throbber
Short sellers and innovation: Evidence from a quasi-natural experiment
`
`
`
`Jie (Jack) He
` Terry College of Business
`University of Georgia
`jiehe@uga.edu
`(706) 542-9076
`
`
`
`Xuan Tian
`Kelley School of Business
`Indiana University
`tianx@indiana.edu
`(812) 855-3420
`
`
`
`
`
`This version: March, 2014
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
` *
`
` We thank Russell Investments for providing us the list of Russell 3000 index used in this paper. We remain
`responsible for any remaining errors or omissions.
`
` Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2380352
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1041
`
`

`
`
`
`Short sellers and innovation: Evidence from a quasi-natural experiment
`
`
`
`Abstract
`We examine the causal effect of short sellers on innovation. Using exogenous variation in short-
`selling costs generated by a quasi-natural experiment, Regulation SHO, which randomly assigns
`a subsample of the Russell 3000 index firms into a pilot program, we show that short sellers have
`a positive, causal effect on firm innovation. The positive effect of short sellers on innovation is
`more pronounced when firms are subject to a larger agency problem and a higher degree of
`information asymmetry. Our paper provides new insights into an under-explored and possibly
`unintended real effect of short sellers – their encouragement for firm innovation.
`
`
`
`
`Key words: Innovation; Short selling; Regulation SHO; Pilot program
`
`JEL number: G14; G18; O31; O32
`
` Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2380352
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1041
`
`

`
`1. INTRODUCTION
`There has been an intensive debate about the economic impact of short sellers among
`academics, practitioners, and regulators in the past few decades. Critics of short sellers claim that
`they affect security prices adversely, lead to high market volatility, and undermine investors’
`confidence in the economy because of panic selling. Moreover, some anecdotes suggest that
`short sellers, given their strong incentives to profit from their short positions, may engage in
`opportunistic or even unethical behavior by disseminating pessimistic, false rumors about a firm.
`However, advocates of short selling take an opposite stand and argue that short sellers actually
`help improve market efficiency, facilitate price discovery, and prevent financial misconducts due
`to their active information production and intensive monitoring of the corporate management.1
`While there might be an element of truth in both sides of these arguments, in practice it is
`hard to identify the causal effect of short sellers on the real economy due to the endogenous
`nature of short sales: short selling activities could give rise to or result from the underlying
`characteristics of the corporate sector. For instance, a drop in stock prices following a period of
`active short sales may imply that short sellers depress the price level via their trading, but it
`could also reflect the fact that short sellers merely predict an upcoming decreasing trend in the
`stock market and thus trade on their expectation.
`In this paper, we exploit a quasi-natural experiment, Regulation SHO, to tackle the above
`endogeneity problem and provide the first empirical study that examines the causal effect of
`short sellers on technological innovation, which is perhaps the most important driver of
`economic growth. The impact of short sellers on innovation is of particular interest to policy
`makers and firm stakeholders not only because innovation is a crucial driver of a nation’s
`economic growth (Solow, 1957) and competitive advantage (Porter, 1992), but also because
`short selling activities in the U.S. are highly regulated and can be altered by a series of security
`laws and regulations over time.
`We rely on existing literature and the prevailing views of short selling to propose two
`competing hypotheses regarding the effect of short sellers on firm innovation. Our first
`
`
`1 In a highly publicized case, short seller Muddy Waters LLC discovered that Sino-Forest, a Canadian company that
`had its operations in China, exaggerated the level of its principal assets (i.e., trees) that were not even owned by the
`company. In contrast, Sino-Forest’s auditor, Ernst & Young, failed to detect the accounting fraud but still claimed
`“we are confident that Ernst & Young Canada’s work… met all professional standards. … Ernst & Young Canada
`did extensive audit work to verify ownership and existence of Sino-Forest’s timber assets.” (New York Times,
`December 6, 2012)
`
`
`
`1
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1041
`
`

`
`hypothesis conjectures that short sellers impede firm innovation. Short sellers are often accused
`of creating tremendous price pressure on a firm’s stock (e.g., Mitchell, Pulvino, and Stafford,
`2004), which leads to excessive pressure on managers to focus on short-term activities,
`exacerbating the managerial myopia problem (e.g., He and Tian, 2013; Fang, Tian, and Tice,
`2014). Manso (2011) theoretically shows that tolerance for failure is necessary for effectively
`motivating and nurturing innovation due to the long-term, risky, idiosyncratic, and unpredictable
`nature of technological innovation.2 However, short sellers have an innate distaste for tolerance
`towards short-term failures, because their main job is to identify underperforming firms, sell
`short these stocks to reflect their unfavorable information, and make trading profits. As a
`consequence, firm managers who care more about short-term stock prices as well as operating
`performance may sacrifice long-term firm value by cutting their investments in long-term, risky,
`but innovative projects to keep their stock prices high in the presence of short selling pressure.
`Therefore, our first hypothesis, the pressure hypothesis, argues that short sellers, by imposing
`short-term pressure on managers to prevent stock prices from falling, impede firm innovation.
`Alternatively, there are at least two plausible reasons why short sellers may, even
`unintentionally, encourage innovation. First, moral hazard models such as Grossman and Hart
`(1988) and Harris and Raviv (1988) suggest that managers who are not properly monitored will
`shirk or tend to invest more in unchallenging routine tasks to enjoy private benefits such as
`“quiet life” (Bertrand and Mullainathan, 2003). Value-destroying underinvestment in innovative
`projects due to agency problems could be mitigated by the threat of depressing stock prices from
`short sellers who have been shown to serve as an effective disciplinary force in the corporate
`setting (Karpoff and Lou, 2010; Massa, Zhang, and Zhang, 2013a, 2013b; Fang, Huang, and
`Karpoff, 2013). Whenever short sellers detect managerial slack such as shirking on long-term
`innovative projects, they could immediately short sell the company’s stock, leading to negative
`market reactions and potential disciplinary actions against the managers, including reduced
`bonuses and even forced managerial turnover. As a result, managers would be motivated to work
`hard and maximize firm value by making value-enhancing investment in innovative projects.
`Second, as Holmstrom (1989) points out, innovative activities involve exploring untested
`and unknown approaches that have a high probability of failure, which makes the innovation
`
`
`2 Recent empirical papers such as Acharya et al, (2013, 2014), Ederer and Manso (2013), and Tian and Wang (2014)
`all find supporting evidence for the implications of the failure tolerance theory.
`
`
`
`2
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1041
`
`

`
`process risky and long. Therefore, firms investing more heavily in innovative projects may be
`subject to a greater degree of information asymmetry (Bhattacharya and Ritter, 1983), are more
`likely to be undervalued by equity holders, and have a greater exposure to hostile takeovers
`(Stein, 1988). To minimize the chance of such expropriation, managers tend to reduce their
`investment in long-term innovation projects (in many cases sub-optimally) and exert more effort
`on routine tasks that offer faster and more stable returns, resulting in a typical managerial myopia
`problem. Since short selling is a costly trading strategy to implement, short sellers, relative to
`other stock market participants, generally spend more resources in information gathering and
`processing. Consequently, they offer a potential remedy for the above underinvestment problem
`in innovation by actively producing information about firm fundamentals, short selling over-
`valued stocks, and making stock prices more efficient.3 While the actual trading actions by short
`sellers reveal bad news (i.e., overvaluation) about the short-sold stocks, the fact that short sellers
`do not take actions after producing information about a firm’s fundamentals itself conveys good
`news to the equity market. In other words, the possibility of short selling a stock (rather than the
`actual trading of it) can potentially reduce the information asymmetry (as well as the associated
`stock undervaluation problem) for innovative firms. Since firm-specific information, including
`that concerning innovative activities, can now be better incorporated into current stock prices,
`firms exposed to a larger number of potential short sellers would be more willing to engage in
`value-enhancing innovation activities.4
`Taken together, the alternative hypothesis argues that short sellers, by reducing
`information asymmetry of innovative firms and actively disciplining managers, encourage firm
`innovation. We term this view the disciplining and information hypothesis.
`We test the above two hypotheses by examining the effect of short sellers on firm
`innovation. Obtaining patent information mainly from the National Bureau of Economic
`Research (NBER) Patent Citation database, we use the number of patents granted to a firm and
`
`3 Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang (2008, 2013) show that short sellers are important contributors to efficient stock
`prices. Boehmer and Wu (2013) find that stock prices are more accurate when short sellers are more active.
`4 It is conceivable that information revelation and transparency may sometimes reduce firms’ incentives to innovate
`due to strategic concerns. If most of the information that short sellers could produce is about firms’ innovation-
`related business secrets, then firms exposed to a larger number of short sellers may actually reduce their innovation
`activities, especially when these activities need to be hidden from industry and product market competitors.
`However, as outsider information producers, short sellers are unlikely to access the core technology or business
`secrets of the firms they sell short, so the possible leakage of strategic information through their information
`production activities does not appear to be a serious concern for our study. Moreover, this “adverse” consequence of
`information production by short sellers actually predicts the opposite to our main findings below.
`
`
`
`3
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1041
`
`

`
`the number of future citations received by each patent to measure innovation output.
`Specifically, the former captures the quantity of innovation and the latter proxies for the quality
`of innovation. Our use of patenting to capture firms’ innovation output has become standard in
`the innovation literature (e.g., Acharya et al., 2014; Aghion et al., 2013; Nanda and Rhodes-
`Kropf, 2013).
`As we argued before, identifying the causal effect of short sellers on firm innovation is
`challenging because of the endogenous nature of short selling activities. There may exist
`unobservable firm characteristics that are correlated with both short selling and innovation,
`introducing biases to our causal inferences. It is also possible that the causality goes the other
`way around: firms’ innovation potential could affect their attractiveness to short sellers.
`Therefore, in this paper, we use a quasi-natural experiment, Regulation SHO, to identify the
`causal effect of short sellers on firm innovation.
`Short selling activities in the U.S. have been largely constrained historically. For
`example, the uptick rule, which was established in 1935, prohibits short sales when stock prices
`are declining, imposing significant costs on short sellers. In July 2004, the Security and
`Exchange Commission (SEC) announced a new regulation on short-selling activities in the U.S.
`equity market, Regulation SHO, which removed the uptick rule restriction for an ex-ante
`randomly selected pilot group of firms (about one third of the Russell 3000 firms listed on
`NYSE, NASDAQ, and AMEX). Meanwhile, the uptick rule remained in effect for the non-pilot
`Russell 3000 firms (i.e. the rest two thirds of the Index). This sudden regulatory change, by
`significantly reducing the cost of short selling only for pilot firms but not for non-pilot firms,
`provides us a nice quasi-laboratory setting to observe the causal impact of short sellers on firm
`innovation, as it was not initiated to alter firms’ investment behavior in anyway. Another crucial
`advantage of this experiment is that it does not require pilot firms to experience an actual
`increase in short selling activities (and the corresponding price pressure) after the regulatory
`shock. The mere threat (or possibility) of becoming more likely to be shorted will influence
`managerial behavior and affect their incentives to innovate. Hence, we adopt a difference-in-
`differences (DiD) method to analyze how firms’ innovation outputs are affected by this
`exogenous shock to short-selling constraints.
`After performing various diagnostic tests to ensure that the parallel trends assumption,
`the key identifying assumption of the DiD test, is satisfied, we show a positive, causal effect of
`
`
`
`4
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1041
`
`

`
`short sellers on firm innovation. According to our multivariate DiD analysis, a reduction in short
`selling costs due to Regulation SHO leads to a larger increase in patent counts and patent
`citations for the treatment (pilot) group compared to the control (non-pilot) group. The evidence
`is consistent with the implication of the disciplining and information hypothesis.5
`We next perform two robustness tests for the baseline DiD analysis. First, to address the
`concern that our DiD results could have been driven by chance, we run simulations that
`randomize the inclusion of pilot firms in our analysis, and find that the DiD estimators obtained
`from this randomization test are on average close to zero. Second, to address the concern that
`unobservable shocks which are unrelated to Regulation SHO could have driven both the
`inclusion into the pilot list and firm innovation, we conduct a placebo test by artificially picking
`a “pseudo-event” year when we assume a regulatory shock reduced short selling costs for the
`pilot firms. We find no significant difference between the innovation activities of pilot firms and
`those of the non-pilot firms around such “pseudo-event” years. Thus, the identified positive
`effect of short sellers on firm innovation is unlikely to be driven by chance or by other earlier
`unobservable shocks, which further supports our causal inference.
`We further attempt to identify possible underlying mechanisms through which short
`sellers encourage firm innovation. To this end, we examine how cross-sectional variation in
`agency problems and information asymmetry alters our main results. We find that the positive
`effect of short sellers on innovation is more pronounced when firms have a larger exposure to
`agency conflicts between shareholders and management, i.e., when institutional ownership is
`lower, when product markets are less competitive, when corporate governance is poorer, and
`when CEO compensation is more sensitive to short-term performance. We also show that the
`positive effect of short sellers on innovation becomes stronger when firms are subject to a greater
`degree of information asymmetry, i.e., when firms are followed by a smaller number of financial
`analysts and when firms are smaller in size. The evidence suggests that both external disciplining
`and information production by short sellers are possible underlying mechanisms through which
`short sellers encourage firm innovation.
`
`
`5 The pilot program ended on August 6, 2007 when the tick restriction was removed for all stocks. This feature of
`the experiment provides us a potential opportunity to check whether the effect of short sellers on innovation outputs
`reverted after the pilot program ended. Unfortunately, we do not have enough reliable information about firms’
`patenting activities after the end of the pilot program to carry out this analysis.
`
`
`
`5
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1041
`
`

`
`The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the related literature.
`Section 3 describes sample selection and reports summary statistics. Section 4 presents the main
`results. Section 5 discusses possible mechanisms. Section 6 concludes.
`
`2. RELATION TO THE EXISTING LITERATURE
`Our paper contributes to two strands of literature. First, our paper is related to the
`emerging literature on finance and innovation. Holmstrom (1989) shows that innovation
`activities are inherently different from and may not mix well with routine tasks in an
`organization. Aghion and Tirole (1994) argue that the organizational structure of firms matters
`for innovation. Manso (2011) suggests that corporate contracting environment plays an important
`role in the innovation process. He theoretically demonstrates that managerial contracts that
`tolerate failure in the short run and reward success in the long run are best suited to motivate
`managers to engage in innovation activities.
`Empirical evidence shows that various firm characteristics and economic forces affect
`managerial incentives of investing in innovation. For example, a larger institutional ownership
`(Aghion, Van Reenen, and Zingales, 2013), corporate rather than independent venture capitalists
`(Chemmanur, Loutskina, and Tian, 2013), debtor-friendly bankruptcy laws (Acharya and
`Subramanian, 2009), lower union power (Bradley, Kim, and Tian, 2013), and private instead of
`public equity ownership (Lerner, Sorensen, and Stromberg, 2011) all enhance managerial and
`employees’ incentives to innovate. Other studies have examined the effects of product market
`competition, general market conditions, firm boundaries, CEO overconfidence, banking
`competition, and failure tolerance on corporate innovation (e.g., Aghion et al., 2005; Nanda and
`Rhodes-Kropf, 2012, 2013; Hirshleifer et al., 2012; Cornaggia et al., 2013; Seru, 2014; Tian and
`Wang, 2014). However, existing literature has been silent on how short sellers affect firms’
`innovation activities. Our paper contributes to this line of research by filling in the gap.
`Our paper also contributes to the literature on short selling. There has been an intensive
`debate on the effects of short-selling constraints on asset prices. While many existing studies
`show that short-selling constraints inflate security prices above their fundamental levels, leading
`to overvaluation (e.g., Miller, 1977; Harrison and Kreps, 1978; Chen, Hong, and Stein, 2002;
`Hong and Stein, 2003), other studies find that short-selling constraints have little effect on the
`stock market (e.g., Battalio and Schultz, 2006; Diether, Lee, and Werner, 2009; Beber and
`
`
`
`6
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1041
`
`

`
`Pagano, 2013). However, the empirical literature that examines the effect of short sellers or
`short-selling constraints on corporate decisions is quite limited. Gilchrist, Himmelberg, and
`Huberman (2005) show that short-selling constraints distort firm investment and financial
`decisions. Karpoff and Lou (2010) and Hirshleifer, Teoh, and Yu (2011) find that short sellers
`are able to detect corporate financial misconduct and dump on suspicious firms. Henry, Kisgen,
`and Wu (2013) document that short sellers could identify firms that have significant changes in
`default probabilities and those whose credit ratings are about to downgrade. Massa, Zhang, and
`Zhang (2013a) show that short sellers reduce earnings management in a cross-country setting.
`Massa, Zhang, and Zhang (2013b) find that short sellers improve corporate governance.
`Two recent papers use the same quasi-natural experiment as ours to examine the real
`effect of short sellers on corporate finance activities. Grullon, Michenaud, and Weston (2013)
`show that an exogenous change in short-selling constraints causes stock prices to fall and
`financially constrained firms respond to the drop in prices by reducing equity issues and
`investment.6 Fang, Huang, and Karpoff (2013) find that an exogenous decrease in short-selling
`costs due to the SHO program reduces pilot firms’ propensity to engage in earnings management
`and that this pattern reverses when the difference in short-selling constraints between pilot and
`control firms disappears after the SHO program ends. Different from the above two studies, our
`paper focuses on the causal effect of the removal of short-selling constraints on firm innovation
`and provides the first empirical analysis to shed light on this important research question.
`
`3. SAMPLE SELECTION AND SUMMARY STATISTICS
`3.1 Sample Selection
`
`
`6 However, their empirical analysis only studies observable capital expenditures (including R&D expenses), which
`are easily verifiable and closely monitored by shareholders. Unlike ordinary investment activities that mainly rely on
`observable inputs, innovation activities involve the usage of many unobservable corporate resources (such as the
`allocation of talent, effort, and attention to innovative projects/divisions and internal incentive schemes including
`mental support and non-monetary awards), which cannot be easily verified by the investors and thus are subject to
`more managerial discretion. Hence, innovation investments are much more likely than ordinary capital expenditures
`to be affected by the incremental disciplining and information production role played by short sellers. To capture
`this unique feature of innovation investments, in this paper, we use patenting as the main innovation output measure,
`which encompasses the successful usage of all (both observable and unobservable) innovation inputs and is most
`likely to be influenced by the disciplining and information production activities of short sellers. Therefore, our use
`of patenting (as opposed to ordinary capital expenditures) as the main outcome variable helps explain why we
`observe a different, and probably an even more important, effect of short sellers on firms’ investment behavior from
`that reported in Grullon, Michenaud, and Weston (2013).
`
`
`
`7
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1041
`
`

`
`Our sample construction starts with the Russell 3000 index in June 2004. Following the
`SEC’s first pilot order issued on July 28, 2004 (Securities Exchange Act Release No. 50104),
`which describes in detail how the pilot and non-pilot stocks in the Regulation SHO program
`were chosen, we exclude stocks that were not listed on the NYSE, AMEX, or NASDAQ NM,
`and stocks that went public or had spin-offs after April 30, 2004. Out of the remaining 2,952
`stocks, we identify 986 pilot stocks according to the published list of the SEC’s pilot order and
`the rest 1,966 stocks comprise the initial non-pilot sample. The exchange distribution of these
`stocks shows that they are very representative of the Russell 3000 Index. For example, around
`50% of the pilot stocks are listed on the NYSE, 48% on the Nasdaq NM, and 2% on the AMEX.
`The exchange distribution of the non-pilot stocks is almost the same.
`To examine the dynamics of innovation output around the implementation of Regulation
`SHO in July 2004, we extract firm characteristics from various data sources four years before
`and after the event year (i.e., 2004). Specifically, we examine innovation outcomes of firms
`whose fiscal year ending dates are between December 31, 2000 and December 31, 2008 (which
`essentially covers all firm activities taken place during the calendar year period of 2000 to 2008).
`We further require all firms to have non-missing Compustat records to calculate firm
`characteristics across the above sample period. The resulting final sample consists of 643 pilot
`firms and 1,261 control firms.7, 8 We collect firm-year patent and citation information from three
`sources. First, we retrieve our patent and citation data between 2000 and 2006 from the latest
`version of the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Patent Citation database. The
`NBER database provides information for all utility patents granted by the US Patent and
`Trademark Office (USPTO) over the period of 1976-2006. Second, we obtain information on
`patents granted over the period of 2007-2008 that is provided by Kogan et al. (2012) (available at
`https://iu.box.com/patents). Third, we construct a dataset for patent citations over the period of
`2007-2008 using
`the Harvard Business School (HBS) patent database (available at
`http://dvn.iq.harvard.edu/dvn/dv/patent).
`
`
`7 If we relax this requirement and only retain firms with non-missing Compustat records in any year during our
`sample period, the resulting full sample contains 909 pilot firms and 1,836 control firms in the year immediately
`before the announcement of the pilot program (i.e., 2003). Although all results reported in the paper are based on the
`restricted sample, they are very similar based on the full sample and available upon request.
`8 Note that this sample is balanced in the sense of calendar year activities but unbalanced in the sense of fiscal year
`activities. For example, a small set of firms in our sample have nine observations to cover their fiscal year activities
`while the majority others only have eight observations.
`
`
`
`8
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1041
`
`

`
`To calculate the control variables used in our study, we collect financial statement
`information from Compustat, stock price information from CRSP, institutional holdings data
`from Thomson’s CDA/Spectrum database (form 13F), anti-takeover provision information from
`the RiskMetrics database, analyst coverage data from the Institutional Brokers Estimate Systems
`(I/B/E/S) database, and CEO wealth-performance sensitivity data from Alex Edmans’ website
`(available at http://faculty.london.edu/aedmans/data.html).
`
`3.2 Variable Measurement
`3.2.1 Measuring Innovation
`We construct two measures to gauge a firm’s innovation output. The first measure is the
`total number of patents filed in a given year (and eventually granted), which captures the
`quantity of innovation. Hall, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg (2001) find that there is an average lag of two
`to three years between patent application year and grant year, though there is significant
`variation in the approval time. We use the application year instead of the grant year to determine
`a firm’s innovation output in a given year because the patent application year has been shown to
`better align with the actual time when the innovation activities take place (Griliches, Pakes, and
`Hall, 1988).
`Despite its straightforward intuition and easy implementation, a simple measure of patent
`counts hardly distinguishes groundbreaking innovations from incremental technological
`improvements. Hence, we construct the second measure of innovation output, the total number of
`citations each patent receives in subsequent years, which captures the quality (impact) of
`innovation.
`Nevertheless, both innovation measures are subject to truncation problems. Since we only
`observe patents that are eventually granted by the end of 2009, patents filed in the last few years
`of our sample period may still be under review and not granted by 2009. Similarly, patents tend
`to receive citations over a long period after its grant date, but we observe at best the citations
`received up to 2009. To deal with these truncation problems, we adjust the patent and citation
`data by using the “weight factors” first developed by Hall, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg (2001, 2005)
`and estimating the shape of the application-grant distribution and the citation-lag distribution,
`respectively.
`
`
`
`9
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1041
`
`

`
`The patent databases used in our study are unlikely to be affected by survivorship bias.
`As long as a patent application is eventually granted, it is attributed to the applying firm at the
`time of application even if the firm later gets acquired or goes bankrupt. Moreover, since patent
`citations are attributed to the patent rather than the applying firm, the patent granted to a firm that
`later gets acquired or goes bankrupt can still keep receiving citations long after the firm ceases to
`exist.
`We merge the patent data with the Russell 3000 index sample. Following the innovation
`
`literature, we set the patent and citation counts to zero for Russell-3000 firms not matched to the
`patent database, because our patent sample covers the entire universe of publicly-traded firms
`that have filed with the U.S. Patent Office. The distribution of patent grants in our final sample is
`right skewed, with its median at zero. Due to the right skewness of patent counts and citations
`per patent, we winsorize these variables at the 95th percentiles and then use the natural logarithm
`of one plus patent counts (LnPatent) and the natural logarithm of one plus the number of
`citations per patent (LnCitePat) as the main innovation measures in our analysis.
`
`3.2.2 Measuring Control Variables
`Following the innovation literature, we control for a vector of firm and industry
`characteristics that may affect a firm’s innovation output in our analysis. We compute all
`variables for firm i over its fiscal year t. Our control variables include firm size (the natural
`logarithm of book value assets), firm age (the natural logarithm of a firm’s age since its IPO
`year), profitability (ROA), investments in intangible assets (R&D expenditures over total assets),
`asset tangibility (net PPE scaled by total assets), leverage, capital expenditures, growth
`opportunities (Tobin’s Q), financial constraints (the Kaplan and Zingales (1997) five-variable
`KZ index), industry concentration (the Herfindahl index based on sales), and institutional
`ownership. To control for non-linear effects of product market competition on innovation outputs
`(Aghion et al., 2005), we also include the squared Herfindahl index in our regressions. We
`provide detailed variable definitions in the Appendix.
`
`3.3 Summary Statistics
`To minimize the effect of outliers, we winsorize all control variables at the 1st and 99th
`percentiles. Table 1 provides summary statistics of the variables. On average, a firm in our
`
`
`
`10
`
`Coalition for Affordable Drugs IV LLC - Exhibit 1041
`
`

`
`sample has 6.08 granted patents per year and each patent receives 0.38 citations. Regarding other
`variables, an average firm has book value assets of $5.58 billion, R&D-to-assets ratio of 3.9%,
`ROA of 9.0%, PPE-to-assets ratio of 47.6%, leverage of 17.2%, capital expenditure ratio of
`4.8%, Tobin’s Q of 1.9, and is 21.9 years old since its IPO date.
`
`4. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
`4.1 Baseline Difference-in-differences Results
`
`In our baseline analysis, we use a quasi-natural experiment, Regulation SHO, to identify
`the causal effect of short sellers on firm innovation. Before July 2004, short selling activities in
`the U.S. equity market were constrained by a regulation commonly referred to as the “uptick
`rule”, which prohibited short sales when stock prices were declining. On July 28, 2004, however,
`the SEC announced a new policy experiment, Regulation SHO, to remove all short sale
`restrictions for a randomly selected group of firms (the pilot group), which include 968 stocks.
`The selection of pilot firms followed a Rule 202T program, which first ranked all Russell 3000
`stocks listed on NYSE, NASDAQ, and AMEX according to their average trading volume, and
`then picked every third stock within each of the

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket