throbber
SENJU EXHIBIT 2151
`INNOPHARMA v SENJU
`IPR2015-00903
`
`

`
`
`
`
`
`7
`
`The Roles of Marketing, Product
`Quality, and Price Competition
`in the Growth and Composition
`of the U.S. Antiulcer
`
`Drug Industry
`
`Ernst R. Berndt, Linda T. Bui. David H. Lucking-Reiley,
`and Glen L. Urban
`
`7.1
`
`Introduction
`
`- 5.‘...
`1.3‘-_ _»
`
`7.
`1-
`
`
`
`,.
`
`'
`
`The introduction ofTagamet into the US. market in 1977 marked theS
`ning of a revolutionary treatment for ulcers and the emergence of a new
`try. What distinguished the products of this new industry was their ability '
`heal ulcers and treat preulcer conditions pharmacologically on an outpatie
`basis. trtoteby substituting for traditional, and costly. hospital admissions
`surgeries. Tagamct. known medically as an H,-receptor antagonist.
`the healing of ulcers by reducing the secretion of acid by the stomach.
`A striking feature of the antiulcer market is that it has sustained
`sales (quantity, not just-revenue) for over fifteen years and still shows2
`of slowing. New prescribing habits have clearly diffused to an ever increasing;
`number of physicians. Today there are a total of four H1-receptor antagonist‘
`Tagtimet. Zantac. Pepcid. and Axid. Zantac is now the United States’ (and,
`world s) largest-selling prescription drug, having estimated worldwidegsai”
`in 1992 of about $3.5 billion. Moreover, Tagamet is also among the ten mg‘.
`selling prescription drugs in the United States.‘
`'
`"T
`
`,
`
`
`
`
`276
`Ruben C. Feenstra and Clintonflk. Shiells
`
`(2) if price is mismeasured. so is the dependent variable, but then their formula
`for the coefficient becomes( [3 + 1)(o - l), and the implied tr = l.2 is even
`less credible.
`"Aging of lines": Once popular restaurants lose customers over time. We
`could bring in new ones and make an adjustment for their superiority. But then,
`some time later. the chefs are hired away and the old restaurants regain their
`share. Will we come back to the same level? How’?
`A major finding is that if one allows for the changing mix of import goods
`this leads to lower estimates of their income elasticity. That makes sense. but
`how low "should" the import income elasticity be? Can one really explain
`rising world trade just by the reduction in transport costs and the rising quality
`of traded goods? I find the notion that traded goods have higher income elastic-
`ities quite plausible. The explicit “bias" adjustment to the price index that fol-
`lows is. however, more problematic. But the advice to collect more data is
`surely right!
`
`References
`
`Berry, 5. 'I'. 1994. Estimating discrete-choice models of product differentiation. Rand
`Journal ofEconamics 25. no. 2 (summer ): 242-62.
`Griliches, Zvi, and Iain Cockbum. I994. Generics and new goods in pharmaceutical
`price indexes. American Economic Review 84 (5): 1213-32.
`Hanoch. Giora. l97l. CRESH production functions. Ecanamerrica 39 (5): 695-712.
`Trnjtenberg, Manuel.
`I990. Product
`innovation, price indices and the (mis-)
`measurement of economic performance. NBER Working Paper no. 3261. Cam-
`bridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
`
`

`
`E. R. Berndt. L. T. Bui, D. H. Lucking-Reiley, and G. L. Urban
`296
`_______;.___ _______ ____
`
`297
`
`The US. Arrtiuiccr Drug Industry
`
`by total industry patient-days, one would implicitly be assuming that the vari-
`ous drugs are perfectly substitutable. To circumvent this problem. we employ
`the economic theory of price indexes and calculate the industry price using the
`Fisher-Ideal price index."
`In tenns of quality, to the extent that product-quality characteristics affect
`the size of the potential market, they should be included in an overall industry
`demand equation. We would expect that the size of the potential patient market
`would depend on the specific indications for which the FDA has granted
`approval. We shall concentrate on one particular indication, GERD, which
`represented an especially large potential new market, and for which the H2-
`antagonists first received FDA approval relatively late in the sample. Specifi-
`cally, when the FDA granted approval to Glaxo’s Zantac for GERD. Zantac
`detailers were permitted to provide specific information to physicians concom-
`ing the treatment of GERD. This was significant, for instead of being confined
`to detailing to gastrocnterologists who saw ulcer patients, now Zantac detailers
`also made calls on general practitioners who commonly saw patients having
`GERD symptoms. This undoubtedly expanded the potential market.
`Such reasoning suggests that a dummy variable, say. GERD (taking the
`value of I following FDA approval), be employed in the overall industry de-
`mand equation. However, it is worth noting that information concerning the
`efficacy of drugs for different indications typically diffuses prior to formal
`FDA approval. The medical community is often aware of results of clinical
`trials prior to the FDA’s reviewing the clinical-trial data and coming to a final
`decision concerning approval for a new indication. As a result, a great deal of
`prescribing is done off-label prior to the FDA‘s granting approval. Thus, it is
`not clear how reliable the GERD dummy variable will be in capturing major
`changes in the size of the potential patient base.
`The third set of factors affecting industry demand involves marketing cf-
`fons. Earlier we noted that, in this industry. the two principal forms of market-
`ing efforts are minutes of detailing and either pages or deflated dollars of medi-
`cal journal advertising. There are several important
`issues concerning the
`measurement of marketing efforts. First. since drug marketing is largely a mat-
`ter of providing information about the existence and usefulness of the product,
`we expect its impact to be long-lived; once a physician has been informed, it
`is hard to see how such information might be destroyed. Indeed, precisely be-
`cause of this durability, firms typically expend a particularly large amount of
`marketing effort in the early stages of a new products life. Hence the impact
`of marketing on sales is likely better measured by the cumulative stock of
`marketing efforts since product launch, rather than simply by the flow of cur-
`
`ld. Specifically. the Fisher-Ideal price index is the geometric mean of the Laspeyres and
`Paasche price indexes, where each of them is computed using updated weights. New products are
`incorporated as soon as is feasible (i.e.. in the second period of their existence. so that their first
`difference is calculated). For further details concerning the Fisher-Ideal price index. set: Dicwert
`(I981. 1992).
`
`PAGE 3 OF 5
`
`rent monthly expenditures. We will also want to allow for the pozstilbrgwhitz
`this stock of information deprecratesbor deteritorates over Llmfi.
`0 8
`m’ght expect the depreciation rate to e quite ow.‘
`1We therefore employ the well-known perpetuahnventory method. Let M, be
`the stock of marketing effort at the end of month 2 (as measure?”by the stpzl:
`ofjournal advertising and detailing minutes), 131 5 be ‘hf’ m°f':_ Yd”
`ofime
`preciation of this stock, and let rm be the flow of markenng 9 °_‘‘ ““ 3
`eriod t. Define M, as the depreciation-adjusted stock of marketrng effort car-
`:ied over from the last month (1 - 3 )M,_, . P1115 new marketing °ff°“5 during
`months I (m,), that is
`
`(1)
`
`M,=<I—8)M,-.+m.= Z <'~5>'t‘"'~-
`v - |
`
`We construct separate stock measures for detailing and for journal advertising.
`Unlike the typical case for capital-stock accounting. we have no problem Wth
`establishing benchmark or “starting values" since we know that prior to August
`1977, the Tagamet journal (and detailing) stocks were pero. To implement
`equation (1), one must however assume rates of depreciation for each of these
`stocks. As discussed below, we will use the historical data on marketing and
`sales to estimate 8 econometrically,.rather than assume its value aflprron. “us
`The other major issue in measuring the effects of marketing e orts en 1
`an innovation of this paper. Other authors have suggested that ativertrs1n_g.be
`modeled as having two simulmneous effects in the market: overall advertising
`by all firms affecting overall market demand. and l'f=la1iV6 1€V815 05 3dV€1't|3m8
`among firms affecting the individual finns’ market shares." We take this mod-
`eling onc step further here by hypothesizing that firms may chglosetgltmil
`their marketing efforts to emphasize one of thetwo effects more
`an
`-
`Although the degree to which firms’ marketing efforts are directed, say.'at
`overall market expansion cannot be directly observed frpm data 0: quautllitétfff
`of marketing done by firms, we now propose a method or estrma mg
`fcct econometrically.
`_
`To clarify this concept, we discuss it in the context of the anttulcer drug
`market. When SrnithKline marketed Thgarnet from :5 rntroducpfin tr;
`until the entry ofZantac in 1983, they did not worry 2: out csfml-‘:3 Sn them 8
`ket share in the H3-antagonist markel._f0f Pale!“ St“1“5_ F°
`‘:1’ O‘; of map
`temporary monopoly positron. From this monopoly p0Sl£l0ll.'
`8 S
`T
`keting for SmithKline was to convince more and more physicians ofthe 2:11ti}?!
`of Hfantagonists in treating ulcer patients. They: and "0 f"h°' fig": regponisé
`rewards ofhaving expended efforts on diffusing tnforrnatitgl on W;8:“: Zan-
`to physicians. since they held 100 percent market share.
`owe
`.
`
`W W 5 ?°rt?c<:::::.°fr.t<.';:.r”"=«...;:.';:.::
`sea rm
`Iated. but distinct. approach that decomposes advertising "' 9 l f _ d“
`‘C: mm“ (1981) and
`components. For examples in the context of the phannaeeutrca in
`say.
`Hurwitz and Caves (1988).
`
`

`
`310
`
`E.R. Berndt, L. T. Bui, D. H. Locking-Reiley, and G. L. Urban
`
`
`
`311 The U.S. Antiulcer Drug Industry.
`
`table 7.2 focus only on relative quantiiies (market shares), but leave fixed the
`size of total industry demand at. say, Q, denote these price elasticities by ejjf.
`A total—price elasticity also captures the impact of a product’s price change on
`total industry demand: denote such a price elasticity by e”. (no asterisk). As
`has been shown by. inter alia. Bemdt and Wood ( 1979), the relationship be
`tween elf} and e” is as follows:
`
`‘W
`
`at,
`
`M
`
`MP
`I
`
`where Q]. is the quantity demanded of product j, Q is total industry demand,
`and P is industry price. The firs: partial derivative in equation (10) can be
`assumed to equal unity (other things being equal. demand for product j grows
`equiproportionally with market demand, i.e., according to its market share),
`while the second partial derivative is the industry- or market—price elasticity
`(estimated values of which are given in table 7.1). The last partial derivative
`in equation (10) indicates the impact of a change in product j’s price on the
`overall industry price index; it can be approximated by the revenue share of
`product j in total industry revenues.
`Alternative OLS and 2SLS estimates of eg.‘ are given in table 7.2, while NLS
`and NI.—2SLS estimates of the industry-price elasticity are presented in table
`7.]. For the twoproduct market. 1993 drugstore revenue shares for Tagamet
`and Zantac are approximately 0.25 and 0.75. For the four-product market,
`these shares are approximately 0.19 (Tagamet), 0.60 (Zantac), 0.12 (Pepcid),
`and 0.09 (Arid). Together. these relationships imply that in the two-product
`context, the ESLS estimates of the total own -price demand elasticities for Taga-
`met and Zantac are approximately - l.l54 and - 1.690, respectively, while in
`the four-product market. the 2SLS estimated total own-price demand elasticity
`is -0.909 for Tagamct. -1.153 for Zantac, -0.820 for Pepcid, and -0.799
`for Axid. Note that while these point estimates imply that some of the demand
`elasticities are less than one in absolute magnitude, the associated standard
`errors may well imply that reasonable confidence intervals include values of
`one and above (in absolute value).
`
`cumulative detailing or cumulative medical journal advertising is 3 m°‘° 3?‘
`propriate measure of marketing impacts than current monthly expendi-
`tures. In the context of industry demand, we distinguish investments of firms
`in these marketing activities by the industry structure prevailing when thc fix-
`penditures originally occurred. In a monopoly market structure. all marketing
`expenditures are market-expanding. for the monopolist has 109 PeT°“-_‘“_§‘3I:‘5‘
`share. In a market structure with k products. however, marketing activr Es _e-
`come more tivalrous, and as Ic becomes large, We ¢XP°°”513”"e'Y “me 5P‘”'
`over” of a finn's marketing efforts in affecting industry demand. We have hy-
`pothesized, thereforc. that in terms ofaffecting ind”-W3’ d°”"‘“d~ the reimge
`effects of marketing expenditures originally made when k PTO?‘-‘ts
`‘nthai
`market will tend to declrneas
`increases. In‘other words. WC VP; 0513‘? k ‘
`the effectiveness of marketing in generating industry sales depen
`on mar e
`structure in a systematic manner.
`I
`_
`_d
`In our empirical analysis of the anuulcer drug market, we obtained cons: er-
`able but not quite unanimous support for this hypothesis. In Pamculai» “‘I’“
`malizing the impact of a monopolist s marketing investments on cur:-en sgest
`to unity, we estimated the impact in a duopoly to be 0.6, In 3 W6:-Pfothlrti
`industry to be 0.8, and in a four-product market to be
`these ast
`e
`numbers are all statistically significantly different from unity (implying that
`we reject the hypothesis that the effectiveness of marketing efforts is indepen-
`dent of market structure). and from zero (indicating that we reject the hYP°th¢'
`sis that once there is competition. the 001)’ MP3“ °f mwkemg ‘5 °“ market
`share. and there is none on overall market size) “"15 °“T ‘°5“"5 Suggest ‘hat
`in the antiulcer drug market there is clear evidence Of 5Pl“0"'¢T5» and “W the“
`spillovers are considerably less than 100 P91’Cent °ff°C""°' M°'e°,v°r’ for Ehe
`most part. these spillovers decline as the number of products in the industry m-
`creases.
`‘
`_
`.
`Second. we find that at the industry level, both cumulative minutes of detail-
`ing and cumulative pages of medical journal advertising affcctpsales‘. typical
`estimates of these elasticities are 0.5 and 0.2.. reSpeCtW¢1y- At ‘hf: ma"k°"5h‘_“'°
`level, relative sales of products are also positively related to relative cumulative
`minutes of detailing; this elasticity is typically in the range of'0.Zht0
`1'1":
`gether these results imply that the marketing efforts of fir:’sfl:n afk3:1 Ill:ates
`drug market had substantial effects, in terms of affecting
`In
`C S
`
`

`
`
`
`312 E. R. Berndt, L. T. Bui, D. H. Luclting-Reiley, and G. L. Urban
`
`
`
`313 The U.S. Antiulcer Drug Industry
`
`(Tagztmet. Zantac, Pepcid, and Axid), we find that the market-share impact of
`the stock of detailing minutes deteriorated at an annual rate of around 40 per-
`cent, reflecting perhaps a more rivalrous content of marketing efforts.
`The remarkable growth in the market share of Zantac over time can be par-
`tially explained, then, by the very substantial marketing efforts undertaken by
`Glaxo. However. pricing policies also had an impact. Zantac gained share over
`Tagamet in part because the price premium commanded by Zanlac declined
`from about 56 percent in 1983 to only 25 percent in I993. Our estimates of
`industry-price elasticities range from about -0.7 to -0.9. while estimates of
`cross-price elasticities between any pair of the four products are about 0.7.
`Another set of important factors affecting sales of antiulcer drugs concerns
`product-quality attributes. At the industry level, the evidence suggests that the
`size of the market was enlarged considerably when the FDA granted approval
`for the GERD indication—a condition that occurs in a relatively large popula-
`tion. At the matket-share level, we find that when a product had a GERD-
`approval advantage relative to other products, its market share increased. Thus
`another reason why Zantac fared so well in the marketplace is that for quite
`some time it was the only product that had received FDA approval for the
`treatment of GERD. Another variable affecting market share significantly is
`the number of adverse interactions with other drugs reported to the FDA. On
`this account Tagarnet fared relatively badly (by 1993. Thgamet had twelve drug
`interactions, Zantac and Axid had only one, and Pepcid had none). Thus Zan-
`tac also enjoyed advantages from this product-quality characteristic. An unex-
`pected result we obtained, however, was that dosing frequency did not appear
`to affect market shares in a statistically significant manner.
`Finally, we found that, as in many other markets, order-of—cntry effects are
`very substantial. In particular, holding constant price, marketing efforts, and
`product quality relative to the nth product. the (rt + l)th entrant can expect
`about forty percent lower sales.
`The results of this paper are of considerable interest in the current health-
`care reform debate. Critics of the pharmaceutical industry have argued that
`much detailing is merely aimed at market share and is socially wasteful. Some
`have suggested placing ceilings on the marketing activities of pharmaceutical
`finns. but our findings demonstrate that this could have negative social welfare
`impacts. The findings in this paper suggest that marketing efforts also play a
`
`Vam,»,ge5_ Thus, such a policy could have anticompetitive impacts. a|lh0l-‘Sh it
`would be consistent with a patent system that rewards 1m1_0V3“°“-
`The research reported in this paper should be extended in a number of ways.
`First although the industry and market- share equations are plausible and PTO‘
`vide important initial evidence on the roles of marketing‘. P"¢¢(;d3'{;5 P|'°f:‘13;
`quality Competition "1 the antrulcer market, the underlying m e
`con
`modified in a number of useful ways. The most obvious extension is to re-
`formulate the models within an explicitly dynamic diffusion framelwprflft, such
`as those involving the Gompertz, logistic. or other more genera '1 ust-on
`curve formulations. in such a framework, marketing and pncrng polrcres might
`not only affect the long-run or equilibrium level of demand. but ‘hey might
`also affect the speed at which a 1onS"'_"“ equilfbrlmn 1°V_‘’l
`'5 aPp'°a?°d't to_
`As second useful extension would involve Incorporating dafa 0“ ““°° '
`consumer marketing.
`In 1988 SmithKline experimented with 21 Tommy
`Tummy" television advertising campaign that was armed drrecgli’ ‘1td°°’:_‘;;"‘i°:':
`but did not mention Tagatnet by name. More recently, (ilaxpl
`ariba ve rd acid
`magazines and on television, suggesting that Pallems Wm‘ ea
`‘"1’ an
`discomfort should see their physicians. These ads are sponsored by the CW0
`Research Institute and. consistent with FDA reg1113‘1°05 °“ d"°°"‘°‘°°“5"_m_"
`
`‘
`warning and other product information is a so ‘ y rsc ose.. _ rnc
`Venisemenrs typically do not mention products names, their impacts more
`likely to be on industry demand than on market share. Moreover, dlrficl-.t°*
`consumer advertising may Change ‘he PhY5i°i3n'P3fi°“t i"f°"m"fi°"‘Sha"ng
`relationship, and therefore could modify the diffusion process. It Would be
`useful to examine whether such effects have actually occurredaand by CXICU‘
`sion how effective is direct-to-consumer marketing in the antrulcer market-
`
`place.
`’
`.
`_
`.
`_
`Third, and perhaps most importantly, the findings of tlus paptir sugtgesglmti
`esting topics in the theory of industrial organization. What is
`e op rm tn
`keting strategy for firms when there are spillovers and marketing activities have
`long—lived impacts? What is the conespofldingly optimal pncIns_behaV1°{'-’
`How does this optimal behavior vary with market structure? How is the 0Pn'
`mal behavior affectedby federal tax provisions thatalloywvfi/1|: 3XPen;1m$II(1T‘:ti1;:'
`than amortizing) °f1°“E'l|"ed maiketmg ‘""°5‘m°“t5'
`at are
`e ' P

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket