`‘‘rebate’’) is below the market rate. The difference is the compensation to the
`lender of the stock. Thus, short-sellers cannot directly use the proceeds from
`short sales to reinvest or to hedge their short position. Regulation T, set by the
`Federal Reserve, requires short-sellers of stocks to deposit additional collateral
`of 50% of the market value of the shorted shares. The short-seller can use
`either long positions in other securities or interest-bearing Treasury securities
`to meet this additional margin requirement, mitigating the cost of maintaining
`this additional collateral (any dividends or interest earned on securities in the
`collateral margin account accrue to the short-seller). If the price of the shorted
`stock rises, increasing the liability of the short-seller, additional collateral funds
`are generally required. The tax treatment of short positions contributes to the
`high cost of short-selling. All profits from a short sale are taxed at the short-
`term capital gains rate, no matter how long the short position is open. Finally,
`the short-seller is required to reimburse the stock lender for any dividends or
`other distributions paid to the shareholders of the shorted stock while the short
`position is open. Because the ex-dividend stock price of the shorted stock is
`generally higher than the pre-dividend stock price less the amount of the
`dividend (e.g., Frank and Jagannathan, 1998), dividend reimbursement
`represents a real cost to the short-seller (in addition to inconvenience and
`transactions costs).
`The standard stock-lending practice is that the loan must be repaid on
`demand. This practice exposes short-sellers to the risk of being ‘‘squeezed.’’ A
`short squeeze occurs when the lender of the borrowed shares wants to sell the
`stock. If the short-seller is unable to find an alternative lender, the short-seller
`must repurchase the shares in the open market to repay the loan and close the
`position. To avoid this risk, a short-seller can borrow on a term basis for an
`additional fee, but most short-sellers seem to prefer the risk of a squeeze to the
`cost of a term loan, and term loans are rare. To help short-sellers assess the
`probability of a squeeze, the broker will sometimes reveal the identity of the
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1042
`
`

`
`P.M. Dechow et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 61 (2001) 77–106
`
`81
`
`lender of the shorted stock. Generally, a short squeeze is less likely for more
`liquid securities,
`such as
`large market-capitalization stocks with high
`institutional ownership, since it is easier for brokers to find alternative lenders
`of such stocks in the event that the original lender demands the return of the
`borrowed shares.2
`Short-selling is therefore riskier and more expensive than establishing a long
`position. Because short sales are more costly than long transactions, Diamond
`and Verrechia (1987) suggest that short-sellers will not trade unless they expect
`the price to fall enough to compensate them for the additional costs and risks
`of shorting. Short-sellers, they propose, are therefore more likely to be better
`informed than are investors with long positions. A short sale is the most direct
`way for an investor to bet that a stock’s price will decrease.3 Of course, short
`sales occur for a myriad of reasons, only one of which is a belief by the short-
`seller that the stock is overvalued relative to its fundamentals. In a merger
`situation, investors often simultaneously go long in the target firm’s stock and
`short
`in the acquiring firm’s stock. In ‘‘pairs trading’’
`investors hedge
`themselves by shorting a security whose return is highly correlated with the
`return of another security they have purchased (e.g., selling Dell short and
`purchasing Gateway). Another reason for short-selling is to arbitrage a price
`differential between the stock and debt convertible into the stock. These other
`reasons for short-selling are not motivated by the expectation of a price decline.
`Thus, to the extent that short-selling is attributable to these other activities,
`they add noise to our empirical tests.
`Early research on short interests by Figlewski (1981), Woolridge and
`Dickinson (1994), Brent, Morse, and Stice (1990), and Figlewski and Webb
`(1993) fails to document a strong relation between short interest and excess
`returns. However, Asquith and Meulbroek point out that the power of the tests
`in these studies is weak, since their sample selections are not based on the
`magnitude of the short interests. As documented by Asquith and Meulbroek,
`many firms have very small short positions (less than 0.5%). These small short
`positions are likely to represent hedge positions, rather than a systematic
`attempt to exploit perceived overpricing. By focusing on a sample of firm-years
`with large short interests (e.g., firm-years with short positions greater than
`2.5% of shares outstanding), Asquith and Meulbroek document a strong and
`
`2 An extreme example of a short squeeze is the case of Amazon.com. In June 1998, the number of
`shorted Amazon shares neared its entire float. The firm then announced a stock split, and the stock
`price rose significantly, with demand coming from both long investors and short-sellers who were
`squeezed due to the lack of shares to borrow. Fears of a short squeeze have been cited as an
`important reason why many short-sellers avoid heavily shorting ‘‘overpriced’’ Internet stocks (see
`St. Louis Post-Dispatch, July 19, 1998, p. E3).
`3 Asquith and Meulbroek (1996) point out that although the option market may seem a less
`costly way to achieve the same goal, many hedge-fund managers and other practitioners state that
`the option market is even more expensive, particularly for hard-to-borrow stocks.
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1042
`
`

`
`82
`
`P.M. Dechow et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 61 (2001) 77–106
`
`consistent relation between short interests and excess returns. They document
`that stocks with high levels of short interest perform significantly more poorly
`than comparable stocks without short positions.
`
`2.2. Ratios of fundamentals to market prices
`
`Basu (1983), Lakonishok et al. (1994), and Sloan (1996) show that various
`measures of cash flows scaled by price are positively related to future stock
`returns. Basu (1983) and Fama and French (1992) show that earnings-to-price
`ratios are positively related to future returns. Stattman (1980), Rosenberg et al.
`(1985), and Fama and French (1992) show that book-to-market ratios are
`positively related to future returns. Considerable prior research has investi-
`gated each of these ratios, and their predictive ability with respect to future
`returns is well documented, so we do not describe them in detail. However,
`research on the more sophisticated value-to-market measure is less well known
`and is discussed below.
`In a dividend-discounting framework, firm value can be expressed as the sum
`of the book value of common equity plus the present value of future abnormal
`earnings (see Edwards and Bell, 1961; Ohlson, 1995):
`
`Et½xatþtŠ
`ð1 þ rÞt;
`
`Pt ¼ bt þ
`
`X1
`
`t¼1
`
`where
`
`bt
`= book value of common equity at time t
`tþt; = Earningstþt rbtþt1
`xa
`r
`= cost of equity capital.
`
`Following Ohlson (1995), Dechow et al. (1999) model abnormal earnings as
`a simple autoregressive process:
`tþ1 ¼ o xat þ etþ1:
`
`xa
`Intrinsic value can then be expressed as
`Pt ¼ bt þ axa
`t
`
`with
`
`a ¼
`
`o
`;
`1 þ r o
`where o measures the persistence of abnormal earnings. This valuation model
`combines information in both earnings and book value. A persistence
`parameter of o ¼ 1 implies a pure earnings model, while a persistence
`parameter of o ¼ 0 implies a pure book value model. Empirically, Dechow
`et al. (1999) show that the average persistence parameter is around 0.6. They
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1042
`
`

`
`P.M. Dechow et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 61 (2001) 77–106
`
`83
`
`demonstrate that the ratio of intrinsic value to market value computed using
`o ¼ 0:6 is more highly associated with future returns than the earnings-to-price
`and book-to-market ratios. We employ their procedure in computing our
`value-to-market ratio.
`
`2.3. Empirical predictions
`
`The focus of this paper is on determining whether short-sellers exploit the
`predictable returns associated with the valuation ratios identified above. Prior
`research has shown that high cash-flow-to-price, earnings-to-price, book-to-
`market, and value-to-market firms earn higher one-year-ahead returns than do
`firms with low values for these ratios. So long as sophisticated investors do not
`perceive stocks with relatively high fundamentals to be riskier, we expect them
`to take advantage of these predictable returns. That is, we expect sophisticated
`investors to buy stocks for which the predictable returns are the highest (where
`cash-flow-to-price, earnings-to-price, book-to-market and value-to-market are
`high) and (short) sell stocks for which the predictable returns are the lowest
`(where cash-flow-to-price, earnings-to-price, book-to-market, and value-to-
`market are low). It is difficult to identify which long-positioned investors are
`sophisticated. However, as argued above, short-sellers represent sophisticated
`investors who claim to specialize in selling overpriced stocks.
`Our primary empirical prediction is that short interests will be relatively high
`in firm-years with relatively low values of cash-flow-to-price, earnings-to-price,
`book-to-market, and value-to-market ratios. We also predict that short-sellers
`will subsequently cover their positions as the predictable returns are realized
`and stock prices fall back in line with fundamentals. Finally, we investigate
`whether the magnitudes of short positions are influenced by differences in the
`relative transactions costs associated with shorting different securities. Such
`evidence would suggest that the effectiveness of short-selling as a mechanism
`for enhancing market efficiency is limited by the high transactions costs
`associated with short-selling.
`
`2.4. Risk and fundamental-to-price ratios
`
`Our results and their interpretation will be confounded if fundamental-to-
`price ratios capture risk factors unknown to us, that are responsible for the
`lower returns of low fundamental-to-price stocks (Fama and French, 1992). If
`these ratios do indeed capture risk factors, then there are two additional
`interpretations of our results:
`
`1. Short-sellers have unique preferences for the risk factors, which motivates
`their trading behavior with respect to low fundamental-to-price stocks; and
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1042
`
`

`
`84
`
`P.M. Dechow et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 61 (2001) 77–106
`
`2. Short-sellers think that they are profiting from short-selling overpriced
`securities, but they are inadvertently loading up on the unidentified risk
`factors.
`
`In an attempt to discriminate between these alternative interpretations, we
`surveyed the world’s ten largest short-selling hedge funds. (The rankings are
`from Managed Accounts Report, Inc. as of February 1999). One of the ten
`funds chose not to participate, but the nine respondents confirmed the
`conventional wisdom that their primary objective is to profit from short-selling
`temporarily overpriced stocks (survey results available upon request). They
`argued against the first risk factor interpretation described above. Of course, it
`is still possible that they inadvertently load up on risk in line with the second
`interpretation described above. Nevertheless, it is informative that sophisti-
`cated investors reject the risk factor interpretation. The fact that these
`sophisticated investors ‘‘vote with their feet’’ by shorting millions of dollars
`based on their belief that low fundamental-to-value ratios are associated
`with temporary mispricing provides additional credence to the mispricing
`interpretation.
`
`3. Sample formation and variable measurement
`
`In Section 3.1 we discuss the data sources and sample selection. In Section
`3.2 we discuss our variable measurement.
`
`3.1. Data sources and sample selection
`
`We require the following information to test our predictions: financial
`statement data, stock returns, institutional holdings data, and short interest
`data. Annual financial statement data are obtained from COMPUSTAT.
`Monthly stock returns are obtained from the Center for Research in Security
`Prices (CRSP). We obtain institutional data from Spectrum’s quarterly tapes.
`Short interest data are extracted from Asquith and Meulbroek’s database of
`monthly short interests. This database includes all New York Stock Exchange
`(NYSE) and American Stock Exchange (AMEX) firms and covers the time
`period 1976–1993. The original data sources for the Asquith and Meulbroek
`database are the Standard and Poor’s Daily Stock Price Record and Quarterly
`History Tape for the years 1976–1990 and the exchanges (NYSE and AMEX)
`for the years 1990–1993.
`Given the limits of the short interest database, our analysis is restricted to
`NYSE and AMEX firms in the years 1976–1993. Use of financial statement
`and stock return data eliminates firm-years not appearing on COMPUSTAT
`or CRSP. Tests using the Spectrum data are restricted to the years 1983–1993.
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1042
`
`

`
`P.M. Dechow et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 61 (2001) 77–106
`
`85
`
`3.2. Variable measurement
`
`The short interest variable used in our analysis is the percent of outstanding
`shares shorted. This is equal to the number of common shares shorted divided
`by the total number of common shares outstanding. We measure short
`positions three months after the end of the fiscal year from which we extract the
`financial data to compute our fundamental-to-price ratios. This provides us
`with reasonable assurance that the financial data would have been available to
`short-sellers. The return cumulation period also begins three months after the
`fiscal year-end. We use buy-and-hold one-year-ahead stock returns (including
`dividends). We measure abnormal returns by adjusting each firm’s return by
`the equal-weighted return for all NYSE and AMEX stocks over the same time
`period. Note that this measure of abnormal returns makes no adjustment for
`differences in risk across firms, and so potentially biases our results in favor of
`mispricing. However, previous research has established that the predictable
`returns associated with the fundamental-to-price ratios are robust with respect
`to a variety of techniques for adjusting returns, and so we employ this relatively
`straightforward adjustment method. Asquith and Meulbroek (1996) also
`establish that the negative relation between excess returns and short positions is
`robust to a variety of techniques for calculating excess returns.
`We examine two measures of institutional holdings at the fiscal year-end: the
`percent of outstanding shares held by institutions and the number of
`institutions investing in the common stock of the firm. We also calculate
`dividend yields as cash dividends paid per share (Compustat item 21) divided
`by stock price. Finally, we construct the four fundamental-to-price ratios
`described in Section 2.2. Similar to prior research, we exclude observations
`when the numerator is negative and winsorize the most extreme 1% of our
`observations. We measure the earnings-to-price ratio as operating income after
`depreciation generated from year t 1 to t (Compustat item 178) divided by
`the product of common shares outstanding (Compustat item 25) and the firm’s
`fiscal year-end price (Compustat item 199). We measure the cash-flow-to-price
`ratio as cash flow generated from year t 1 to t divided by the product of
`common shares outstanding and the fiscal year-end price. Following Sloan
`(1996), cash flows are measured as earnings minus accruals, with earnings
`measured as described above and accruals measured as follows:
`Accrualst ¼ ðDCAt DCashtÞ ðDCLt DSTDt DTPÞt Dept;
`
`where
`DCAt=change in current assets (Compustat item 4)
`DCLt=change in current liabilities (Compustat item 5)
`DCasht=change in cash and cash equivalents (Compustat item 1)
`DSTDt=change in debt included in current liabilities (Compustat item 34)
`DTPt=change in income tax payable (Compustat item 71) and
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1042
`
`

`
`86
`
`P.M. Dechow et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 61 (2001) 77–106
`
`Dept=depreciation and amortization expense (Compustat item 14).
`
`We measure the book-to-market ratio as the book value of common equity
`(Compustat item 60) divided by the product of common shares outstanding
`and the fiscal year-end price. We measure the value-to-market ratio at t as
`Book value of common equityt þ a1 ½Abnormal earningstŠ
`Common shares outstandingtPricet
`
`;
`
`a1 ¼
`
`and
`Abnormal earningst=Earningst (Compustat item 18) (Book value of
`common equityt1  r), and
`o
`1 þ r o
`where o is the persistence factor of abnormal earnings and r, the discount rate,
`is set equal to the long-run average return on equity of 12%. Following
`Dechow et al. (1999), we measure the persistence factor o for firm i in year t by
`performing the following pooled cross-sectional/time-series regression using all
`firm-years with available data in all prior years up to year t:
`Abnormal earningsi;t1 ¼ a0 þ o (Abnormal earningsi;t2)+ei;t1.
`
`In 1983, we use all firm-years prior to 1983, and in 1984 we use all firm-years
`prior to 1984, etc. We do not use information about abnormal earnings in year
`t since firms have different financial year-ends, and so not all information
`would necessarily be available for calculating o. For more details on this model
`see Ohlson (1995) and Dechow et al. (1999).
`
`4. Results
`
`Section 4.1 provides the results of our basic analysis of the relation between
`short interests, fundamental-to-price ratios, and future stock returns. Section
`4.2 presents additional
`results
`that provide further
`insights
`into the
`determinants of short interest.
`
`4.1. Short positions and the fundamental-to-price ratios
`
`Asquith and Meulbroek (1996) report that while most firms have less than
`0.5% of their outstanding shares shorted, a few firms have very large short
`positions (more than 5% of outstanding shares are shorted). The distribution
`of short positions is very similar for our sample of 34,037 firm-years. No short
`positions are observed for 12,445 firm-years, or 36.6% of the observations.
`Approximately 46% of our firm-year observations have very small short
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1042
`
`

`
`P.M. Dechow et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 61 (2001) 77–106
`
`87
`
`positions (more than zero but no more than 0.5%). However, the distribution
`is highly skewed, with fewer than 2% of firm-years having over 5% of their
`outstanding shares shorted. Fig. 1 provides a calendar time plot of short
`positions. The average short interest has increased over time. Part of this
`increase is likely to be due to the deregulation of the capital market and the
`growth in hedge funds. Similar time trends are also observed in our
`fundamental-to-price ratios. Our empirical tests take into account the effect
`of this serial correlation on coefficient estimates.
`Panel A of Table 1 provides evidence on the relation between short positions
`and future returns. We sort firm-years into six categories based on the
`magnitude of the short position in the stock. Note that the number of
`observations varies across the categories, ranging from 12,445 in the category
`with no short positions to 564 in the category with over 5% of the outstanding
`shares shorted. For each category, we sort firm-years by calendar year and
`calculate the mean one-year-ahead abnormal return for each calendar year.
`The average of the 18 calendar-year mean abnormal returns are reported in
`Panel A. Consistent with Asquith and Meulbroek (1996) we document a
`negative relation between the level of short interest and future stock returns.
`Future abnormal returns decline monotonically with the level of short interest.
`For firms with no short positions, the average one-year-ahead abnormal return
`is 2.3%, while for firms with over 5% shorted, the average abnormal return
`falls to 18.1%.4 For each of the categories with short positions, the average
`abnormal return is significantly lower than the average abnormal return for the
`firm-years with no short positions.5
`In the tests that follow, we classify firms with over 0.5% of outstanding
`shares shorted as firms with ‘‘high short’’ positions, while the remaining firms
`are classified as ‘‘low short’’ positions. We focus on ‘‘high shorts’’ (as opposed
`to nonzero shorts) to increase the power of our tests. Large short positions are
`more likely to represent a consensus among short-sellers that a stock is
`
`4 The time-series mean abnormal return for all firms with over 0.5% shorted is 3.5% with a
`standard error of 0.009 (significant at the 0.001 level using a two-tailed test). The time-series mean
`abnormal return for firms with over 0.5% shorted but less than 5% shorted is 2.4% with a
`standard error of 0.012 (significant at the 0.06 level using a two-tailed test). Thus, firms that we
`classify as having ‘‘high short’’ positions have significantly negative abnormal returns.
`5 For each of the short interest portfolios, for each calendar year, we subtract the mean abnormal
`return on the no-short portfolio from the mean abnormal return on the short interest portfolio. We
`then determine whether the 18 resulting hedge portfolio returns are significant using the time-series
`standard errors of the hedge portfolio returns. The significance levels for each category are less than
`0.06 using a two-tailed test. We also investigate the robustness of these results by computing the
`standard errors of portfolio returns, weighting each observation by the square root of the reciprocal
`of the number of observations in the portfolio. This procedure controls for any heteroskedasticity
`introduced by changing numbers of portfolio observations over calendar time. However, because
`the number of observations is relatively constant over time, it has little discernible effect on the
`standard errors.
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1042
`
`

`
`88
`
`P.M. Dechow et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 61 (2001) 77–106
`
`Fig. 1. Average percent of outstanding shares shorted three months after the fiscal year-end.
`Sample consists of 34,037 firm-year observations over the sample period 1975–1993 with data
`available on both the number of shares shorted and the variables required to compute the
`fundamental-to-price ratios.
`
`overpriced (consistent with the return results in Panel A of Table 1). This 0.5%
`cutoff is arbitrary however, and so we test the sensitivity of our results to this
`cutoff. The tenor of our results is unchanged when we use 1% or 2.5% cutoffs.
`Panel B of Table 1 reports the relation between the four fundamental-to-
`price ratios and future abnormal stock returns. Firm-year observations are
`assigned to ten portfolios based on the relative magnitude of their ratios. The
`ranking procedure is carried out separately for each ratio and each calendar
`year. We then pool the observations across calendar years such that portfolio 1
`contains the lowest values of each of the ratios and portfolio 10 contains the
`highest values of each ratio across the sample period. Recall that prior research
`has documented a positive relation between one-year-ahead abnormal returns
`and each of the four ratios. Panel B indicates that we can replicate prior
`findings for our sample of firm-years. For cash-flow-to-price, the abnormal
`returns vary from 6.1% in portfolio 1 to 9.9% in portfolio 10. For earnings-
`to-price, the abnormal returns are slightly smaller, varying from 3.1% in
`portfolio 1 to 10.4% in portfolio 10. For book-to-market, the abnormal
`returns are 2.7% in portfolio 1 and 9.6% in portfolio 10. Finally, for our
`value-to-market ratio, the abnorma

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket